Revision as of 16:37, 11 February 2005 editAhoerstemeier (talk | contribs)110,683 editsm Reverted edits by 63.149.167.101 to last version by Suruena← Previous edit | Revision as of 12:56, 24 December 2024 edit undoGermanydeurdj373 (talk | contribs)51 edits →ModernityTags: Mobile edit Mobile web editNext edit → | ||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{Short description|Economic system based on private ownership}} | |||
'''Capitalism''' generally refers to | |||
{{About|an economic system}} | |||
{{Redirect|Capitalist|other uses|Capitalist (disambiguation)}} | |||
{{Pp-pc|small=yes}} | |||
{{Use American English|date=January 2014}} | |||
{{Use dmy dates|date=June 2020}} | |||
{{Capitalism sidebar}} | |||
{{Economics sidebar}} | |||
{{Economic systems sidebar|expanded=by ideology}} | |||
{{Liberalism sidebar}} | |||
{{Neoliberalism sidebar}} | |||
'''Capitalism''' is an ] based on the ] of the ] and their operation for ].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Zimbalist |last2=Sherman |last3=Brown |first1=Andrew |first2=Howard J. |first3=Stuart |title=Comparing Economic Systems: A Political-Economic Approach |publisher=] |date=October 1988 |isbn=978-0-15-512403-5 |pages= |quote=Pure capitalism is defined as a system wherein all of the means of production (physical capital) are privately owned and run by the capitalist class for a profit, while most other people are workers who work for a salary or wage (and who do not own the capital or the product). |url=https://archive.org/details/comparingeconomi0000zimb_q8i6/page/6}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Rosser |first1=Mariana V. |last2=Rosser |first2=J Barkley |title=Comparative Economics in a Transforming World Economy |publisher=] |date=23 July 2003 |isbn=978-0-262-18234-8 |page=7 |quote=In capitalist economies, land and produced means of production (the capital stock) are owned by private individuals or groups of private individuals organized as firms.}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |first=Chris |last=Jenks |title=Core Sociological Dichotomies |quote=Capitalism, as a mode of production, is an economic system of manufacture and exchange which is geared toward the production and sale of commodities within a market for profit, where the manufacture of commodities consists of the use of the formally free labor of workers in exchange for a wage to create commodities in which the manufacturer extracts surplus value from the labor of the workers in terms of the difference between the wages paid to the worker and the value of the commodity produced by him/her to generate that profit. |location=London; Thousand Oaks, CA; New Delhi |publisher=] |page=383}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |title=The Challenge of Global Capitalism : The World Economy in the 21st Century |last=Gilpin |first=Robert |author-link=Robert Gilpin |isbn=978-0-691-18647-4 |oclc=1076397003 |date=2018|publisher=Princeton University Press }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Sternberg |first1=Elaine |title=Defining Capitalism |journal=] |date=2015 |volume=35 |issue=3 |pages=380–396 |doi=10.1111/ecaf.12141|s2cid=219373247 | issn = 0265-0665}}</ref> The defining characteristics of capitalism include ], ], ]s, ]s, recognition of ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], a ] that makes possible ] and ], ], ], ], ], production of ] and ]s, and a strong emphasis on ] and ].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Heilbroner |first1=Robert L. |title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics |date=2018 |publisher=] |location=London |isbn=978-1-349-95189-5 |pages=1378–1389 |url=https://link.springer.com/referenceworkentry/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_154 |language=en |chapter=Capitalism |doi=10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_154}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Hodgson |first1=Geoffrey M. |title=Conceptualizing Capitalism: Institutions, Evolution, Future |date=2015 |publisher=] |location=Chicago |isbn=9780226168142 |url=https://press.uchicago.edu/ucp/books/book/chicago/C/bo18523749.html}}</ref><ref name = "harris">{{cite journal |last1=Harris |first1=Neal |last2=Delanty |first2=Gerard |title=What is capitalism? Toward a working definition |journal=] |date=2023 |volume=62 |issue=3 |pages=323–344 |doi=10.1177/05390184231203878 |doi-access=free}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Berend |first1=Ivan T. |title=Capitalism |journal=] |date=2015 |pages=94–98 |doi=10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.62003-2|isbn=978-0-08-097087-5 }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Antonio |first1=Robert J. |last2=Bonanno |first2=Alessandro |title=Capitalism |journal=The Wiley-Blackwell Encyclopedia of Globalization |date=2012 |doi=10.1002/9780470670590.wbeog060|isbn=978-1-4051-8824-1 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Beamish |first1=Rob |chapter=Capitalism |title=Core Concepts in Sociology |date=2018 |pages=17–22 |doi=10.1002/9781394260331.ch6|isbn=978-1-119-16861-4 }}</ref> In a ], decision-making and investments are determined by owners of wealth, property, or ability to maneuver capital or production ability in ] and ]s—whereas prices and the distribution of goods and services are mainly determined by competition in goods and services markets.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Gregory |first1=Paul |last2=Stuart |first2=Robert |year=2013 |title=The Global Economy and its Economic Systems |publisher=] |page=41 |isbn=978-1-285-05535-0 |quote=Capitalism is characterized by private ownership of the factors of production. Decision making is decentralized and rests with the owners of the factors of production. Their decision making is coordinated by the market, which provides the necessary information. Material incentives are used to motivate participants.}}</ref> | |||
* in ] and ], a social system based on the principle of individual ], including ]. | |||
Economists, historians, political economists, and sociologists have adopted different perspectives in their analyses of capitalism and have recognized various forms of it in practice. These include '']'' or ], ], ], and ]. Different ] feature varying degrees of ]s, ],<ref name="gregorystuart">{{cite book|last1=Gregory |first1=Paul |last2=Stuart |first2=Robert |title=The Global Economy and its Economic Systems |publisher=] |date=2013 |isbn=978-1-285-05535-0 |page=107 |quote=Real-world capitalist systems are mixed, some having higher shares of public ownership than others. The mix changes when privatization or nationalization occurs. Privatization is when property that had been state-owned is transferred to private owners. ] occurs when privately owned property becomes publicly owned.}}</ref> obstacles to free competition, and state-sanctioned ]. The degree of ] in ] and the role of ] and ], as well as the scope of state ownership, vary across different models of capitalism.<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54">{{cite book |title=Macmillan Dictionary of Modern Economics |edition=3rd |date=1986 |pages=54}}</ref><ref>{{cite magazine |last=Bronk |first=Richard |title=Which model of capitalism?|url=http://oecdobserver.org/news/archivestory.php/aid/345/Which_model_of_capitalism_.html |url-status=live |magazine=] |publisher=] |date=Summer 2000 |volume=1999 |issue=221–222 |pages=12–15 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180406200423/http://oecdobserver.org/news/archivestory.php/aid/345/Which_model_of_capitalism_.html |archive-date=6 April 2018 |access-date=6 April 2018}}</ref> The extent to which different markets are free and the rules defining private property are matters of politics and policy. Most of the existing capitalist economies are ] that combine elements of free markets with state intervention and in some cases ].<ref name="Stilwell">{{cite book |last=Stilwell |first=Frank |author-link=Frank Stilwell (economist) |title=Political Economy: the Contest of Economic Ideas |edition=1st |publisher=] |location=Melbourne, Australia |date=2002}}</ref> | |||
* in ], a combination of ] practices that became institutionalized in ] between the ] and ] centuries, especially involving the right of individuals and groups of individuals acting as "legal persons" (or ]) to buy and sell ] goods such as ], ], and ] (see ] and ]), in a ] (see ]), and relying on the enforcement by the state of ] rights rather than ] obligations. | |||
Capitalism in its modern form emerged from ] in ], as well as ] practices by European countries between the 16th and 18th centuries. The Industrial Revolution of the 18th century established ], characterized by ] and a complex ]. Through the process of ], capitalism spread across the world in the 19th and 20th centuries, especially before World War I and after the end of the Cold War. During the 19th century, capitalism was largely unregulated by the state, but became more regulated in the post–] period through ], followed by a return of more unregulated capitalism starting in the 1980s through ]. | |||
* additionally, it may mean competing theories that developed in the ], in the context of the ], and ], in the context of the ], meant to justify the private ownership of ], to explain the operation of such markets, and to guide the application or elimination of ] ] of property and markets. (See ], ], ]) | |||
The existence of market economies has been observed under many ] and across a vast array of ], ]s, and cultural contexts. The modern industrial capitalist societies that exist today developed in Western Europe as a result of the Industrial Revolution. The accumulation of capital is the primary mechanism through which capitalist economies promote ]. However, it is a characteristic of such economies that they experience a ] of ] followed by recessions.<ref name = "HP">{{cite journal |last1=Hodrick |first1=R. |last2=Prescott|first2= E. |year=1997 |title=Postwar US business cycles: An empirical investigation |journal=Journal of Money, Credit and Banking|volume=29|issue=1 |pages=1–16|doi=10.2307/2953682 |jstor=2953682 |s2cid=154995815 | url = http://www.kellogg.northwestern.edu/research/math/papers/451.pdf}}</ref> | |||
* a belief in the advantages of such practices. | |||
== Etymology == | == Etymology == | ||
The term "capitalist", meaning an owner of ], appears earlier than the term "capitalism" and dates to the mid-17th century. "Capitalism" is derived from ''capital'', which evolved from {{lang|la|capitale}}, a late ] word based on {{lang|la|caput}}, meaning "head"—which is also the origin of "]" and "]" in the sense of movable property (only much later to refer only to livestock). {{lang|la|Capitale}} emerged in the 12th to 13th centuries to refer to funds, stock of merchandise, sum of money or money carrying interest.<ref name="Braudel-1979">{{cite book |last=Braudel |first=Fernand |author-link=Fernand Braudel |title=The Wheels of Commerce: Civilization and Capitalism 15th–18th Century |publisher=] |date=1979}}</ref>{{rp|232}}<ref name="OED-93">]. "Capital". . ''Oxford English Press''. {{abbr|Vol.|Volume}} 2. p. 93.</ref> By 1283, it was used in the sense of the capital assets of a trading firm and was often interchanged with other words—wealth, money, funds, goods, assets, property and so on.<ref name="Braudel-1979" />{{rp|233}} | |||
The lexical roots of the word '''capital''' reveal roots in the trade and ownership of animals. The ] root of the word '''capital''' is ''capitalis'', from the ] ''kaput'', which means "head", this being how wealth was measured. The more heads of cattle, the better. The terms ''chattel'' (meaning goods, animals, or slaves) and even ''cattle'' itself also derive from this same origin. | |||
