Misplaced Pages

Collusion: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 07:18, 25 February 2023 editSimLibrarian (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users123,959 editsm Definition: title style fixTag: Visual edit← Previous edit Latest revision as of 10:01, 25 April 2024 edit undoLarry Hockett (talk | contribs)Autopatrolled, Extended confirmed users, Pending changes reviewers, Rollbackers125,506 edits Undid revision 1220692829 by 46.199.73.50 (talk) unexplainedTag: Undo 
(24 intermediate revisions by 14 users not shown)
Line 14: Line 14:
| pages = | pages =
| isbn = 0-13-063085-3}}</ref> | isbn = 0-13-063085-3}}</ref>
It can involve "unions, wage fixing, kickbacks, or misrepresenting the independence of the relationship between the colluding parties".<ref></ref> In legal terms, all acts effected<!-- "effect" is used intentionally as a verb meaning "to make or bring about". See dictionary. --> by collusion are considered ].<ref>Collusion {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080109224939/http://encarta.msn.com/encyclopedia_761571249/Collusion.html|date=2008-01-09}}.</ref> It can involve "unions, wage fixing, kickbacks, or misrepresenting the independence of the relationship between the colluding parties".<ref></ref> In legal terms, all acts effected<!-- "effect" is used intentionally as a verb meaning "to make or bring about". See dictionary. --> by collusion are considered ].<ref>Collusion . {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080109224939/http://encarta.msn.com/encyclopedia_761571249/Collusion.html|date=2008-01-09}}.</ref>


== Definition == == Definition ==
In the study of ] and market ], collusion takes place within an ] when rival companies cooperate for their mutual benefit. ] usually involves an agreement between two or more sellers to take action to suppress competition between sellers in the market. Because competition among sellers can provide consumers with low prices, conspiracy agreements increase the price consumers pay for the goods. Because of this harm to consumers, it is against antitrust laws to fix prices by agreement between producers, so participants must keep it a secret. Collusion often takes place within an ] ], where there are few firms and agreements that have significant impacts on the entire market or industry. To differentiate from a ], collusive agreements between parties may not be explicit; however, the implications of cartels and collusion are the same.<ref name="stats.oecd.org">{{Cite web|title=OECD Glossary of Statistical Terms - Collusion Definition|url=https://stats.oecd.org/glossary/detail.asp?ID=3159|access-date=2020-11-01|website=stats.oecd.org}}</ref> In the study of ] and market ], collusion takes place within an ] when rival companies cooperate for their mutual benefit. ] usually involves an agreement between two or more sellers to take action to suppress competition between sellers in the market. Because competition among sellers can provide consumers with low prices, conspiracy agreements increase the price consumers pay for the goods. Because of this harm to consumers, it is against antitrust laws to fix prices by agreement between producers, so participants must keep it a secret. Collusion often takes place within an ] ], where there are few firms and agreements that have significant impacts on the entire market or industry. To differentiate from a ], collusive agreements between parties may not be explicit; however, the implications of cartels and collusion are the same.<ref name="stats.oecd.org">{{Cite web|title=OECD Glossary of Statistical Terms - Collusion Definition|url=https://stats.oecd.org/glossary/detail.asp?ID=3159|access-date=2020-11-01|website=stats.oecd.org}}</ref>


Under competition law, there is an important distinction between direct and covert collusion. Direct collusion generally refers to a group of companies communicating directly with each other, usually to coordinate and/or monitor their actions, to cooperate through pricing, market allocation, sales quotas, etc. By contrast, tacit collusion is where companies coordinate and monitor their behavior without this direct communication. This is generally not considered illegal, so companies guilty of tacit conspiracy should face no penalties, even though their actions would have a similar economic impact as explicit conspiracy. Collusion is the result of less competition through mutual understanding, where competitors can independently set prices and market share.<ref>Garrod, & Olczak, M. (2018). Explicit vs tacit collusion: The effects of firm numbers and asymmetries. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 56, 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2017.10.006</ref> A core principle of antitrust policy is that companies must not communicate with each other. Even if conversations between multiple companies are illegal but not enforceable, the incentives to comply with collusive agreements are the same with and without communication. It is against competition law for companies to have explicit conversations in private. If evidence of conversations is accidentally left behind, it will become the most critical and conclusive evidence in antitrust litigation. Even without communication, businesses can coordinate prices by observation, but from a legal standpoint, this tacit handling leaves no evidence. Most companies cooperate through invisible collusion, so whether companies communicate is absolutely at the core of antitrust policy.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Fonseca |first1=Miguel A. |last2=Normann |first2=Hans-Theo |date=2012-11-01 |title=Explicit vs. tacit collusion—The impact of communication in oligopoly experiments |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0014292112001237 |journal=European Economic Review |language=en |volume=56 |issue=8 |pages=1759–1772 |doi=10.1016/j.euroecorev.2012.09.002 |hdl=10871/14991 |issn=0014-2921|hdl-access=free }}</ref> Under competition law, there is an important distinction between direct and covert collusion. Direct collusion generally refers to a group of companies communicating directly with each other to coordinate and monitor their actions, such as cooperating through pricing, market allocation, sales quotas, etc. On the other hand, tacit collusion is where companies coordinate and monitor their behavior without direct communication. This type of collusion is generally not considered illegal, so companies guilty of tacit conspiracy should face no penalties even though their actions would have a similar economic impact as explicit conspiracy.


Collusion results from less competition through mutual understanding, where competitors can independently set prices and market share.<ref>Garrod, & Olczak, M. (2018). Explicit vs tacit collusion: The effects of firm numbers and asymmetries. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 56, 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2017.10.006</ref> A core principle of antitrust policy is that companies must not communicate with each other. Even if conversations between multiple companies are illegal but not enforceable, the incentives to comply with collusive agreements are the same with and without communication. It is against competition law for companies to have explicit conversations in private. If evidence of conversations is accidentally left behind, it will become the most critical and conclusive evidence in antitrust litigation. Even without communication, businesses can coordinate prices by observation, but from a legal standpoint, this tacit handling leaves no evidence. Most companies cooperate through invisible collusion, so whether companies communicate is at the core of antitrust policy.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Fonseca |first1=Miguel A. |last2=Normann |first2=Hans-Theo |date=2012-11-01 |title=Explicit vs. tacit collusion—The impact of communication in oligopoly experiments |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0014292112001237 |journal=European Economic Review |language=en |volume=56 |issue=8 |pages=1759–1772 |doi=10.1016/j.euroecorev.2012.09.002 |hdl=10871/14991 |issn=0014-2921|hdl-access=free }}</ref>
Collusion which is covert is known as ], and is considered legal. ] in ] explains that since the masters (business owners) are fewer in numbers, it is easier to collude to serve common interests among those involved, such as maintaining low wages, whilst it is difficult for the labor to coordinate to protect their own interests due to their vast numbers. Hence, business owners have a bigger advantage over the working class. Nevertheless, according to Adam Smith, the public rarely hear about coordination and collaborations that occur between business owners as it takes place in informal settings.<ref name="WoN">{{cite web |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/download/pdf/Capital-Volume-I.pdf |title=''A Critique of Political Economy''}}</ref> Some forms of explicit collusion are not considered impactful enough on an individual basis to be considered illegal, such as that which occurred by the social media group ] in the ].<ref>{{cite web |url=http://blog.practicalethics.ox.ac.uk/2021/02/ethics-of-the-gamestop-short-squeeze/ |title=Ethics of the GameStop Short Squeeze |last=McConnell |first=Doug |publisher=University of Oxford}}</ref>

Collusion is illegal in the ], ], ] and most of the ] due to ] laws, but implicit collusion in the form of ] and tacit understandings still takes place.