The ''Hollantse ({{langx|de|holländische}}) Mercurius'' uses "capitalists" in 1633 and 1654 to refer to owners of capital.<ref name="Braudel-1979" />{{rp|234}} In French, ] referred to ''capitalistes'' in 1788,<ref>E.g., "L'Angleterre a-t-elle l'heureux privilège de n'avoir ni Agioteurs, ni Banquiers, ni Faiseurs de services, ni Capitalistes ?" in (1788) ''De la foi publique envers les créanciers de l'état : lettres à M. Linguet sur le n° CXVI de ses annales'' {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150319071130/http://books.google.com/books?id=ESMVAAAAQAAJ&pg=PA19 |date=19 March 2015 }}</ref> four years before its first recorded English usage by ] in his work ''Travels in France'' (1792).<ref name="OED-93" /><ref>Arthur Young. .</ref> In his '']'' (1817), ] referred to "the capitalist" many times.<ref>Ricardo, David. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. 1821. John Murray Publisher, 3rd edition.</ref> English poet ] used "capitalist" in his work ''Table Talk'' (1823).<ref>Samuel Taylor Coleridge. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200223123202/https://books.google.com/books?id=ma-4W-XiGkIC |date=23 February 2020 }}. p. 267.</ref> ] used the term in his first work, '']'' (1840), to refer to the owners of capital. ] used the term in his 1845 work '']''.<ref name="OED-93" /> ] used "capitalist" in his ] presented to the United States Congress in 1791. | |||
The lexical connections between animal trade and economics can also be seen in the names of many currencies and words about money: fee (''faihu''), rupee (''rupya''), buck (a deerskin), pecuniary (''pecu''), stock (''livestock''), and peso (''pecu'' or ''pashu'') all derive from animal-trade origins. | |||
The initial use of the term "capitalism" in its modern sense is attributed to ] in 1850 ("What I call 'capitalism' that is to say the appropriation of capital by some to the exclusion of others") and Pierre-Joseph Proudhon in 1861 ("Economic and social regime in which capital, the source of income, does not generally belong to those who make it work through their labor").<ref name="Braudel-1979" />{{rp|237}} ] frequently referred to the "]" and to the "capitalist mode of production" in '']'' (1867).<ref>{{cite book |last=Saunders |first=Peter |date=1995 |title=Capitalism |publisher=] |page=1}}</ref><ref name=":0">MEW, 23, & Das Kapital. Kritik der politischen Oekonomie. Erster Band-Verlag von Otto Meissner (1867)</ref> Marx did not use the form ''capitalism'' but instead used ], ''capitalist'' and ''capitalist mode of production'', which appear frequently.<ref name=":0" /><ref>The use of the word "capitalism" appears in ''Theories of Surplus Value'', volume II. ToSV was edited by Kautsky.</ref> Due to the word being coined by socialist critics of capitalism, economist and historian ] stated that the term "capitalism" itself is a term of disparagement and a misnomer for ].<ref>Hessen, Robert (2008) "Capitalism", in Henderson, David R. (ed.) ''The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics'' p. 57</ref> ] agrees with the statement that the term is a misnomer, adding that it misleadingly suggests that there is such a thing as "]" that inherently functions in certain ways and is governed by stable economic laws of its own.<ref>Harcourt, Bernard E. (2020) ''For Coöperation and the Abolition of Capital, Or, How to Get Beyond Our Extractive Punitive Society and Achieve a Just Society'', Rochester, NY: Columbia Public Law Research Paper No. 14-672, p. 31</ref> | |||
The first use of the word "capitalism" in English is by ] in ], by which he meant having ownership of capital. In ] ] used the term "capitalist" to refer to owners of capital, and Marx and Engels refer to the "Capitalist production system" and in '']'' to ''"Kapitalisten"'', "capitalists" (meaning the private owners of the means of production). By the early ] the term had become widespread, as evidenced by ]'s use of the term in his '']'' in ], and ]'s ] ''Modern Capitalism''. The ] cites the use of the term "private Capitalism" by ], German-American Socialist and ] in the late ], in an ] work entitled "Better Times", and a citation by an unknown author in ] in the pages of ] magazine. | |||
In the ], the term "capitalism" first appears, according to the '']'' (OED), in 1854, in the novel '']'' by novelist ], where the word meant "having ownership of capital".<ref name="OED-94">]. "Capitalism" p. 94.</ref> Also according to the OED, ], a ] ] and ], used the term "private capitalism" in 1863. | |||
==History of capitalism== | |||
''Main article: ]'' | |||
Other terms sometimes used for capitalism are: | |||
* ]<ref>{{cite book |last=Mandel |first=Ernst |author-link=Ernst Mandel |title=An Introduction to Marxist Economic Theory |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Pf9Jd1sIMJ0C&pg=PA24 |year=2002 |publisher=] |isbn=978-1-876646-30-1 |page=24 |access-date=29 January 2017 |archive-date=15 February 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170215160137/https://books.google.com/books?id=Pf9Jd1sIMJ0C&pg=PA24 |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
* ] | |||
* ]<ref>{{cite journal |title=Adam Smith and His Legacy for Modern Capitalism |last=Werhane |first=P. H. |journal=The Review of Metaphysics |volume=47 |year=1994 |issue=3}}</ref> | |||
* ] | |||
* Free enterprise<ref name="rogetfreeenterprise">{{cite encyclopedia |title=Free enterprise |encyclopedia=Roget's 21st Century Thesaurus |edition=Third |publisher=Philip Lief Group |date=2008}}</ref>{{page needed|date=July 2021}} | |||
* ] | |||
* Free enterprise economy<ref name="britannica" /> | |||
* ]<ref name="rogetfreeenterprise" />{{page needed|date=July 2021}} | |||
* Free market economy<ref name="britannica" /> | |||
* '']''<ref name=Barrons>{{cite book |title=Barrons Dictionary of Finance and Investment Terms |date=1995 |page=74}}</ref> | |||
* ]<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |url=https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/market%20economy |title=Market economy |dictionary=Merriam-Webster Unabridged Dictionary}}</ref> | |||
* Profits system<ref>{{cite book |last=Shutt |first=Harry |title=Beyond the Profits System: Possibilities for the Post-Capitalist Era |publisher=] |year=2010 |isbn=978-1-84813-417-1}}</ref>{{page needed|date=July 2021}} | |||
* Self-regulating market<ref name="rogetfreeenterprise" />{{page needed|date=July 2021}} | |||
== Definition == | |||
==History of theory of capitalism== | |||
There is no universally agreed upon definition of capitalism; it is unclear whether or not capitalism characterizes an entire society, a specific type of social order, or crucial | |||
''Main article: ]'' | |||
components or elements of a society.<ref name="wolf">{{cite encyclopedia |last=Wolf |first=Harald |editor1-last=Ritzer |editor1-first=George|title=Capitalism |encyclopedia=Encyclopedia of Social Theory|pages=76–80|date=2004 |publisher=Sage Publications|isbn=978-1-4522-6546-9}}</ref> Societies officially founded in opposition to capitalism (such as the ]) have sometimes been argued to actually exhibit characteristics of capitalism.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Howard |first1=M.C. |last2=King |first2=J.E. |title='State Capitalism' in the Soviet Union |journal=History of Economics Review |date=January 2001 |volume=34 |issue=1 |pages=110–126 |doi=10.1080/10370196.2001.11733360 |s2cid=42809979 |url=https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/pdf/10.1080/10370196.2001.11733360 |language=en |issn=1037-0196}}</ref> ] describes usage of the term "capitalism" by many authors as "mainly rhetorical, functioning less as an actual concept than as a gesture toward the | |||
need for a concept".<ref name="harris"/> Scholars who are uncritical of capitalism rarely actually use the term "capitalism".<ref name="delacroix">{{cite encyclopedia |last=Delacroix |first=Jacques |editor1-last=Ritzer |editor1-first=George |title=Capitalism |encyclopedia=Encyclopedia of Social Theory|date=2007 |publisher=Wiley|doi=10.1002/9781405165518.wbeosc004 |isbn=978-1-4051-2433-1|url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/9781405165518.wbeosc004}}</ref> | |||
Some doubt that the term "capitalism" possesses valid scientific dignity,<ref name="wolf"/> and it is generally not discussed in ],<ref name="harris"/> with economist ] suggesting that the term "capitalism" should be abandoned entirely.<ref>{{cite book |last=Acemoglu |first=Daron |date=2017 |editor1-last=Frey |editor1-first=Bruno S.|editor2-last = Iselin|editor2-first = David |title=Economic Ideas You Should Forget |publisher=Springer|pages=1–3 |chapter=Capitalism|doi=10.1007/978-3-319-47458-8_1 |isbn=978-3-319-47457-1|chapter-url=https://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007/978-3-319-47458-8_1}}</ref> Consequently, understanding of the concept of capitalism tends to be heavily influenced by opponents of capitalism and by the followers and critics of Karl Marx.<ref name="delacroix"/> | |||
== History == | |||
The conception of what constitutes capitalism has changed significantly over time, as well as varying depending on the political perspective and analytical approach taken. ] focussed on the role of enlightened self-interest (the "invisible hand") and the role of ] in making capital accumulation efficient. Some proponents of capitalism (like ]) emphasize the role of ]s, which they claim promote ] between individuals, innovation, economic growth, and ]. For many (like ]), capitalism hinges on the elaboration of an economic system in which ] are traded in ]s, and ]s belong to non-state entities, onto a global scale. For others (like ]), it is defined by the creation of a ] in which most people have to sell their ] in order to survive. As Marx argued (see also ]), capitalism is also distinguished from other market economies with private ownership by the concentration of the means of production in the hands of a few. | |||
{{Main|History of capitalism}} | |||
] (pictured in a 16th-century portrait by ]) built an international financial empire and was one of the first ]ers.]] | |||
], the centre of early capitalism<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |last1=Behringer |first1=Wolfgang |contribution=Core and Periphery: The Holy Roman Empire as a Communication(s) Universe |title=The Holy Roman Empire, 1495–1806 |date=2011 |publisher=Oxford University Press |location=Oxford |isbn=978-0-19-960297-1 |pages=347–358|url=https://perspectivia.net/servlets/MCRFileNodeServlet/pnet_derivate_00004689/behringer_core.pdf |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20221009/https://perspectivia.net/servlets/MCRFileNodeServlet/pnet_derivate_00004689/behringer_core.pdf |archive-date=9 October 2022 |url-status=live |access-date=7 August 2022}}</ref>]] | |||
Capitalism, in its modern form, can be traced to the emergence of agrarian capitalism and mercantilism in the early ], in city-states like ].<ref>{{cite news |url=http://www.economist.com/node/13484709 |title=Cradle of capitalism |newspaper=] |date=16 April 2009 |access-date=9 March 2015 |archive-date=18 January 2018 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180118055643/http://www.economist.com/node/13484709 |url-status=live}}</ref> ] has existed incipiently on a small scale for centuries<ref name="WarburtonDavid">{{cite book |last=Warburton |first=David |title=Macroeconomics from the beginning: The General Theory, Ancient Markets, and the Rate of Interest |location=Paris |publisher=Recherches et Publications |date=2003 |pages=49}}</ref> in the form of merchant, renting and lending activities and occasionally as small-scale industry with some wage labor. Simple ] exchange and consequently simple commodity production, which is the initial basis for the growth of capital from trade, have a very long history. During the ], ] promulgated capitalist economic policies such as free trade and banking. Their use of ] facilitated ]. These innovations migrated to Europe through trade partners in cities such as Venice and Pisa. Italian ] traveled the Mediterranean talking to Arab traders and returned to popularize the use of Indo-Arabic numerals in Europe.<ref name="Koehler, Benedikt">{{cite book |last=Koehler |first=Benedikt |title=Early Islam and the Birth of Capitalism |quote=In Baghdad, by the early tenth century a fully-fledged banking sector had come into being... |pages=2 |publisher=] |date=2014}}</ref> | |||
==How capitalism works== | |||
=== Example of Starting a Business === | |||
The following example introduces many of the ideas involved in capitalism. When starting a ], the initial owners or investors typically provide some money (the ]) which is used by the business to buy or ] some means of production. For example, the enterprise may buy or ] a piece of land and a building; it may buy machinery and hire workers (]). The commodities produced by the workers become the property of the capitalist ("capitalist" in this context refers to a person who has capital, rather than a person who favors capitalism), and are sold by the workers on behalf of the capitalist. The money from sales also becomes the property of the capitalist. The workers deposit the money into the capitalist's bank account. Once the capitalist receives this money, he or she pays the workers a portion for their labor, pays other overhead costs, and keeps the rest as ]. If more money is needed than the initial owners are willing or able to provide, the business may need to borrow a limited amount of extra money with a promise to pay it back with interest -- in effect it may rent more ]. The business is granted a degree of legal authority, and control, over a set of ] (as economists call them). The business can register as a ], meaning that it can act as a type of virtual person in many matters before the law (see ] for listing of such entities). The owners can pay themselves some of the income derived from the business (]s), sell shares of ] in the ], or they can sell all of the equipment, land, and other assets, and split the proceeds between them. | |||
=== |
=== Agrarianism === | ||
The economic foundations of the feudal agricultural system began to shift substantially in 16th-century England as the ] had broken down and land began to become concentrated in the hands of fewer landlords with increasingly large estates. Instead of a ]-based system of labor, workers were increasingly employed as part of a broader and expanding money-based economy. The system put pressure on both landlords and tenants to increase the productivity of agriculture to make profit; the weakened coercive power of the ] to extract peasant ] encouraged them to try better methods, and the tenants also had incentive to improve their methods in order to flourish in a competitive ]. Terms of rent for land were becoming subject to economic market forces rather than to the previous stagnant system of custom and feudal obligation.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Brenner |first1=Robert |title=The Agrarian Roots of European Capitalism |journal=] |date=1 January 1982 |issue=97 |pages=16–113 |doi=10.1093/past/97.1.16 |jstor=650630}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=http://monthlyreview.org/1998/07/01/the-agrarian-origins-of-capitalism |title=The Agrarian Origins of Capitalism |access-date=17 December 2012 |date=July 1998 |archive-date=11 December 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191211183143/https://monthlyreview.org/1998/07/01/the-agrarian-origins-of-capitalism/ |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
Traditionally, capitalist economies have had corporations working along the lines of the above example existing in parallel with other types of organisation such as governments, sole traders, partnerships and sometimes ]s, credit unions, and other entities. Observers do not always agree which of these organisations, or which features of them are part of capitalism, although most often companies, or many features of their operation, are included as part of the definition. | |||
=== Mercantilism === | |||
Additionally, many of the characteristics and techniques of business workings in the above example existed before capitalism, and many have continued to be added. So this leaves much room for debate. However, many people agree that it was around the time when share-trading in ] became common and widely understood that capitalism can be said to have begun, even though there is often disagreement that it was the share-trading itself that defined capitalism. Such share trading first took place widely in Europe during the 17th century and continued to develop and spread thereafter, although the word "capitalism" itself did not come into use until the 19th century. | |||
{{Main|Mercantilism}} | |||
]]] | |||
] with the ] after the ] which began the British rule in ]]] | |||
The economic doctrine prevailing from the 16th to the 18th centuries is commonly called ].<ref name=GSGB>{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Pf9Jd1sIMJ0C |title=An Introduction to Marxist Economic Theory |date= 2002 |publisher=] |via=] |isbn=978-1-876646-30-1 |access-date=27 August 2016 |archive-date=11 December 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161211173733/https://books.google.com/books?id=Pf9Jd1sIMJ0C |url-status=live}}</ref><ref name="Burnham">{{cite book |last=Burnham |first=Peter |author-link=Peter Burnham |title=Capitalism: The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics |publisher=] |year=2003}}</ref> This period, the ], was associated with the geographic exploration of foreign lands by merchant traders, especially from England and the ]. Mercantilism was a system of trade for profit, although commodities were still largely produced by non-capitalist methods.<ref name="Scott" /> Most scholars consider the era of merchant capitalism and mercantilism as the origin of modern capitalism,<ref name="Burnham"/><ref name="Encyclopædia Britannica 2006">''Encyclopædia Britannica'' (2006)</ref> although ] argued that the hallmark of capitalism is the establishment of generalized markets for what he called the "fictitious commodities", i.e. land, labor and money. Accordingly, he argued that "not until 1834 was a competitive labor market established in England, hence industrial capitalism as a social system cannot be said to have existed before that date".<ref>{{cite book |last=Polanyi |first=Karl |author-link=Karl Polanyi |title=The Great Transformation |publisher=] |location=Boston |date=1944 |pages=87}}</ref> | |||
England began a large-scale and integrative approach to mercantilism during the ] (1558–1603). A systematic and coherent explanation of balance of trade was made public through ]'s argument ''England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, or the Balance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of Our Treasure.'' It was written in the 1620s and published in 1664.<ref>{{cite book |first1=David |last1=Onnekink |first2=Gijs |last2=Rommelse |title=Ideology and Foreign Policy in Early Modern Europe (1650–1750) |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=M1QdbzdTimsC&pg=PA257 |year=2011 |publisher=] |page=257 |isbn=978-1-4094-1914-3 |access-date=27 June 2015 |archive-date=19 March 2015 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150319130220/http://books.google.com/books?id=M1QdbzdTimsC&pg=PA257 |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
One can view shares as converting company ownership into a commodity - the ownership rights are divided into units (the shares) for ease of trading in them. In a similar way, one can view ] as a commoditisation of debt. Other financial instruments have come into being since the early years of capitalism that have commoditised fluctuations in markets, future prices, classes of items, and many other things. Increases in communications technologies have helped facilitate an increase in the number and availability of financial instruments, and the ease of trading. | |||
European ]s, backed by state controls, subsidies and ], made most of their profits by buying and selling goods. In the words of ], the purpose of mercantilism was "the opening and well-balancing of trade; the cherishing of manufacturers; the banishing of idleness; the repressing of waste and excess by sumptuary laws; the improvement and husbanding of the soil; the regulation of prices...".<ref>Quoted in {{cite book |first=George |last=Clark |title=The Seventeenth Century |location=New York |publisher=] |date=1961 |page=24}}</ref> | |||
In the bulk of capitalist economies, a predominant proportion of productive capacity has belonged to corporate bodies such as companies. Therefore, to a large degree, authority over productive capacity has resided with the owners of companies. Within legal limits and the financial means available to them, the owners of each company can decide how it will operate. This normally includes deciding the following things (among many others): | |||
After the period of the ], the ] and the ], after massive contributions from the ],<ref name="Prakash">], "", ''History of World Trade Since 1450'', edited by ], vol. 1, Macmillan Reference USA, 2006, pp. 237–240, ''World History in Context''. Retrieved 3 August 2017</ref><ref name="ray">{{cite book |first=Indrajit |last=Ray |year=2011 |title=Bengal Industries and the British Industrial Revolution (1757–1857) |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=CHOrAgAAQBAJ&pg=PA57 |publisher=] |pages=57, 90, 174 |isbn=978-1-136-82552-1 |access-date=20 June 2019 |archive-date=29 May 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160529021839/https://books.google.com/books?id=CHOrAgAAQBAJ |url-status=live}}</ref> inaugurated an expansive era of commerce and trade.<ref name=Banaji>{{cite journal |last=Banaji |first=Jairus |year=2007 |title=Islam, the Mediterranean and the rise of capitalism |journal=] |volume=15 |pages=47–74 |doi=10.1163/156920607X171591 |url=http://eprints.soas.ac.uk/15983/1/Islam%20and%20capitalism.pdf |access-date=20 April 2018 |archive-date=29 March 2018 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180329015002/http://eprints.soas.ac.uk/15983/1/Islam%20and%20capitalism.pdf |url-status=dead}}</ref><ref name="britannica2">{{cite book |title=Economic system:: Market systems |url=https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/178493/economic-system/61117/Market-systems#toc242146 |publisher=Encyclopædia Britannica |year=2006 |access-date=4 January 2009 |archive-date=24 May 2009 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090524075921/https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/178493/economic-system/61117/Market-systems#toc242146 |url-status=live}}</ref> These companies were characterized by their ] and ] powers given to them by nation-states.<ref name="Banaji" /> During this era, merchants, who had traded under the previous stage of mercantilism, invested capital in the East India Companies and other colonies, seeking a ]. | |||