=== Tacit Collusion ===
Covert collusion is known as ] and is considered legal. ] in '']'' explains that since the masters (business owners) are fewer in number, it is easier to collude to serve common interests among those involved, such as maintaining low wages, whilst it is difficult for the labour to coordinate to protect their interests due to their vast numbers. Hence, business owners have a bigger advantage over the working class. Nevertheless, according to Adam Smith, the public rarely hears about coordination and collaborations that occur between business owners as it takes place in informal settings.<ref name="WoN">{{cite web |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/download/pdf/Capital-Volume-I.pdf |title=''A Critique of Political Economy''}}</ref> Some forms of explicit collusion are not considered impactful enough on an individual basis to be considered illegal, such as that which occurred by the social media group ] in the ].<ref>{{cite web |url=http://blog.practicalethics.ox.ac.uk/2021/02/ethics-of-the-gamestop-short-squeeze/ |title=Ethics of the GameStop Short Squeeze |last=McConnell |first=Doug |publisher=University of Oxford}}</ref>
There are many ways that implicit collusion tends to develop:
* The practice of stock analyst conference calls and meetings of industry participants almost necessarily results in tremendous amounts of strategic and price transparency. This allows each firm to see how and why every other firm is pricing their products.
* If the practice of the industry causes more complicated pricing, which is hard for the consumer to understand (such as ], hidden taxes and fees in the wireless industry, negotiable pricing), this can cause competition based on price to be meaningless (because it would be too complicated to explain to the customer in a short advertisement). This causes industries to have essentially the same prices and compete on advertising and image, something theoretically as damaging to consumers as normal price fixing.<ref>{{Cite web |last=PricewaterhouseCoopers |title=The telecom price wars continue to rage in the global wireless industry |url=https://www.strategyand.pwc.com/gx/en/about/media/press-releases/telco-price-wars-continue.html |access-date=2023-04-19 |website=PwC}}</ref>


==Base model of (Price) Collusion== ==Base model of (Price) Collusion==
For a cartel to work successfully, it must: For a cartel to work successfully, it must:


* coordinate on the conspiracy agreement. * '''Co-ordinate''' on the conspiracy agreement (bargaining, explicit or implicit communication).
* '''Monitor''' compliance.
(Bargaining, explicit or implicit communication)
* Monitor compliance. * '''Punish''' non-compliance.
* '''Control''' the expansion of non-cartel supply.
* Punish non-compliance.
* '''Avoid''' inspection by customers and competition authorities.
* Control the expansion of non-cartel supply.
* Avoid inspection by customers and competition authorities.


Regarding stability within the cartel: Regarding stability within the cartel:
Line 44: Line 51:


== Variations == == Variations ==
* <math>\frac{\pi (P_c)}{n(1-\delta)}\geq\pi(P_c)\rightarrow\frac{1}{n(1-\delta)}\geq 1 </math>
* π(Pc)/n(1-ẟ) ≥ π(Pc) →1/n(1-ẟ)≥ 1
* 1 n(1-) * <math>1 \geq n(1-\delta)</math>
* 1 n-nẟ * <math>1 \geq n-n\delta</math>
* <math>n \delta \geq n-1</math>
* nẟ≥n-1
* <math>\delta \geq \frac{n-1}{n}</math>
* ẟ ≥n-1/n


Suppose there are n firms in this market. At the collusive price, the firms are symmetric, so they divide the profits equally between the whole industry, represented as π(Pc)/n.If and only if the profit of choosing deviate is greater than that of sticking to collude, i.e Suppose this market has <math> n </math> firms. At the collusive price, the firms are symmetric, so they divide the profits equally between the whole industry, represented as <math>\frac{\pi(P_c)}{n}</math>. If and only if the profit of choosing to deviate is greater than that of sticking to collude, i.e.
* π(Pc)/n(1-) ≥ π(Pc)(Companies have no incentive to deviate unilaterally) * <math>\frac{\pi (P_c)}{n(1-\delta)}\geq\pi(P_c)</math> (Companies have no incentive to deviate unilaterally)
* Therefore, when 𝛿 𝑛−1/𝑛 is the case, i.e. the firm has no incentive to deviate unilaterally, the cartel alliance will be stable. So as the number of firms increases, the more difficult it is for The Cartel to maintain stability. * Therefore, the cartel alliance will be stable when <math>\delta\geq \frac{n-1}{n}</math> is the case, i.e. the firm has no incentive to deviate unilaterally. So as the number of firms increases, the more difficult it is for The Cartel to maintain stability.
As the number of firms in the market increases, so does the factor of the minimum discount required for collusion to succeed.<ref>Compte et al., 2002. Olivier Compte, Frederic Jenny, Patrick Rey Capacity, constraints, mergers and collusion European Economic Review, 46 (2002), pp. 1-29</ref> As the number of firms in the market increases, so does the factor of the minimum discount required for collusion to succeed.<ref>Compte et al., 2002. Olivier Compte, Frederic Jenny, Patrick Rey Capacity, constraints, mergers and collusion European Economic Review, 46 (2002), pp. 1-29</ref>