* which land production will take place on, | |||
=== Industrial Revolution === | |||
* how many people to employ, | |||
{{Main|Industrial Revolution}} | |||
], fuelled primarily by ], propelled the ] in ].<ref>Watt steam engine image located in the lobby of the Superior Technical School of Industrial Engineers of the ]{{clarify|date=April 2016}} (]).</ref>]] | |||
In the mid-18th century a group of economic theorists, led by ] (1711–1776)<ref>{{cite book |last=Hume |first=David |author-link=David Hume |title=Political Discourses |url=https://archive.org/details/McGillLibrary-125702-2590 |location=Edinburgh |publisher=A. Kincaid & A. Donaldson |year=1752}}</ref> and ] (1723–1790), challenged fundamental mercantilist doctrines—such as the belief that the world's wealth remained constant and that a state could only increase its wealth at the expense of another state. | |||
During the ], ] replaced merchants as a dominant factor in the capitalist system and effected the decline of the traditional handicraft skills of ]s, guilds and ]. Industrial capitalism marked the development of the ] of manufacturing, characterized by a complex ] between and within work process and the routine of work tasks; and eventually established the domination of the ].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Burnham |first1=Peter |author1-link=Peter Burnham |year=1996 |chapter=Capitalism |editor1-last=McLean |editor1-first=Iain |editor2-last=McMillan |editor2-first=Alistair |title=The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=8JkyAwAAQBAJ |series=Oxford Quick Reference |edition=3 |location=Oxford |publisher=] |publication-date=2009 |isbn=978-0-19-101827-5 |access-date=14 September 2019 |quote=Industrial capitalism, which Marx dates from the last third of the eighteenth century, finally establishes the domination of the capitalist mode of production. |archive-date=27 July 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200727163404/https://books.google.com/books?id=8JkyAwAAQBAJ |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
* what activities employees will do, | |||
Industrial Britain eventually abandoned the ] policy formerly prescribed by mercantilism. In the 19th century, ] (1804–1865) and ] (1811–1889), who based their beliefs on the ], initiated a movement to lower ].<ref name="laissezf">{{cite web |title=Laissez-faire |url=http://www.bartleby.com/65/la/laissezf.html |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081202050426/http://www.bartleby.com/65/la/laissezf.html |archive-date=2 December 2008}}</ref> In the 1840s Britain adopted a less protectionist policy, with the 1846 repeal of the ] and the 1849 repeal of the ].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Burnham |first1=Peter |author1-link=Peter Burnham |year=1996 |chapter=Capitalism |editor1-last=McLean |editor1-first=Iain |editor2-last=McMillan |editor2-first=Alistair |title=The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=8JkyAwAAQBAJ |series=Oxford Quick Reference |edition=3 |location=Oxford |publisher=] |publication-date=2009 |isbn=978-0-19-101827-5 |access-date=14 September 2019 |quote=For most analysts, mid- to late-nineteenth century Britain is seen as the apotheosis of the laissez-faire phase of capitalism. This phase took off in Britain in the 1840s with the repeal of the Corn Laws, and the Navigation Acts, and the passing of the Banking Act. |archive-date=27 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200727163404/https://books.google.com/books?id=8JkyAwAAQBAJ |url-status=live}}</ref> Britain reduced tariffs and ], in line with David Ricardo's advocacy of ]. | |||
* which machines and tools to use for production. | |||
=== Modernity === | |||
In larger companies, authority is usually delegated in a hierarchical or ] system of ]. When company ownership is spread among many shareholders, the shareholders generally have votes in the exercise of authority over the company in proportion to the size of their share of ownership. | |||
] formed the financial basis of the international economy from 1870 to 1914.]] | |||
Broader processes of ] carried capitalism across the world. By the beginning of the nineteenth century, a series of loosely connected market systems had come together as a relatively integrated global system, in turn intensifying processes of economic and other globalization.<ref name="SAGE Publications">{{cite book |year=2007 |last1=James |first1=Paul |author-link=Paul James (academic) |last2=Gills |first2=Barry |title=Globalization and Economy, Vol. 1: Global Markets and Capitalism |url=https://www.academia.edu/4199690 |publisher=] |location=London |page=xxxiii}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |title=Impact of Global Capitalism on the Environment of Developing Economies |url=http://s-space.snu.ac.kr/bitstream/10371/93716/1/04_Osariyekemwen%20Igiebor.pdf |journal=Impact of Global Capitalism on the Environment of Developing Economies: The Case of Nigeria |pages=84 |access-date=31 July 2020 |archive-date=20 March 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200320071239/http://s-space.snu.ac.kr/bitstream/10371/93716/1/04_Osariyekemwen%20Igiebor.pdf |url-status=live}}</ref> Late in the 20th century, capitalism overcame a challenge by ] and is now the encompassing system worldwide,<ref name="britannica">{{cite book |title=Capitalism |publisher=Encyclopædia Britannica |url=https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/93927/capitalism |date=10 November 2014 |access-date=24 March 2015 |archive-date=29 June 2011 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110629021539/https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/93927/capitalism |url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=James |first=Fulcher |title=Capitalism, A Very Short Introduction |quote=In one respect there can, however, be little doubt that capitalism has gone global and that is in the elimination of alternative systems |pages=99 |publisher=] |date=2004 |isbn=978-0-19-280218-7}}</ref> with the ] as its dominant form in the industrialized Western world. | |||
Importantly, the owners receive any profits or proceeds generated by the productive capacity that they own - sometimes in the form of dividends, other times in the form of profits being re-invested in the capacity that is owned (and "]"). The price at which ownership of productive capacity sells is generally in rough proportion to the profits currently being generated and/or expected to be generated by that productive capacity in the future. There is therefore a financial incentive for owners to exercise their authority in ways that increase the productive capacity of what they own. Various owners are motivated to various degrees by this incentive -- some give away a proportion of what they own, others seem very driven to increase their holdings. Nevertheless the incentive is always there, and it is credited by many as being a key aspect behind the remarkably consistent growth exhibited by capitalist economies. Meanwhile, some critics of capitalism claim that the incentive for the owners is exaggerated and that it results in the owners receiving money that rightfully belongs to the workers, while others point to the fact that the incentive only motivates owners to make a '']'' - something which may not necessarily result in a positive impact on society. | |||
] allowed cheap production of household items using ], while rapid ] created sustained demand for commodities. The ] of the 18th-century decisively shaped globalization.<ref name="SAGE Publications" /><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Thomas |first1=Martin |last2=Thompson |first2=Andrew |date=1 January 2014 |title=Empire and Globalisation: from 'High Imperialism' to Decolonisation |journal=The International History Review |volume=36 |issue=1 |pages=142–170 |doi=10.1080/07075332.2013.828643 |s2cid=153987517 |issn=0707-5332|doi-access=free }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |title=Globalization and Empire |url=https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/47230635.pdf |journal=Globalization and Empire |access-date=31 July 2020 |archive-date=23 September 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063531/https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/47230635.pdf |url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |title=Europe and the causes of globalization |url=https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/7045619.pdf |journal=Europe and the Causes of Globalization, 1790 to 2000 |access-date=31 July 2020 |archive-date=7 December 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171207091124/https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/7045619.pdf |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
== Characteristics of capitalist economies == | |||
Despite wide disagreements over the precise definition of capitalism, and arguments over which economies are capitalist and to what degree, a set of broad characteristics are generally agreed on by both advocates and critics of capitalism. These are a ], ], ], ], unequal distribution of ], competition, evolving ] networks and social arrangements, and the existence of ] like the ]. | |||
After the ] and ]s (1839–60) by ] and ] and the completion of the ] conquest of India by 1858 and the ] conquest of ], ] and ] by 1887, vast populations of Asia became consumers of European exports. Europeans colonized areas of Africa and the Pacific islands. Colonisation by Europeans, notably of Africa by the British and French, yielded valuable natural resources such as ], ] and ] and helped fuel trade and investment between the European imperial powers, their colonies and the United States: | |||
=== Property rights === | |||
One core difference to earlier social systems was the introduction of strong formal property rights and rule of law. Earlier social systems were much weaker in these aspects, often meaning that the weak had to accept the leadership and pay for the protection from a strong patron or lord. It has been argued that a strong formal property and legal system caused | |||
{{blockquote|The inhabitant of London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea, the various products of the whole earth, and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep. Militarism and imperialism of racial and cultural rivalries were little more than the amusements of his daily newspaper. What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man was that age which came to an end in August 1914.<ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.pbs.org/wgbh/commandingheights/shared/minitext/tr_show01.html |title=Commanding Heights: Episode One: The Battle of Ideas |publisher=] |date=24 October 1929 |access-date=31 July 2010 |archive-date=30 March 2010 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100330093746/http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/commandingheights/shared/minitext/tr_show01.html |url-status=live}}</ref>}} | |||
a) more independence | |||
b) clear and provable protected ownership | |||
From the 1870s to the early 1920s, the global financial system was mainly tied to the ].<ref>{{cite book|last=Eichengreen|first=Barry|author-link=Barry Eichengreen|date=6 August 2019|title=Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System|edition=3rd|publisher=]|doi=10.2307/j.ctvd58rxg|isbn=978-0-691-19458-5|s2cid=240840930 |lccn=2019018286}}{{page needed|date=December 2023}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|last1=Eichengreen|first1=Barry|author-link=Barry Eichengreen|last2=Esteves|first2=Rui Pedro|date=2021|editor1-last=Fukao|editor1-first=Kyoji|editor2-last=Broadberry|editor2-first=Stephen|editor2-link=Stephen Broadberry|section=International Finance|title=The Cambridge Economic History of the Modern World|publisher=]|volume=2: ''1870 to the Present''|pages=501–525|isbn=978-1-107-15948-8}}</ref> The United Kingdom first formally adopted this standard in 1821. Soon to follow were ] in 1853, ] in 1865, the United States and Germany ('']'') in 1873. New technologies, such as the ], the ], the ], the ] and ]s allowed goods and information to move around the world to an unprecedented degree.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.nber.org/papers/w7195 |last1=Bordo |first1=Michael D. |author1-link=Michael D. Bordo |last2=Eichengreen |first2=Barry |author2-link=Barry Eichengreen |last3=Irwin |first3=Douglas A. |title=Is Globalization Today Really Different than Globalization a Hundred Years Ago? |series=NBER |number=Working Paper No. 7195 |date=June 1999|doi=10.3386/w7195 }}</ref> | |||
c) standardization and integration of property rules and property information for whole country | |||
d) increased trust due to more certain punishment of cheating in economic transactions | |||
In the United States, the term "capitalist" primarily referred to powerful businessmen<ref>{{Cite book |last=Andrews |first=Thomas G. |title=Killing for Coal: America's Deadliest Labor War |publisher=] |year=2008 |isbn=978-0-674-03101-2 |location=Cambridge |page=64 |author-link=Thomas G. Andrews (historian)}}</ref> until the 1920s due to widespread societal skepticism and criticism of capitalism and its most ardent supporters. | |||
e) more formal and complex written representations of ownership which easier allowed things like shared risk and ownership in companies or the insurance of risk | |||
f) more loans for new projects since more things could be used as collateral for the loans | |||
] ] (1963)]] | |||
g) easier and more reliable information for things like credit history and the worth of assets | |||
h) increased fungability, standardization and transportability of property representations allowing things like national markets in companies or easy transportation of property in complex networks of people. All of these things enhanced ]. | |||
Contemporary capitalist societies developed in the West from 1950 to the present and this type of system continues throughout the world—relevant examples started in the ], ], ], ], and others. At this stage most capitalist markets are considered{{by whom|date=July 2021}} developed and characterized by developed private and public markets for equity and debt, a high ] (as characterized by the ] and the ]), large institutional investors and a well-funded ]. A significant ] has emerged{{when|date=July 2021}} and decides on a significant proportion of investments and other decisions. A different future than that envisioned by Marx has started to emerge—explored and described by ] in the United Kingdom in his 1956 book '']''<ref>{{cite book |last=Crosland |first=Anthony |title=The Future of Socialism |publisher=Jonathan Cape |year=1956 |location=United Kingdom}}{{page needed|date=December 2023}}</ref> and by ] in North America in his 1958 book '']'',<ref>{{cite book |last=Galbraith |first=John Kenneth |title=The Affluent Society |publisher=] |year=1958 |location=United States}}{{page needed|date=December 2023}}</ref> 90 years after Marx's research on the state of capitalism in 1867.<ref>{{cite book |last=Shiller |first=Robert |title=Finance and The Good Society |publisher=] |year=2012 |location=United States}}{{page needed|date=December 2023}}</ref> | |||
The ] ended in the late 1960s and early 1970s and the economic situation grew worse with the rise of ].<ref>{{cite book |last=Barnes |first=Trevor J. |title=Reading economic geography |publisher=] |isbn=978-0-631-23554-5 |page=127 |year=2004}}</ref> ], a modification of ] that is more compatible with ''laissez-faire'' analyses, gained increasing prominence in the capitalist world, especially under the years in office of ] in the United States (1981–1989) and of ] in the United Kingdom (1979–1990). Public and political interest began shifting away from the so-called ] concerns of Keynes's managed capitalism to a focus on individual ], called "remarketized capitalism".<ref name="Fulcher, James 2004">{{cite book |last=Fulcher |first=James |title=Capitalism |edition=1st |location=New York |publisher=] |date=2004}}{{page needed|date=December 2023}}</ref> | |||
The end of the ] and the ] allowed for capitalism to become a truly global system in a way not seen since before ]. The development of the ] global economy would have been impossible without the fall of ].<ref>{{cite book |last=Gerstle |first=Gary |author-link=Gary Gerstle |date=2022 |title=The Rise and Fall of the Neoliberal Order: America and the World in the Free Market Era |url=https://global.oup.com/academic/product/the-rise-and-fall-of-the-neoliberal-order-9780197519646?cc=us&lang=en& |location= |publisher=] |pages=10–12 |isbn=978-0-19-751964-6}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Bartel |first=Fritz |date=2022 |title=The Triumph of Broken Promises: The End of the Cold War and the Rise of Neoliberalism |url=https://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog.php?isbn=978-0-674-97678-8 |location= |publisher=] |pages=5–6, 19 |isbn=978-0-674-97678-8}}</ref> | |||
Harvard Kennedy School economist Dani Rodrik distinguishes between three historical variants of capitalism:<ref>{{citation |last=Rodrik |first=Dani |title=Capitalism 3.0 |date=2009 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctt46mtqx.23 |work=Aftershocks |volume= |pages=185–193 |editor-last=Hemerijck |editor-first=Anton |publisher=] |jstor=j.ctt46mtqx.23 |isbn=978-90-8964-192-2 |access-date=14 January 2021 |editor2-last=Knapen |editor2-first=Ben |editor3-last=van Doorne |editor3-first=Ellen}}</ref> | |||
* Capitalism 1.0 during the 19th century entailed largely unregulated markets with a minimal role for the state (aside from national defense, and protecting property rights); | |||
* Capitalism 2.0 during the post-World War II years entailed Keynesianism, a substantial role for the state in regulating markets, and strong welfare states; | |||
* Capitalism 2.1 entailed a combination of unregulated markets, globalization, and various national obligations by states. | |||
==== Relationship to democracy ==== | |||
The relationship between ] and capitalism is a contentious area in theory and in popular political movements.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Milner |first1=Helen V |title=Is Global Capitalism Compatible with Democracy? Inequality, Insecurity, and Interdependence |journal=] |date=2021 |volume=65 |issue=4 |pages=1097–1110 |doi=10.1093/isq/sqab056 |doi-access=free}}</ref> The extension of adult-male ] in 19th-century Britain occurred along with the development of industrial capitalism and ] became widespread at the same time as capitalism, leading capitalists to posit a causal or mutual relationship between them. However, according to some authors in the 20th-century, capitalism also accompanied a variety of political formations quite distinct from liberal democracies, including ] regimes, ] and ].<ref name="Burnham" /> ] asserts that democracies seldom fight other democracies, but others suggest this may be because of political similarity or stability, rather than because they are "democratic" or "capitalist". Critics argue that though economic growth under capitalism has led to democracy, it may not do so in the future as ] régimes have been able to manage economic growth using some of capitalism's competitive principles<ref>{{cite magazine |first=Gady |last=Epstein |title=The Winners And Losers in Chinese Capitalism |url=https://www.forbes.com/sites/gadyepstein/2010/08/31/the-winners-and-losers-in-chinese-capitalism/ |magazine=] |access-date=28 October 2015 |archive-date=5 November 2015 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151105210914/http://www.forbes.com/sites/gadyepstein/2010/08/31/the-winners-and-losers-in-chinese-capitalism/ |url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite news |title=The rise of state capitalism |url=http://www.economist.com/node/21543160 |newspaper=] |access-date=24 October 2015 |issn=0013-0613 |archive-date=15 June 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200615124603/https://www.economist.com/leaders/2012/01/21/the-rise-of-state-capitalism |url-status=live}}</ref> without making concessions to greater ].<ref>{{cite web |last=Mesquita |first=Bruce Bueno de |url=http://www.foreignaffairs.org/20050901faessay84507/bruce-bueno-de-mesquita-george-w-downs/development-and-democracy.html |title=Development and Democracy |date=September 2005 |access-date=26 February 2008 |work=] |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080220154505/http://www.foreignaffairs.org/20050901faessay84507/bruce-bueno-de-mesquita-george-w-downs/development-and-democracy.html |archive-date=20 February 2008}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Siegle |first1=Joseph |last2=Weinstein |first2=Michael |last3=Halperin |first3=Morton |date=1 September 2004 |title=Why Democracies Excel |url=http://www.mafhoum.com/press7/212S28.pdf |journal=] |volume=83 |issue=5 |pages=57 |doi=10.2307/20034067 |jstor=20034067 |access-date=26 August 2018 |archive-date=12 April 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190412055541/http://www.mafhoum.com/press7/212S28.pdf |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
Political scientists ] and ] see democracy and capitalism as mutually supportive.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Iversen |first1=Torben |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctv4g1r3n |title=Democracy and Prosperity: Reinventing Capitalism through a Turbulent Century |last2=Soskice |first2=David |date=2019 |publisher=] |jstor=j.ctv4g1r3n |isbn=978-0-691-18273-5}}</ref> ] argued in ''On Democracy'' that capitalism was beneficial for democracy because economic growth and a large middle class were good for democracy.<ref name=":0a">{{cite book |last=Dahl |first=Robert A. |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ZG4JEAAAQBAJ |title=On Democracy |date=2020 |publisher=] |isbn=978-0-300-25799-1 |language=en}}</ref> He also argued that a market economy provided a substitute for government control of the economy, which reduces the risks of tyranny and authoritarianism.<ref name=":0a" /> | |||
In his book '']'' (1944), ] (1899–1992) asserted that the free-market understanding of ] as present in capitalism is a requisite of ]. He argued that the market mechanism is the only way of deciding what to produce and how to distribute the items without using coercion. ] and ] also promoted this view.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Pryor |first1=Frederic L. |title=Capitalism and freedom? |journal=Economic Systems |date=2010 |volume=34 |issue=1 |pages=91–104 |doi=10.1016/j.ecosys.2009.09.003}}</ref> Friedman claimed that centralized economic operations are always accompanied by ]. In his view, transactions in a market economy are voluntary and the wide diversity that voluntary activity permits is a fundamental threat to repressive ]s and greatly diminishes their power to coerce. Some of Friedman's views were shared by ], who believed that capitalism was vital for freedom to survive and thrive.<ref>{{cite journal |first=Friedrich |last=Hayek |author-link=Friedrich Hayek |title=The Road to Serfdom |journal=] |volume=154 |issue=3911 |pages=473–474 |publisher=] |year=1944 |isbn=978-0-226-32061-8 |bibcode=1944Natur.154..473C |doi=10.1038/154473a0 |s2cid=4071358}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Bellamy |first=Richard |title=The Cambridge History of Twentieth-Century Political Thought |publisher=] |year=2003 |isbn=978-0-521-56354-3 |page=60}}</ref> ], an American ] that conducts international research on, and advocates for, democracy, political freedom and ], has argued that "there is a high and statistically significant correlation between the level of political freedom ] and economic freedom ]".<ref>{{cite book |first=Adrian |last=Karatnycky |title=Freedom in the World: The Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties |publisher=] |date=2001 |isbn=978-0-7658-0101-2 |page=11}}</ref> | |||