According to ] and ], the independence of suppliers forces prices to their minimum, increasing ] and decreasing the price-determining ability of each individual firm.<ref name="Springer Netherlands">{{Citation|last1=Kalai|first1=Ehud|title=The Kinked Demand Curve, Facilitating Practices, and Oligopolistic Coordination|date=1994|url=https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-1370-0_2|work=Imperfections and Behavior in Economic Organizations|pages=15–38|editor-last=Gilles|editor-first=Robert P.|series=Theory and Decision Library|place=Dordrecht|publisher=Springer Netherlands|language=en|doi=10.1007/978-94-011-1370-0_2|isbn=978-94-011-1370-0|access-date=2020-11-01|last2=Satterthwaite|first2=Mark A.|editor2-last=Ruys|editor2-first=Pieter H. M.}}</ref> However if all firms collude to increase prices, loss of sales will be minimized, as consumers lack alternative choices at lower prices and must decide between what is available. This benefits the colluding firms, as they generate more sales, at the cost of ] to society.<ref name="stats.oecd.org"/> However, depending on the assumptions made in the theoretical model on the information available to all firms, there are some outcomes, based on Cooperative Game Theory, where collusion may have higher efficiency than if firms did not collude.<ref name=":0">{{Cite book|doi=10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_22-1|chapter=Collusion|title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics|year=1987|last1=Roberts|first1=Kevin|pages=1–5|isbn=978-1-349-95121-5}}</ref> According to ] and ], the independence of suppliers forces prices to their minimum, increasing ] and decreasing the price-determining ability of each firm.<ref name="Springer Netherlands">{{Citation|last1=Kalai|first1=Ehud|title=The Kinked Demand Curve, Facilitating Practices, and Oligopolistic Coordination|date=1994|url=https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-1370-0_2|work=Imperfections and Behavior in Economic Organizations|pages=15–38|editor-last=Gilles|editor-first=Robert P.|series=Theory and Decision Library|place=Dordrecht|publisher=Springer Netherlands|language=en|doi=10.1007/978-94-011-1370-0_2|isbn=978-94-011-1370-0|access-date=2020-11-01|last2=Satterthwaite|first2=Mark A.|editor2-last=Ruys|editor2-first=Pieter H. M.}}</ref> However if all firms collude to increase prices, loss of sales will be minimized, as consumers lack choices at lower prices and must decide between what is available. This benefits the colluding firms, as they generate more sales at the cost of ] to society.<ref name="stats.oecd.org"/> However, depending on the assumptions made in the theoretical model on the information available to all firms, there are some outcomes, based on Cooperative Game Theory, where collusion may have higher efficiency than if firms did not collude.<ref name=":0">{{Cite book|doi=10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_22-1|chapter=Collusion|title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics|year=1987|last1=Roberts|first1=Kevin|pages=1–5|isbn=978-1-349-95121-5}}</ref>


One variation of this traditional theory is the theory of ]. Firms face a kinked demand curve if, when one firm decreases its price, other firms are expected to follow suit in order to maintain sales. When one firm increases its price, its rivals are unlikely to follow, as they would lose the sales gains that they would otherwise receive by holding prices at the previous level. Kinked demand potentially fosters ] because any one firm would receive a reduced benefit from cutting price, as opposed to the benefits accruing under neoclassical theory and certain game-theoretic models such as ].<ref name="Springer Netherlands"/> One variation of this traditional theory is the theory of ]. Firms face a kinked demand curve if, when one firm decreases its price, other firms are expected to follow suit to maintain sales. When one firm increases its price, its rivals are unlikely to follow, as they would lose the sales gains they would otherwise receive by holding prices at the previous level. Kinked demand potentially fosters ] because any one firm would receive a reduced benefit from cutting price, as opposed to the benefits accruing under neoclassical theory and certain game-theoretic models such as ].<ref name="Springer Netherlands"/>


Collusion may also occur in auction markets, where independent firms coordinate their bids (]).<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Conley |first1=Timothy |last2=Decarolis |first2=Francesco |title=Detecting Bidders Groups in Collusive Auctions |journal=American Economic Journal: Microeconomics |date=2016 |volume=8 |issue=2|pages=1–38 |doi=10.1257/mic.20130254 }}</ref> Collusion may also occur in auction markets, where independent firms coordinate their bids (]).<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Conley |first1=Timothy |last2=Decarolis |first2=Francesco |title=Detecting Bidders Groups in Collusive Auctions |journal=American Economic Journal: Microeconomics |date=2016 |volume=8 |issue=2|pages=1–38 |doi=10.1257/mic.20130254 }}</ref>
Line 73: Line 80:


== Indicators == == Indicators ==
Practices that suggest possible collusion may include one or more actions such as: Some actions that may indicate collusion among competitors are:


* ] and setting of an unjustified high or an unjustified low price * Charging ] or setting prices that are either too high or too low without justification
* ] and blanket referral agreements between competing businesses * Paying or receiving ] and agreeing to refer customers only to each other
* ] and market allocation * ] and ] of markets among themselves
* ] and anticompetitive ] (although, not all product bundling is anticompetitive) * ] and anticompetitive ] (although, not all product bundling is anticompetitive)
* ] and ] * ] with certain customers or suppliers and ] with certain customers or suppliers
* ] * Selling products below cost in order to drive out competitors (also known as ])
* Restricting the distribution or supply of products along the supply chain through ]
* ]
* ] by fixing bids or agreeing not to bid for certain contracts
* ]
* ]


== Examples == == Examples ==
Line 90: Line 96:
*When companies discriminate, price collusion is less likely, so the discount factor needed to ensure stability must be increased. In such price competition, competitors use delivered pricing to discriminate in space, but this does not mean that firms using delivered pricing to discriminate cannot collude.<ref>Heywood, Li, D., & Ye, G. (2020). Does price discrimination make collusion less likely? a delivered pricing model. Journal of Economics (Vienna, Austria), 131(1), 39–60. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-020-00699-4</ref> *When companies discriminate, price collusion is less likely, so the discount factor needed to ensure stability must be increased. In such price competition, competitors use delivered pricing to discriminate in space, but this does not mean that firms using delivered pricing to discriminate cannot collude.<ref>Heywood, Li, D., & Ye, G. (2020). Does price discrimination make collusion less likely? a delivered pricing model. Journal of Economics (Vienna, Austria), 131(1), 39–60. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-020-00699-4</ref>


=== United States ===
Collusion is illegal in the ], ] and most of the ] due to ] laws, but implicit collusion in the form of ] and tacit understandings still takes place. Several examples of collusion in the United States include:

* ] and ] among manufacturers of heavy ] equipment in the 1960s, including ].<ref>{{cite book * ] and ] among manufacturers of heavy ] equipment in the 1960s, including ].<ref>{{cite book
| title = Encyclopedia of white-collar & corporate crime | title = Encyclopedia of white-collar & corporate crime
Line 98: Line 103:
* The sharing of potential contract terms by ] free agents in an effort to help a targeted franchise circumvent the salary cap. * The sharing of potential contract terms by ] free agents in an effort to help a targeted franchise circumvent the salary cap.
* Price fixing within ] manufacturers providing cafeteria food to ]s and the ] in 1993. * Price fixing within ] manufacturers providing cafeteria food to ]s and the ] in 1993.
* Market division and output determination of livestock feed additive, called ], by companies in the US, ] and ] in 1996, ] being the most notable of these.<ref>Hunter-Gault, Charlayne (October 15, 1996). "ADM: Who's Next?". MacNeil/Lehrer Newshour (PBS). https://www.pbs.org/newshour/bb/business/october96/adm_10-15.html. Retrieved on 2007-10-17.</ref> * Market division and output determination of livestock feed additive, called ], by companies in the US, ] and ] in 1996, ] being the most notable of these.<ref>Hunter-Gault, Charlayne (October 15, 1996). "ADM: Who's Next?". MacNeil/Lehrer Newshour (PBS). https://www.pbs.org/newshour/bb/business/october96/adm_10-15.html {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20070930041515/http://www.pbs.org/newshour/bb/business/october96/adm_10-15.html |date=2007-09-30 }}. Retrieved on 2007-10-17.</ref>
* ] in ]<ref>{{Cite web |title=Collusion Strategy and Analysis for Texas Hold'em by T. Hayes |url=https://www.lybrary.com/collusion-strategy-and-analysis-for-texas-holdem-p-922246.html |access-date=2022-12-27 |website=Lybrary.com |language=en}}</ref> or any other card game played for money. * ] in ]<ref>{{Cite web |title=Collusion Strategy and Analysis for Texas Hold'em by T. Hayes |url=https://www.lybrary.com/collusion-strategy-and-analysis-for-texas-holdem-p-922246.html |access-date=2022-12-27 |website=Lybrary.com |language=en}}</ref> or any other card game played for money.
*] and ] collusion of products in 2013: Ben and Jerry's makes chunkier flavors with more treats in them, while Häagen-Dazs sticks to smoother flavors.<ref>Sullivan, Christopher John. ''Three Essays on Product Collusion''. Diss. University of Michigan, 2016. https://deepblue.lib.umich.edu/bitstream/handle/2027.42/138544/sullivcj_1.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y</ref> *] and ] collusion of products in 2013: Ben and Jerry's makes chunkier flavors with more treats in them, while Häagen-Dazs sticks to smoother flavors.<ref>Sullivan, Christopher John. ''Three Essays on Product Collusion''. Diss. University of Michigan, 2016. https://deepblue.lib.umich.edu/bitstream/handle/2027.42/138544/sullivcj_1.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y</ref>
* Google and Apple against employee poaching, a collusion case in 2015 wherein it was revealed that both companies agreed not to hire employees from one another in order to halt the rise in wages.<ref name=TG>{{cite web |url=https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2014/apr/24/apple-google-settle-antitrust-lawsuit-hiring-collusion |title=''A Critique of Political Economy''|website=]|date=24 April 2014}}</ref> * Google and Apple against employee poaching, a collusion case in 2015 wherein it was revealed that both companies agreed not to hire employees from one another in order to halt the rise in wages.<ref name="TG">{{cite web |url=https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2014/apr/24/apple-google-settle-antitrust-lawsuit-hiring-collusion |title=''A Critique of Political Economy''|website=]|date=24 April 2014}}</ref>
* Google has been hit with a series of antitrust lawsuits. In October 2020, the US Department of Justice filed a landmark lawsuit alleging that Google unlawfully boxed out competitors by reaching deals with phone makers, including Apple and Samsung, to be the default search engine on their devices.<ref name="cnet.com">{{Cite web |title=Google's three antitrust battles: Here's what you need to know |url=https://www.cnet.com/tech/tech-industry/googles-three-antitrust-battles-heres-what-you-need-to-know-faq/ |access-date=2023-04-04 |website=CNET |language=en}}</ref> Another lawsuit filed by nearly 40 attorneys general on Dec. 17, 2020 alleges that Google’s search results favored its own services over those of more-specialized rivals, a tactic that harmed competitors.<ref name="cnet.com"/>


=== Europe ===
In the EU:
* The illegal collusion between the giant German automakers BMW, Daimler and Volkswagen, discovered by the ] in 2019, to hinder technological progress in improving the quality of vehicle emissions in order to reduce the cost of production and maximize profits.<ref name=DW>{{cite web |url=https://www.dw.com/en/european-commission-finds-german-automakers-illegally-colluded-on-emissions-technology/a-48218578 |title=''European Commission finds German automakers illegally colluded on emissions technology''|website=]}}</ref> * The illegal collusion between the giant German automakers BMW, Daimler and Volkswagen, discovered by the ] in 2019, to hinder technological progress in improving the quality of vehicle emissions in order to reduce the cost of production and maximize profits.<ref name=DW>{{cite web |url=https://www.dw.com/en/european-commission-finds-german-automakers-illegally-colluded-on-emissions-technology/a-48218578 |title=''European Commission finds German automakers illegally colluded on emissions technology''|website=]}}</ref>


=== Australia ===
There are many ways that implicit collusion tends to develop:


* Japanese shipping company Kawasaki Kisen Kaisha Ltd (]) were fined $34.5 million by the Federal Court for engaging in criminal cartel conduct. The court found that K-Line participated in a cartel with other shipping companies to fix prices on the transportation of cars, trucks, and buses to Australia between 2009 and 2012. K-Line pleaded guilty in April 2018 and the fine is the largest ever imposed under the Competition and Consumer Act. The court noted that the penalty should serve as a strong warning to businesses that cartel conduct will not be tolerated and will result in serious consequences.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Commission |first=Australian Competition and Consumer |date=2019-08-02 |title=K-Line convicted of criminal cartel conduct and fined $34.5 million |url=https://www.accc.gov.au/media-release/k-line-convicted-of-criminal-cartel-conduct-and-fined-345-million |access-date=2023-04-19 |website=www.accc.gov.au |language=English}}</ref>
* The practice of stock analyst conference calls and meetings of industry participants almost necessarily results in tremendous amounts of strategic and price transparency. This allows each firm to see how and why every other firm is pricing their products.
* Between 2004 and 2013, Dr Esra Ogru, the former CEO of an Australian biotech company called Phosphagenics, colluded with two colleagues by using false invoicing and credit card reimbursements to defraud her employer of more than $6.1 million.<ref>{{Cite web |title=14-296MR Former CEO and two Melbourne men jailed following theft of millions from Phosphagenics Limited |url=https://asic.gov.au/about-asic/news-centre/find-a-media-release/2014-releases/14-296mr-former-ceo-and-two-melbourne-men-jailed-following-theft-of-millions-from-phosphagenics-limited/ |access-date=2023-04-19 |website=asic.gov.au |language=en}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |title=Combating collusion - Cartels, Monopolies - Australia |url=https://www.mondaq.com/australia/cartels-monopolies/493088/combating-collusion |access-date=2023-04-19 |website=www.mondaq.com}}</ref>
* If the practice of the industry causes more complicated pricing, which is hard for the consumer to understand (such as ], hidden taxes and fees in the wireless industry, negotiable pricing), this can cause competition based on price to be meaningless (because it would be too complicated to explain to the customer in a short advertisement). This causes industries to have essentially the same prices and compete on advertising and image, something theoretically as damaging to consumers as normal price fixing.{{Citation needed|date=September 2011}}
{{See also|Disney litigation}}


== Barriers == == Barriers ==
There can be significant barriers to collusion. In any given industry, these may include: There can be significant barriers to collusion. In any given industry, these may include:


* The number of firms: As the number of firms in an ] increases, it is more difficult to successfully organize, collude and communicate. * '''The number of firms:''' As the number of firms in an ] increases, it is more difficult to successfully organize, collude and communicate.
* Cost and demand differences between firms: If costs vary significantly between firms, it may be impossible to establish a price at which to fix output. Firms generally prefer to produce at a level where marginal cost meets marginal revenue, if one firm can produce at a lower cost, it will prefer to produce more units, and would receive a larger share of profits than its partner in the agreement.<ref name=":0" /> * '''Cost and demand differences between firms:''' If costs vary significantly between firms, it may be impossible to establish a price at which to fix output. Firms generally prefer to produce at a level where marginal cost meets marginal revenue, if one firm can produce at a lower cost, it will prefer to produce more units, and would receive a larger share of profits than its partner in the agreement.<ref name=":0" />
*Asymmetry of information: Colluding firms may not have all the correct information about all other firms, from a quantitative perspective (firms may not know all other firms' cost and demand conditions) or a qualitative perspective (moral hazard). In either situation, firms may not know each others' preferences or actions, and any discrepancy would incentive at least one actor to renege.<ref name=":0" /> *'''Asymmetry of information:''' Colluding firms may not have all the correct information about all other firms, from a quantitative perspective (firms may not know all other firms' cost and demand conditions) or a qualitative perspective (moral hazard). In either situation, firms may not know each others' preferences or actions, and any discrepancy would incentive at least one actor to renege.<ref name=":0" />
* Cheating: There is considerable incentive to cheat on collusion agreements; although lowering prices might trigger ], in the short term the defecting firm may gain considerably. This phenomenon is frequently referred to as "chiseling". * '''Cheating:''' There is considerable incentive to cheat on collusion agreements; although lowering prices might trigger ], in the short term the defecting firm may gain considerably. This phenomenon is frequently referred to as "chiseling".
* Potential entry: New firms may enter the industry, establishing a new baseline price and eliminating collusion (though anti-dumping laws and tariffs can prevent foreign companies from entering the market). * '''Potential entry:''' New firms may enter the industry, establishing a new baseline price and eliminating collusion (though anti-dumping laws and tariffs can prevent foreign companies from entering the market).
* Economic recession: An increase in average total cost or a decrease in revenue provides the incentive to compete with rival firms in order to secure a larger market share and increased demand. * '''Economic recession:''' An increase in average total cost or a decrease in revenue provides the incentive to compete with rival firms in order to secure a larger market share and increased demand.
* Anti-collusion legal framework and ]. Many countries with anti-collusion laws outlaw side-payments, which are an indication of collusion as firms pay each other to incentivize the continuation of the collusive relationship, may see less collusion as firms will likely prefer situations where profits are distributed towards themselves rather than the combined venture.<ref name=":0" /> * '''Anti-collusion legal framework and ].''' Many countries with anti-collusion laws outlaw side-payments, which are an indication of collusion as firms pay each other to incentivize the continuation of the collusive relationship, may see less collusion as firms will likely prefer situations where profits are distributed towards themselves rather than the combined venture.<ref name=":0" />
* '''Leniency Programs:''' Leniency programs are policies that reduce sanctions against collusion if a participant voluntarily confesses their behavior or cooperates with the public authority’s investigation.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Park |first=Sangwon |date=2014 |title=The effect of leniency programs on endogenous collusion |url=https://ideas.repec.org//a/eee/ecolet/v122y2014i2p326-330.html |journal=Economics Letters |language=en |volume=122 |issue=2 |pages=326–330|doi=10.1016/j.econlet.2013.12.014 }}</ref> One example of a leniency program is offering immunity to the first firm who comes clean and gives the government information about collusion.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Emons |first=Winand |date=2020-05-01 |title=The effectiveness of leniency programs when firms choose the degree of collusion |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0167718720300424 |journal=International Journal of Industrial Organization |language=en |volume=70 |pages=102619 |doi=10.1016/j.ijindorg.2020.102619 |issn=0167-7187|hdl=10419/204916 |hdl-access=free }}</ref> These programs are designed to destabilize collusion and increase deterrence by encouraging firms to report illegal behavior.


== Conditions Conducive to Collusion ==
==Government policies to reduce collusion==
There are several industry traits that are thought to be conducive to collusion or empirically associated with collusion. These traits include:
Collusion is when multiple companies reach an agreement to increase prices and profitability, at the expense of consumers. So the government is trying to prevent this from happening, such as the following policies:

* Fines for companies convicted of collusion.
* '''High market concentration:''' High market concentration refers to a market with few firms, which makes it easier for these firms to collude and coordinate their actions.<ref name="Characteristics of Collusive Firms">{{Cite journal |last1=Asch |first1=Peter |last2=Seneca |first2=Joseph J. |date=1975 |title=Characteristics of Collusive Firms |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/2097944 |journal=The Journal of Industrial Economics |volume=23 |issue=3 |pages=223–237 |doi=10.2307/2097944 |jstor=2097944 |issn=0022-1821}}</ref>
* Fines and imprisonment for company executives who are personally liable.
* '''Homogeneous products:''' Homogeneous products refer to products that are similar in nature, which makes it easier for firms to agree on prices and reduces the incentive for firms to compete on ]<ref name="Characteristics of Collusive Firms"/>
* '''Stable demand and/or excess capacity:''' Stable demand and capacity implies predictability and therefore demand and capacity does not fluctuate significantly, which makes it easier for firms to coordinate their actions and maintain a collusive agreement.<ref>Harrington, J. (2015). Some Thoughts on Why Certain Markets are More Susceptible to Collusion.</ref> This can also refer to a situation where firms have more production capacity than is needed to meet demand.<ref>{{Citation |title=Excess capacity and collusion |date=1995 |url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/books/competition-policy/excess-capacity-and-collusion/97E07C97D1DD8ED8486503D6F4E74B62 |work=Competition Policy: A Game-Theoretic Perspective |pages=151–172 |editor-last=Phlips |editor-first=Louis |access-date=2023-04-04 |place=Cambridge |publisher=Cambridge University Press |doi=10.1017/CBO9780511522055.010 |isbn=978-0-521-49871-5|hdl=10419/221034 |hdl-access=free }}</ref>

==Government Intervention==

Collusion often occurs within an ] market structure, which is a type of ]. Therefore, natural market forces alone may be insufficient to prevent or deter collusion, and government intervention is often necessary.

Fortunately, various forms of government intervention can be taken to reduce collusion among firms and promote natural market competition.

* Fines and imprisonment to companies that collude and their executives who are personally liable.
* Detect collusion by screening markets for suspicious pricing activity and high profitability. * Detect collusion by screening markets for suspicious pricing activity and high profitability.
* Provide immunity to the first company to confess and provide the government with information about the collusion.<ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.economicshelp.org/blog/164535/economics/government-policies-to-reduce-collusion/ |title= Government policies to reduce collusion |last=Pettinger |first=Tejvan}}</ref> * Provide immunity (leniency) to the first company to confess and provide the government with information about the collusion.<ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.economicshelp.org/blog/164535/economics/government-policies-to-reduce-collusion/ |title= Government policies to reduce collusion |last=Pettinger |first=Tejvan|date= July 2020 }}</ref>


== See also == == See also ==
* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* ]

== Further reading ==

* Chassang, Sylvain; Ortner, Juan (2023). "]". ''Annual Review of Economics'' '''15''' (1)


== References == == References ==

Latest revision as of 10:01, 25 April 2024

Agreement between two or more parties, sometimes illegal and therefore secretive For a secret agreement by people to commit something criminally or civilly wrong or illegal, see Conspiracy. For other uses, see Collusion (disambiguation).
Competition law
Basic concepts
Anti-competitive practices
Enforcement authorities and organizations

Collusion is a deceitful agreement or secret cooperation between two or more parties to limit open competition by deceiving, misleading or defrauding others of their legal right. Collusion is not always considered illegal. It can be used to attain objectives forbidden by law; for example, by defrauding or gaining an unfair market advantage. It is an agreement among firms or individuals to divide a market, set prices, limit production or limit opportunities. It can involve "unions, wage fixing, kickbacks, or misrepresenting the independence of the relationship between the colluding parties". In legal terms, all acts effected by collusion are considered void.