In '']'' (2013), ] of the ] asserted that inequality is the inevitable consequence of economic growth in a capitalist economy and the resulting ] can destabilize democratic societies and undermine the ideals of social justice upon which they are built.<ref>{{cite book |author-link=Thomas Piketty |last=Piketty |first=Thomas |date=2014 |title=Capital in the Twenty-First Century |publisher=] |isbn=978-0-674-43000-6 |page=571}}</ref> | |||
States with capitalistic economic systems have thrived under political regimes deemed to be authoritarian or oppressive. ] has a successful open market economy as a result of its competitive, business-friendly climate and robust rule of law. Nonetheless, it often comes under fire for its style of government which, though democratic and consistently one of the least corrupt,<ref>{{cite web |title=Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015 |url=https://www.transparency.org/country/#SGP |website=Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015 – By Country / Territory |publisher=Transparency International |access-date=20 September 2016 |archive-date=31 March 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160331114640/http://www.transparency.org/country/#SGP |url-status=dead}}</ref> operates largely under a one-party rule. Furthermore, it does not vigorously defend freedom of expression as evidenced by its government-regulated ], and its penchant for upholding laws protecting ethnic and religious harmony, judicial dignity and personal reputation. The private (capitalist) sector in the People's Republic of China has grown exponentially and thrived since its inception, despite having an authoritarian government. ]'s ] led to economic growth and high levels of inequality<ref>] (2008). ''].'' ]. {{ISBN|0-312-42799-9}} {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150319071518/http://books.google.com/books?id=PwHUAq5LPOQC&lpg=PP1&pg=PA105 |date=19 March 2015 }}.</ref> by using authoritarian means to create a safe environment for investment and capitalism. Similarly, ]'s authoritarian reign and ] of the ] allowed for the expansion of capitalism in ].<ref>{{cite journal |last=Farid |first=Hilmar |date=2005 |title=Indonesia's original sin: mass killings and capitalist expansion, 1965–66 |journal=] |volume=6 |issue=1 |pages=3–16 |doi=10.1080/1462394042000326879 |s2cid= 145130614}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Robinson |first=Geoffrey B. |date=2018 |title=The Killing Season: A History of the Indonesian Massacres, 1965–66 |url=https://press.princeton.edu/titles/11135.html |publisher=] |page=177 |isbn=978-1-4008-8886-3 |access-date=1 August 2018 |archive-date=19 April 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190419011656/https://press.princeton.edu/titles/11135.html |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
The term "capitalism" in its modern sense is often attributed to ].<ref name="Scott">{{cite book |title=Industrialism: A Dictionary of Sociology |last=Scott |first=John |publisher=] |year=2005}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |title="capitalism, n.2". OED Online |url=http://www.oed.com/view/Entry/27454?rskey=ZVI1hr&result=2&isAdvanced=false |access-date=19 January 2013 |archive-date=23 September 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063611/https://www.oed.com/start;jsessionid=A9CBE07460C68ED291D7D6CDCE84A1B1?authRejection=true&url=%2Fview%2FEntry%2F27454%3Frskey%3DZVI1hr%26result%3D2%26isAdvanced%3Dfalse |url-status=live}}</ref> In his '']'', Marx analyzed the "]" using a method of understanding today known as ]. However, Marx himself rarely used the term "capitalism" while it was used twice in the more political interpretations of his work, primarily authored by his collaborator ]. In the 20th century, defenders of the capitalist system often replaced the term "capitalism" with phrases such as free enterprise and private enterprise and replaced "capitalist" with ] and ] in reaction to the negative connotations associated with capitalism.<ref name="Williams 1983 51">{{cite book |last=Williams |first=Raymond |title=Keywords: A vocabulary of culture and society, revised edition |publisher=] |year=1983 |isbn=978-0-19-520469-8 |page= |chapter=Capitalism |chapter-url=https://archive.org/details/keywordsvocabula00willrich/page/51}}</ref> | |||
== Characteristics == | |||
{{further|Academic perspectives on capitalism}} | |||
In general, capitalism as an economic system and mode of production can be summarized by the following:<ref>{{cite web|url=http://publishing.cdlib.org/ucpressebooks/view?docId=ft3n39n8x3&chunk.id=d0e1212&toc.id=&brand=ucpress |title=Althusser and the Renewal of Marxist Social Theory |access-date=24 March 2015 |archive-date=2 April 2015 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150402094835/http://publishing.cdlib.org/ucpressebooks/view?docId=ft3n39n8x3&chunk.id=d0e1212&toc.id=&brand=ucpress |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
* ]:<ref name=ch32>{{cite book|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch32.htm |title=Economic Manuscripts: Capital Vol. I |chapter=Thirty Two |first=Karl |last=Marx |author-link=Karl Marx |access-date=24 March 2015 |via=] |archive-date=21 February 2015 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150221104326/https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch32.htm |url-status=live}}</ref> production for profit and accumulation as the implicit purpose of all or most of production, constriction or elimination of production formerly carried out on a common social or private household basis.<ref name=xxx31 /> | |||
* ]: production for exchange on a market; to maximize ] instead of ]. | |||
* Exchange of goods or services, can be enabled by ]s.<ref name="y015">{{cite book | last=Goldberg | first=Victor P. | title=The Oxford Handbook of Capitalism | chapter=Contracts | publisher=Oxford University Press | date=21 November 2012 | isbn=978-0-19-539117-6 | doi=10.1093/oxfordhb/9780195391176.013.0010 | pages=250–274}}</ref> Exchange of services can be in form of ].<ref name="Steinfeld 2009 3"/> | |||
* ] of the means of production:<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54" /> | |||
* The ] of money to make a profit.<ref>James Fulcher, ''Capitalism A Very Short Introduction'', "the investment of money in order to make a profit, the essential feature of capitalism", p. 14, Oxford, 2004, {{ISBN|978-0-19-280218-7}}.</ref> | |||
* The use of the ] to allocate resources between competing uses.<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54" /> | |||
* Economically efficient use of the ] and raw materials due to maximization of value added in the production process.<ref>{{cite book|title=Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life |last=Reisman |first=George |year=1998 |isbn=0-915463-73-3 |publisher=Jameson Books}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|title=History of Economic Thought: A Critical Perspective |last1=Hunt |first1=E.K. |last2=Lautzenheiser |first2=Mark |year=2014 |publisher=PHI Learning |isbn=978-0-7656-2599-1}}</ref> | |||
* Freedom of capitalists to act in their self-interest in managing their business and investments.<ref>{{cite book|title=Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life |last=Reisman |first=George |year=1998 |isbn=978-0-915463-73-2 |publisher=Jameson Books}}</ref> | |||
* Capital suppliance by "the single owner of a firm, or by ]s in the case of a ]."<ref name=":1">{{Cite book |title=The Desk Encyclopedia of World History |publisher=] |year=2006 |isbn=978-0-7394-7809-7 |editor-last=Wright |editor-first=Edmund |location=New York |pages=111–112}}</ref> | |||
=== Market === | |||
In ] and '']'' forms of capitalism, markets are used most extensively with minimal or no regulation over the pricing mechanism. In mixed economies, which are almost universal today,<ref>James Fulcher, ''Capitalism A Very Short Introduction'', "...in the wake of the 1970 crisis, the neoliberal model of capitalism became intellectually and ideologically dominant", p. 58, Oxford, 2004, {{ISBN|978-0-19-280218-7}}.</ref> markets continue to play a dominant role, but they are regulated to some extent by the state in order to correct ]s, promote ], conserve ]s, fund ] and ] or other rationale. In ] systems, markets are relied upon the least, with the state relying heavily on ] or indirect economic planning to accumulate capital. | |||
Competition arises when more than one producer is trying to sell the same or similar products to the same buyers. Adherents of the capitalist theory believe that competition leads to innovation and more affordable prices. ] or ] can develop, especially if there is no competition. A monopoly occurs when a firm has exclusivity over a market. Hence, the firm can engage in ] behaviors such as limiting output and raising prices because it has no fear of competition. | |||
Governments have implemented legislation for the purpose of preventing the creation of monopolies and cartels. In 1890, the ] became the first legislation passed by the United States Congress to limit monopolies.<ref>{{Cite news|url=http://www.investopedia.com/terms/m/monopoly.asp|title=Monopoly|author=<!--Staff writer(s); no by-line.-->|date=24 November 2003|work=Investopedia|access-date=2 March 2017|language=en-US|archive-date=22 February 2017|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170222204011/http://www.investopedia.com/terms/m/monopoly.asp|url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
=== Wage labor === | |||
{{Main|Wage labor}} | |||
Wage labor, usually referred to as paid work, paid employment, or paid labor, refers to the ] relationship between a ] and an ] in which the worker sells their labor power under a formal or informal ].<ref name="Steinfeld 2009 3">{{Harvnb|Steinfeld|2009|p=3}}: "All labor contracts were/are designed legally to bind a worker in one way or another to fulfill the labor obligations the worker has undertaken. That is one of the principal purposes of labor contracts."</ref> These transactions usually occur in a ] where ]s or ] are ].<ref>{{Harvnb|Deakin|Wilkinson|2005}}</ref> | |||
In exchange for the money paid as wages (usual for short-term work-contracts) or salaries (in permanent employment contracts), the work product generally becomes the ] of the employer. A wage laborer is a person whose primary means of income is from the selling of their labor in this way.<ref>{{cite book|page=278|title=Concise Dictionary of Economics|isbn=978-93-5057-032-6|publisher=V&S Publishers|year=2013|author=Editorial Board|chapter=W}}</ref> | |||
=== Profit motive === | |||
{{Main|Profit motive}} | |||
The ], in the theory of capitalism, is the desire to earn income in the form of profit. Stated differently, the reason for a business's existence is to turn a profit.<ref> | |||
Compare: | |||
{{cite book | |||
| last1 = Duska | |||
| first1 = Ronald F. | |||
| year = 1997 | |||
| chapter = The Why's of Business Revisited | |||
| title = Contemporary Reflections on Business Ethics | |||
| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=dANmdJHsqu0C | |||
| series = Issues in Business Ethics | |||
| volume = 23 | |||
| location = Dordrecht | |||
| publisher = Springer Science & Business Media | |||
| publication-date = 2007 | |||
| page = 41 | |||
| isbn = 978-1-4020-4984-2 | |||
| access-date = 8 July 2019 | |||
| quote = In microeconomics courses, profit maximization is frequently given as the goal of the firm. ... In microeconomics, profit maximization functions largely as a theoretical goal, with economists using it to prove how firms behave rationally to increase profit. Unfortunately, it ignores many real-world complexities. | |||
}} | |||
</ref> The profit motive functions according to ], or the theory that individuals tend to pursue what is in their own best interests. Accordingly, businesses seek to benefit themselves and/or their shareholders by maximizing profit. | |||
In capitalist theoretics, the profit motive is said to ensure that resources are being allocated efficiently. For instance, ] ] explains: "If there is no profit in making an article, it is a sign that the labor and capital devoted to its production are misdirected: the value of the resources that must be used up in making the article is greater than the value of the article itself".<ref>Hazlitt, Henry. "The Function of Profits". ''Economics in One Lesson''. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. Web. 22 April 2013.</ref> | |||
Socialist theorists note that, unlike mercantilists, capitalists accumulate their profits while expecting their profit rates to remain the same. This causes problems as earnings in the rest of society do not increase in the same proportion.<ref>"What is capitalism" ''Australian Socialist'' https://search.informit.org/doi/10.3316/informit.818838886883514</ref> | |||
=== Private property === | |||
{{Main|Private property}} | |||
The relationship between the ], its formal mechanisms, and capitalist societies has been debated in many fields of social and political theory, with active discussion since the 19th century. ] is a contemporary Peruvian economist who has argued that an important characteristic of capitalism is the functioning state protection of property rights in a formal property system where ownership and transactions are clearly recorded.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2001/03/desoto.htm|title=The mystery of capital|author=Hernando de Soto|access-date=26 February 2008|archive-date=8 February 2008|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080208180121/http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2001/03/desoto.htm|url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
According to de Soto, this is the process by which physical assets are transformed into capital, which in turn may be used in many more ways and much more efficiently in the market economy. A number of Marxian economists have argued that the ]s in England and similar legislation elsewhere were an integral part of capitalist ] and that specific legal frameworks of private land ownership have been integral to the development of capitalism.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch27.htm|title=Capital, v. 1. Part VIII: primitive accumulation|author=Karl Marx|access-date=26 February 2008|archive-date=3 March 2008|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080303162047/http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch27.htm|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |author=N.F.R. Crafts |title=Enclosure and labor supply revisited |journal=Explorations in Economic History |issue=2 |date=April 1978 |pages=172–183 |doi=10.1016/0014-4983(78)90019-0 |volume=15}}</ref> | |||
Private property rights are not absolute, as in many countries the state has the power to seize private property, typically for public use, under the powers of ]. | |||
=== Market competition === | |||
{{Main|Competition (economics)}} | |||
In capitalist economics, market competition is the rivalry among sellers trying to achieve such goals as increasing profits, market share and sales volume by varying the elements of the ]: price, product, distribution and promotion. Merriam-Webster defines competition in business as "the effort of two or more parties acting independently to secure the business of a third party by offering the most favourable terms".<ref>{{cite web |url=http://m-w.com/dictionary/competition |title=Definition of COMPETITION |access-date=24 March 2015 |archive-date=4 July 2008 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080704114809/http://m-w.com/dictionary/competition |url-status=dead}}</ref> It was described by ] in '']'' (1776) and later economists as allocating productive ]s to their most highly valued uses<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |first=George J. |last=Stigler |author-link=George J. Stigler |date=2008 |title=competition |dictionary=] |edition=2nd |url=http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000261&q=competition&topicid=&result_number=6 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150215032134/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000261&q=competition&topicid=&result_number=6 |archive-date=15 February 2015}}</ref> and encouraging ]. Smith and other ]s before ] were referring to price and non-price rivalry among producers to sell their goods on best terms by bidding of buyers, not necessarily to a large number of sellers nor to a market in final ].<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |first=Mark |last=Blaug |author-link=Mark Blaug |date=2008 |title=Invisible hand |dictionary=] |edition=2nd |volume=4 |page=565 |url=http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_I000220&edition=current&q=Invisible%20hand&topicid=&result_number=1 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130605204024/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_I000220&edition=current&q=Invisible%20hand&topicid=&result_number=1 |archive-date=5 June 2013}}</ref> Competition is widespread throughout the ]. It is a condition where "buyers tend to compete with other buyers, and sellers tend to compete with other sellers".<ref name=ewot2014 /><!-- p. 102 --> In offering goods for exchange, buyers competitively bid to purchase specific quantities of specific goods which are available, or might be available if sellers were to choose to offer such goods. Similarly, sellers bid against other sellers in offering goods on the market, competing for the attention and exchange resources of buyers. Competition results from ], as it is not possible to satisfy all conceivable human wants, and occurs as people try to meet the criteria being used to determine allocation.<ref name=ewot2014>{{cite book |last1=Heyne |first1=Paul |last2=Boettke |first2=Peter J. |last3=Prychitko |first3=David L. |title=The Economic Way of Thinking |date=2014 |publisher=Pearson |isbn=978-0-13-299129-2 |pages=102–106 |edition=13th}}<!--|access-date=24 December 2014 --></ref>{{rp|105}} | |||
In the works of Adam Smith, the idea of capitalism is made possible through competition which creates growth. Although capitalism had not entered mainstream economics at the time of Smith, it is vital to the construction of his ideal society. One of the foundational blocks of capitalism is competition. Smith believed that a prosperous society is one where "everyone should be free to enter and leave the market and change trades as often as he pleases."<ref name="W.W. Norton">{{cite book |last1=Warsh |first1=David |title=Knowledge and the Wealth of Nations |date=2007 |publisher=] |page=42}}</ref> He believed that the freedom to act in one's self-interest is essential for the success of a capitalist society. In response to the idea that if all participants focus on their own goals, society's well-being will be water under the bridge, Smith maintains that despite the concerns of intellectuals, "global trends will hardly be altered if they refrain from pursuing their personal ends."<ref>{{cite book |last1=Lippit |first1=Victor |title=Capitalism |date=2005 |publisher=] |location=ProQuest |page=2}}</ref> He insisted that the actions of a few participants cannot alter the course of society. Instead, Smith maintained that they should focus on personal progress instead and that this will result in overall growth to the whole. | |||
Competition between participants, "who are all endeavoring to justle one another out of employment, obliges every man to endeavor to execute his work" through competition towards growth.<ref name="W.W. Norton"/> | |||
=== Economic growth === | === Economic growth === | ||
{{further|Economic growth}} | |||
One of the primary objectives in a social system in which commerce and property have a central role is to promote the growth of capital. The measurements for "growth" are Gross Domestic Product or ], capacity utilization, and "standard of living". | |||
{{expand section|date=January 2021}} | |||
] is a characteristic tendency of capitalist economies.<ref name=joff>{{cite journal|title=The root cause of economic growth under capitalism |journal=] |year=2011 |issue=5 |pages=873–896 |first=Michael |last=Joff |volume=35 |quote=The tendency for capitalist economies to grow is one of their most characteristic properties. |doi=10.1093/cje/beq054}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Baumol |first1=William J. |title=The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism |date=2004 |publisher=] |location=Princeton |isbn=9780691116303}}</ref> However, capitalist economies may experience fluctuations in growth that cannot be accounted for by demographic or technological changes. These fluctuations, which involve sustained periods of economic growth and recession, are referred to as business cycles in macroeconomics. Economic growth is measured as growth in investment, economic output, and economic consumption per capita. Changes in hours of employment on their own are not considered as a factor of economic growth.<ref name = "HP"/> | |||
The ability of capitalist economies to sustainably increase and improve their stock of capital was central to the argument which ] advanced for having a free market set production, price and resource allocation. It has been argued that GDP/capita was essentially flat until the industrial revolution and introduction of the capitalistic system. And that it thereafter has increased rapidly in capitalistic countries . And that a higher GDP/capita allows a higher standard of living, including adequate or better food, housing, clothes, healthcare, psychotherapy, shorter working hours and no work for children and the elderly. Things which are not possible if the GDP/capita is low enough and people live on the edge of starvation. | |||
=== As a mode of production === | |||
Economic growth, however, is not universally agreed on, nor is it universally seen to be an unequivocal good. Growth's down sides are, within the discipline of economics, referred to as "externalization of costs" (see ]). These include pollution, disruption of traditional living patterns and cultures, spread of pathogens, wars over resources or market access, the creation of underclasses, among others. In defense of capitalism, philosophers such as ] have pointed out that all of these ills are neither unique to capitalism, nor are they inevitable results of it. | |||