Definition

In the study of economics and market competition, collusion takes place within an industry when rival companies cooperate for their mutual benefit. Conspiracy usually involves an agreement between two or more sellers to take action to suppress competition between sellers in the market. Because competition among sellers can provide consumers with low prices, conspiracy agreements increase the price consumers pay for the goods. Because of this harm to consumers, it is against antitrust laws to fix prices by agreement between producers, so participants must keep it a secret. Collusion often takes place within an oligopoly market structure, where there are few firms and agreements that have significant impacts on the entire market or industry. To differentiate from a cartel, collusive agreements between parties may not be explicit; however, the implications of cartels and collusion are the same.

Under competition law, there is an important distinction between direct and covert collusion. Direct collusion generally refers to a group of companies communicating directly with each other to coordinate and monitor their actions, such as cooperating through pricing, market allocation, sales quotas, etc. On the other hand, tacit collusion is where companies coordinate and monitor their behavior without direct communication. This type of collusion is generally not considered illegal, so companies guilty of tacit conspiracy should face no penalties even though their actions would have a similar economic impact as explicit conspiracy.

Collusion results from less competition through mutual understanding, where competitors can independently set prices and market share. A core principle of antitrust policy is that companies must not communicate with each other. Even if conversations between multiple companies are illegal but not enforceable, the incentives to comply with collusive agreements are the same with and without communication. It is against competition law for companies to have explicit conversations in private. If evidence of conversations is accidentally left behind, it will become the most critical and conclusive evidence in antitrust litigation. Even without communication, businesses can coordinate prices by observation, but from a legal standpoint, this tacit handling leaves no evidence. Most companies cooperate through invisible collusion, so whether companies communicate is at the core of antitrust policy.

Collusion is illegal in the United States, Canada, Australia and most of the EU due to antitrust laws, but implicit collusion in the form of price leadership and tacit understandings still takes place.

Tacit Collusion

Covert collusion is known as tacit collusion and is considered legal. Adam Smith in The Wealth of Nations explains that since the masters (business owners) are fewer in number, it is easier to collude to serve common interests among those involved, such as maintaining low wages, whilst it is difficult for the labour to coordinate to protect their interests due to their vast numbers. Hence, business owners have a bigger advantage over the working class. Nevertheless, according to Adam Smith, the public rarely hears about coordination and collaborations that occur between business owners as it takes place in informal settings. Some forms of explicit collusion are not considered impactful enough on an individual basis to be considered illegal, such as that which occurred by the social media group WallStreetBets in the GameStop short squeeze. There are many ways that implicit collusion tends to develop:

  • The practice of stock analyst conference calls and meetings of industry participants almost necessarily results in tremendous amounts of strategic and price transparency. This allows each firm to see how and why every other firm is pricing their products.
  • If the practice of the industry causes more complicated pricing, which is hard for the consumer to understand (such as risk-based pricing, hidden taxes and fees in the wireless industry, negotiable pricing), this can cause competition based on price to be meaningless (because it would be too complicated to explain to the customer in a short advertisement). This causes industries to have essentially the same prices and compete on advertising and image, something theoretically as damaging to consumers as normal price fixing.

Base model of (Price) Collusion

For a cartel to work successfully, it must:

  • Co-ordinate on the conspiracy agreement (bargaining, explicit or implicit communication).
  • Monitor compliance.
  • Punish non-compliance.
  • Control the expansion of non-cartel supply.
  • Avoid inspection by customers and competition authorities.

Regarding stability within the cartel:

  • Collusion on high prices means that members have an incentive to deviate.
  • In a one-off situation, high prices are not sustainable.
  • Requires long-term vision and repeated interactions.
  • Companies need to choose between two approaches:
  1. Insist on collusion agreements (now) and promote cooperation (future).
  2. Turn away from the alliance (now) and face punishment (future).
  • Two factors influence this choice: (1) deviations must be detectable (2) penalties for deviations must have a significant effect.
  • Collusion is illegal, contracts between cartels establishing collusion are not protected by law, cannot be enforced by courts, and must have other forms of punishment

Variations

  • π ( P c ) n ( 1 δ ) π ( P c ) 1 n ( 1 δ ) 1 {\displaystyle {\frac {\pi (P_{c})}{n(1-\delta )}}\geq \pi (P_{c})\rightarrow {\frac {1}{n(1-\delta )}}\geq 1}
  • 1 n ( 1 δ ) {\displaystyle 1\geq n(1-\delta )}
  • 1 n n δ {\displaystyle 1\geq n-n\delta }
  • n δ n 1 {\displaystyle n\delta \geq n-1}
  • δ n 1 n {\displaystyle \delta \geq {\frac {n-1}{n}}}

Suppose this market has n {\displaystyle n} firms. At the collusive price, the firms are symmetric, so they divide the profits equally between the whole industry, represented as π ( P c ) n {\displaystyle {\frac {\pi (P_{c})}{n}}} . If and only if the profit of choosing to deviate is greater than that of sticking to collude, i.e.

  • π ( P c ) n ( 1 δ ) π ( P c ) {\displaystyle {\frac {\pi (P_{c})}{n(1-\delta )}}\geq \pi (P_{c})} (Companies have no incentive to deviate unilaterally)
  • Therefore, the cartel alliance will be stable when δ n 1 n {\displaystyle \delta \geq {\frac {n-1}{n}}} is the case, i.e. the firm has no incentive to deviate unilaterally. So as the number of firms increases, the more difficult it is for The Cartel to maintain stability.

As the number of firms in the market increases, so does the factor of the minimum discount required for collusion to succeed.

According to neoclassical price-determination theory and game theory, the independence of suppliers forces prices to their minimum, increasing efficiency and decreasing the price-determining ability of each firm. However if all firms collude to increase prices, loss of sales will be minimized, as consumers lack choices at lower prices and must decide between what is available. This benefits the colluding firms, as they generate more sales at the cost of efficiency to society. However, depending on the assumptions made in the theoretical model on the information available to all firms, there are some outcomes, based on Cooperative Game Theory, where collusion may have higher efficiency than if firms did not collude.

One variation of this traditional theory is the theory of kinked demand. Firms face a kinked demand curve if, when one firm decreases its price, other firms are expected to follow suit to maintain sales. When one firm increases its price, its rivals are unlikely to follow, as they would lose the sales gains they would otherwise receive by holding prices at the previous level. Kinked demand potentially fosters supra-competitive prices because any one firm would receive a reduced benefit from cutting price, as opposed to the benefits accruing under neoclassical theory and certain game-theoretic models such as Bertrand competition.