{{further|Mode of production}} | |||
The capitalist mode of production refers to the systems of organising production and distribution within capitalist ]. Private money-making in various forms (renting, banking, merchant trade, production for profit and so on) preceded the development of the capitalist mode of production as such. | |||
The term capitalist mode of production is defined by ] of the ], extraction of ] by the owning class for the purpose of ], ] and, at least as far as ] are concerned, being ].<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.marxists.org/glossary/terms/c/a.htm#capitalism |title=Capitalism |publisher=] |access-date=8 July 2011 |author=Encyclopedia of Marxism at marxism.org |archive-date=7 May 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190507154837/https://www.marxists.org/glossary/terms/c/a.htm#capitalism |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
=== Economic mobility === | |||
One of the key signs entrepreneurial economies, and of "growth" is economic mobility - expressed as a large change in the socio-economic strata. The way this is measured is by large changes in the populations in the various ] or ] of income and wealth, and large changes over a person's lifetime in real wage earning power. In standard economics, a capitalist system provides more opportunities for an individual to rise faster in the world by entering new professions, or by forming a business venture. The instability of economic strata is contrasted with traditional ] or ] societies that are thought to have more stable relationships of wealth and with ] in socialist societies which distribute more of the wealth in social benefits, and therefore reduce the income mobility, particularly of those who own capital and wish to sell it. | |||
Capitalism in the form of money-making activity has existed in the shape of merchants and money-lenders who acted as intermediaries between consumers and producers engaging in ] (hence the reference to "]") since the beginnings of civilisation. What is specific about the "capitalist mode of production" is that most of the inputs and outputs of production are supplied through the market (i.e. they are commodities) and essentially all production is in this mode.<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54" /> By contrast, in flourishing feudalism most or all of the factors of production, including labor, are owned by the feudal ruling class outright and the products may also be consumed without a market of any kind, it is production for use within the feudal social unit and for limited trade.<ref name=ch32 /> This has the important consequence that, under capitalism, the whole organisation of the production process is reshaped and re-organised to conform with economic ] by capitalism, which is expressed in price relationships between inputs and outputs (wages, non-labor factor costs, sales and profits) rather than the larger rational context faced by society overall—that is, the whole process is organised and re-shaped in order to conform to "commercial logic". Essentially, capital accumulation comes to define economic rationality in capitalist production.<ref name=xxx31>{{cite web|url=http://www.dsp.org.au/node/31 |title=The contradictions of capitalism – Democratic Socialist Perspective |publisher=dsp.org.au |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150406094810/http://www.dsp.org.au/node/31 |archive-date=6 April 2015}}</ref> | |||
Large turnover in the population of income deciles, however, does not always represent income mobility - with individuals having regular increases in wages over their life and then retiring, population change alone, does not show that there is "mobility" per se. More over, it is argued by many labor economists that instability of working wages represents the moving of risk on to workers and into particular sectors such as agriculture, and off of holders of capital. | |||
A society, region or ] is capitalist if the predominant source of incomes and products being distributed is capitalist activity, but even so this does not yet mean necessarily that the capitalist mode of production is dominant in that society.<ref>{{Cite web|title=Capitalism|url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/capitalism.asp|access-date=14 February 2022|website=Investopedia|language=en}}</ref> | |||
=== Distribution of wealth === | |||
Capitalist economies have shown an uneven distribution of ]. Typically between 0.5% and 1% of people own more than half of productive capacity, if not half of all wealth. Various studies have shown distributions with the peak in the distribution at or near zero with fewer people owning progressively higher wealth. Common mathematical models of such distributions include ] distributions, exponential distributions, and mixtures of the two. In these distributions some people own hundreds of thousands, or sometimes millions of times more than average. Differences in actual income are smaller, for example in the US 1% of the population earning under 20% of all household income. | |||
] rely on the nation they are in to provide some goods or services, while the free market produces and maintains the rest.<ref name=":1" /> | |||
Arguments directed against unfairness or dysfunctionality of this have a tendency to go roughly as follows: Most characteristics of people, such as height or weight, and it might be surmised people's ability to be productive, are distributed according to a bell shaped curve (]) with a peak at the average and few people far on either side. For example, there are very few people who are twice as tall as average, or who can run twice as fast, or have twice as high an IQ. The fact that capitalism doesn't distribute wealth in a similar fashion could mean that an untamed capitalist system has inherent biases favoring those who already possess greater resources. For example, rich people can give their children a better education and inherited wealth. This can create or even increase large differences in wealth between people who do not differ in ability or effort. | |||
=== Role of government === | |||
A different explanation for the wealth inequality is that some people voluntarily do not achieve their full economic potential. For example, some people may not see money as very important and make life choices that make them earn less than their potential. Another explanation is that human contributions vary much more than humans vary in height. As can be illustrated by comparing the contributions of an arsonist and an inventor/producer of antibiotics. Still another explanation is that economic systems are not even the main culprit. The economist ] has attributed factors such as geography, climate, culture, and natural resources as primary reasons for inequality. Although this may apply primarily to wealth inequality between nations, not to wealth inequality in a nation. | |||
Government agencies regulate the standards of service in many industries, such as airlines and broadcasting, as well as financing a wide range of programs. In addition, the government regulates the flow of capital and uses financial tools such as the interest rate to control such factors as inflation and unemployment.<ref>"Capitalism." World Book Encyclopedia. 1988. p. 194.</ref> | |||
== Supply and demand == | |||
A problem with using "distribution of wealth" as a standard to measure economic systems is that such a standard can produce seemingly irrational judgments. Under the "distribution of wealth" standard, a system where everyone has nothing is judged as equal to a system where everyone has enormous wealth since the distribution of wealth in the two systems is equal. The claim is made that capitalist economics are not ] games and that more wealth for most people is actually "created" through innovation, and risk-taking. And that inequality may be necessary in this process. For example, the inheritance of wealth may cause people to continue working and saving when they get older. | |||
{{Main|Supply and demand}} | |||
] at each price (demand D): the diagram shows a positive shift in demand from D<sub>1</sub> to D<sub>2</sub>, resulting in an increase in price (P) and quantity sold (Q) of the product.]] | |||
In capitalist economic structures, supply and demand is an ] of ] in a ]. It postulates that in a ], the ] for a particular ] will vary until it settles at a point where the quantity demanded by consumers (at the current price) will equal the quantity supplied by producers (at the current price), resulting in an ] for price and ]. | |||
The "basic laws" of ] and ], as described by David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam, are the following four:<ref name="besanko-and-braeutigam-2010">{{cite book |last1=Besanko |first1=David |last2=Braeutigam |first2=Ronald |year=2010 |title=Microeconomics |publisher=] |edition=4th}}</ref>{{rp|37}} | |||
] has argued that no condition of perfect equality could be maintained for very long. If all agents possess the same amount of wealth, they will immediately begin investing it in different ventures which will pay off to varying degrees. Within moments of the first trade, then, inequality would be restored. But voluntary economic exchange is seen as leaving both parties better off as both would not be trading unless the outcome of the trade was an improvement for both. According to this view, even if the resulting distribution is not even, at least it is better than if there were no trading. | |||
# If demand increases (demand curve shifts to the right) and supply remains unchanged, then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price. | |||
# If demand decreases (demand curve shifts to the left) and supply remains unchanged, then a surplus occurs, leading to a lower equilibrium price. | |||
# If demand remains unchanged and supply increases (supply curve shifts to the right), then a surplus occurs, leading to a lower equilibrium price. | |||
# If demand remains unchanged and supply decreases (supply curve shifts to the left), then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price. | |||
=== Supply schedule === | |||
Thus, people who see uneven wealth distribution as a lesser or unavoidable problem tend to argue that if inequality leads to higher average wealth and higher wealth and income for most people, then wealth inequality may be acceptable. For example, there are far fewer poor in China today than under communism, even if there is more inequality. In response, critics of capitalism have argued that even if these arguments could justify ''some'' economic inequity, they cannot explain the very high inequality that capitalism brings with it. | |||
A supply schedule is a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied.<ref name="Boundless Economics 2017">{{cite web |title=Supply |website=Boundless Economics |date=13 June 2017 |url=https://courses.lumenlearning.com/boundless-economics/chapter/supply/ |access-date=27 October 2021}}</ref> | |||
=== Demand schedule === | |||
Other points of view on capitalism's wealth distribution include: | |||
A demand schedule, depicted graphically as the ], represents the amount of some ] that buyers are willing and able to purchase at various prices, assuming all determinants of demand other than the price of the good in question, such as income, tastes and preferences, the price of ]s and the price of ]s, remain the same. According to the ], the demand curve is almost