Collusion may also occur in auction markets, where independent firms coordinate their bids (bid rigging).

Deviation

Future collusive profits

Actions that generate sufficient returns in the future are important to every company, and the probability of continued interaction and the company discount factor must be high enough. The sustainability of cooperation between companies also depends on the threat of punishment, which is also a matter of credibility. Firms that deviate from cooperative pricing will use MMC in each market. MMC increases the loss of deviation, and incremental loss is more important than incremental gain when the firm's objective function is concave. Therefore, the purpose of MMC is to strengthen corporate compliance or inhibit deviant collusion.

The principle of collusion: firms give up deviation gains in the short term in exchange for continued collusion in the future.

  • Collusion occurs when companies place more emphasis on future profits
  • Collusion is easier to sustain when the choice deviates from the maximum profit to be gained is lower (i.e. the penalty profit is lower) and the penalty is greater.
  • Future collusive profits − future punishment profits ≥ current deviation profits − current collusive profits-collusion can sustain.

Scholars in economics and management have tried to identify factors explaining why some firms are more or less likely to be involved in collusion. Some have noted the role of the regulatory environment and the existence of leniency programs.

Indicators

Some actions that may indicate collusion among competitors are:

Examples

Set higher prices
  • In the example in the picture, the dots in Pc and Q represent competitive industry prices. If firms collude, they can limit production to Q2 and raise the price to P2. Collusion usually involves some form of agreement to seek a higher price.
  • When companies discriminate, price collusion is less likely, so the discount factor needed to ensure stability must be increased. In such price competition, competitors use delivered pricing to discriminate in space, but this does not mean that firms using delivered pricing to discriminate cannot collude.

United States

  • Market division and price-fixing among manufacturers of heavy electrical equipment in the 1960s, including General Electric.
  • An attempt by Major League Baseball owners to restrict players' salaries in the mid-1980s.
  • The sharing of potential contract terms by NBA free agents in an effort to help a targeted franchise circumvent the salary cap.
  • Price fixing within food manufacturers providing cafeteria food to schools and the military in 1993.
  • Market division and output determination of livestock feed additive, called lysine, by companies in the US, Japan and South Korea in 1996, Archer Daniels Midland being the most notable of these.
  • Chip dumping in poker or any other card game played for money.
  • Ben and Jerry's and Häagen-Dazs collusion of products in 2013: Ben and Jerry's makes chunkier flavors with more treats in them, while Häagen-Dazs sticks to smoother flavors.
  • Google and Apple against employee poaching, a collusion case in 2015 wherein it was revealed that both companies agreed not to hire employees from one another in order to halt the rise in wages.
  • Google has been hit with a series of antitrust lawsuits. In October 2020, the US Department of Justice filed a landmark lawsuit alleging that Google unlawfully boxed out competitors by reaching deals with phone makers, including Apple and Samsung, to be the default search engine on their devices. Another lawsuit filed by nearly 40 attorneys general on Dec. 17, 2020 alleges that Google’s search results favored its own services over those of more-specialized rivals, a tactic that harmed competitors.

Europe

  • The illegal collusion between the giant German automakers BMW, Daimler and Volkswagen, discovered by the European Commission in 2019, to hinder technological progress in improving the quality of vehicle emissions in order to reduce the cost of production and maximize profits.

Australia

  • Japanese shipping company Kawasaki Kisen Kaisha Ltd (K-Line) were fined $34.5 million by the Federal Court for engaging in criminal cartel conduct. The court found that K-Line participated in a cartel with other shipping companies to fix prices on the transportation of cars, trucks, and buses to Australia between 2009 and 2012. K-Line pleaded guilty in April 2018 and the fine is the largest ever imposed under the Competition and Consumer Act. The court noted that the penalty should serve as a strong warning to businesses that cartel conduct will not be tolerated and will result in serious consequences.
  • Between 2004 and 2013, Dr Esra Ogru, the former CEO of an Australian biotech company called Phosphagenics, colluded with two colleagues by using false invoicing and credit card reimbursements to defraud her employer of more than $6.1 million.

Barriers

There can be significant barriers to collusion. In any given industry, these may include:

  • The number of firms: As the number of firms in an industry increases, it is more difficult to successfully organize, collude and communicate.
  • Cost and demand differences between firms: If costs vary significantly between firms, it may be impossible to establish a price at which to fix output. Firms generally prefer to produce at a level where marginal cost meets marginal revenue, if one firm can produce at a lower cost, it will prefer to produce more units, and would receive a larger share of profits than its partner in the agreement.
  • Asymmetry of information: Colluding firms may not have all the correct information about all other firms, from a quantitative perspective (firms may not know all other firms' cost and demand conditions) or a qualitative perspective (moral hazard). In either situation, firms may not know each others' preferences or actions, and any discrepancy would incentive at least one actor to renege.
  • Cheating: There is considerable incentive to cheat on collusion agreements; although lowering prices might trigger price wars, in the short term the defecting firm may gain considerably. This phenomenon is frequently referred to as "chiseling".
  • Potential entry: New firms may enter the industry, establishing a new baseline price and eliminating collusion (though anti-dumping laws and tariffs can prevent foreign companies from entering the market).
  • Economic recession: An increase in average total cost or a decrease in revenue provides the incentive to compete with rival firms in order to secure a larger market share and increased demand.
  • Anti-collusion legal framework and collusive lawsuit. Many countries with anti-collusion laws outlaw side-payments, which are an indication of collusion as firms pay each other to incentivize the continuation of the collusive relationship, may see less collusion as firms will likely prefer situations where profits are distributed towards themselves rather than the combined venture.
  • Leniency Programs: Leniency programs are policies that reduce sanctions against collusion if a participant voluntarily confesses their behavior or cooperates with the public authority’s investigation. One example of a leniency program is offering immunity to the first firm who comes clean and gives the government information about collusion. These programs are designed to destabilize collusion and increase deterrence by encouraging firms to report illegal behavior.

Conditions Conducive to Collusion

There are several industry traits that are thought to be conducive to collusion or empirically associated with collusion. These traits include:

  • High market concentration: High market concentration refers to a market with few firms, which makes it easier for these firms to collude and coordinate their actions.
  • Homogeneous products: Homogeneous products refer to products that are similar in nature, which makes it easier for firms to agree on prices and reduces the incentive for firms to compete on product differentiation
  • Stable demand and/or excess capacity: Stable demand and capacity implies predictability and therefore demand and capacity does not fluctuate significantly, which makes it easier for firms to coordinate their actions and maintain a collusive agreement. This can also refer to a situation where firms have more production capacity than is needed to meet demand.

Government Intervention

Collusion often occurs within an oligopoly market structure, which is a type of market failure. Therefore, natural market forces alone may be insufficient to prevent or deter collusion, and government intervention is often necessary.

Fortunately, various forms of government intervention can be taken to reduce collusion among firms and promote natural market competition.

  • Fines and imprisonment to companies that collude and their executives who are personally liable.
  • Detect collusion by screening markets for suspicious pricing activity and high profitability.
  • Provide immunity (leniency) to the first company to confess and provide the government with information about the collusion.

See also

Further reading

References

General references

  • Vives, X. (1999) Oligopoly pricing, MIT Press, Cambridge MA (readable; suitable for advanced undergraduates.)
  • Tirole, J. (1988) The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT Press, Cambridge MA (An organized introduction to industrial organization)
  • Tirole, J. (1986), "Hierarchies and Bureaucracies", Journal of Law Economics and Organization, vol. 2, pp. 181–214.
  • Tirole, J. (1992), "Collusion and the Theory of Organizations", Advances in Economic Theory: Proceedings of the Sixth World Congress of the Econometric Society, ed by J.-J. Laffont. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, vol.2:151-206.

Inline citations

  1. O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458: Pearson Prentice Hall. pp. 171. ISBN 0-13-063085-3.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  2. Collusion Law & Legal Definition
  3. Collusion . Archived 2008-01-09 at the Wayback Machine.
  4. ^ "OECD Glossary of Statistical Terms - Collusion Definition". stats.oecd.org. Retrieved 2020-11-01.
  5. Garrod, & Olczak, M. (2018). Explicit vs tacit collusion: The effects of firm numbers and asymmetries. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 56, 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2017.10.006
  6. Fonseca, Miguel A.; Normann, Hans-Theo (2012-11-01). "Explicit vs. tacit collusion—The impact of communication in oligopoly experiments". European Economic Review. 56 (8): 1759–1772. doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2012.09.002. hdl:10871/14991. ISSN 0014-2921.
  7. "A Critique of Political Economy" (PDF).
  8. McConnell, Doug. "Ethics of the GameStop Short Squeeze". University of Oxford.
  9. PricewaterhouseCoopers. "The telecom price wars continue to rage in the global wireless industry". PwC. Retrieved 2023-04-19.
  10. Levenstein, & Suslow, V. Y. (2006). What Determines Cartel Success? Journal of Economic Literature, 44(1), 43–95. https://doi.org/10.1257/002205106776162681
  11. Compte et al., 2002. Olivier Compte, Frederic Jenny, Patrick Rey Capacity, constraints, mergers and collusion European Economic Review, 46 (2002), pp. 1-29
  12. ^ Kalai, Ehud; Satterthwaite, Mark A. (1994), Gilles, Robert P.; Ruys, Pieter H. M. (eds.), "The Kinked Demand Curve, Facilitating Practices, and Oligopolistic Coordination", Imperfections and Behavior in Economic Organizations, Theory and Decision Library, Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands, pp. 15–38, doi:10.1007/978-94-011-1370-0_2, ISBN 978-94-011-1370-0, retrieved 2020-11-01
  13. ^ Roberts, Kevin (1987). "Collusion". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. pp. 1–5. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_22-1. ISBN 978-1-349-95121-5.
  14. Conley, Timothy; Decarolis, Francesco (2016). "Detecting Bidders Groups in Collusive Auctions". American Economic Journal: Microeconomics. 8 (2): 1–38. doi:10.1257/mic.20130254.
  15. ^ Sorenson. (2007). Credible collusion in multimarket oligopoly. Managerial and Decision Economics, 28(2), 115–128. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1314
  16. Morgan, Eleanor J. (2009). "Controlling cartels – Implications of the EU policy reforms". European Management Journal. 27 (1): 1–12. doi:10.1016/j.emj.2008.04.006. ISSN 0263-2373.
  17. Brenner, Steffen (2009). "An empirical study of the European corporate leniency program". International Journal of Industrial Organization. 27 (6): 639–645. doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2009.02.007. ISSN 0167-7187.
  18. Heywood, Li, D., & Ye, G. (2020). Does price discrimination make collusion less likely? a delivered pricing model. Journal of Economics (Vienna, Austria), 131(1), 39–60. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-020-00699-4
  19. Salinger, Lawrence M. (2005). Encyclopedia of white-collar & corporate crime. ISBN 9780761930044.
  20. Hunter-Gault, Charlayne (October 15, 1996). "ADM: Who's Next?". MacNeil/Lehrer Newshour (PBS). https://www.pbs.org/newshour/bb/business/october96/adm_10-15.html Archived 2007-09-30 at the Wayback Machine. Retrieved on 2007-10-17.
  21. "Collusion Strategy and Analysis for Texas Hold'em by T. Hayes". Lybrary.com. Retrieved 2022-12-27.
  22. Sullivan, Christopher John. Three Essays on Product Collusion. Diss. University of Michigan, 2016. https://deepblue.lib.umich.edu/bitstream/handle/2027.42/138544/sullivcj_1.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y
  23. "A Critique of Political Economy". TheGuardian.com. 24 April 2014.
  24. ^ "Google's three antitrust battles: Here's what you need to know". CNET. Retrieved 2023-04-04.
  25. "European Commission finds German automakers illegally colluded on emissions technology". Deutsche Welle.
  26. Commission, Australian Competition and Consumer (2019-08-02). "K-Line convicted of criminal cartel conduct and fined $34.5 million". www.accc.gov.au. Retrieved 2023-04-19.
  27. "14-296MR Former CEO and two Melbourne men jailed following theft of millions from Phosphagenics Limited". asic.gov.au. Retrieved 2023-04-19.
  28. "Combating collusion - Cartels, Monopolies - Australia". www.mondaq.com. Retrieved 2023-04-19.
  29. Park, Sangwon (2014). "The effect of leniency programs on endogenous collusion". Economics Letters. 122 (2): 326–330. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2013.12.014.
  30. Emons, Winand (2020-05-01). "The effectiveness of leniency programs when firms choose the degree of collusion". International Journal of Industrial Organization. 70: 102619. doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2020.102619. hdl:10419/204916. ISSN 0167-7187.
  31. ^ Asch, Peter; Seneca, Joseph J. (1975). "Characteristics of Collusive Firms". The Journal of Industrial Economics. 23 (3): 223–237. doi:10.2307/2097944. ISSN 0022-1821. JSTOR 2097944.
  32. Harrington, J. (2015). Some Thoughts on Why Certain Markets are More Susceptible to Collusion.
  33. Phlips, Louis, ed. (1995), "Excess capacity and collusion", Competition Policy: A Game-Theoretic Perspective, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 151–172, doi:10.1017/CBO9780511522055.010, hdl:10419/221034, ISBN 978-0-521-49871-5, retrieved 2023-04-04
  34. Pettinger, Tejvan (July 2020). "Government policies to reduce collusion".
Topics of game theory
Definitions
Equilibrium
concepts
Strategies
Classes
of games
Games
Theorems
Key
figures
Search optimizations
Miscellaneous
Corruption
Corruption in different fields
Measures of corruption
Forms or aspects
of corruption
General
State
Elections
Institutions dealing
with corruption
International
National
Anti-corruption
Laws and
enforcement
International
instruments
and efforts
Protest
movements
Categories: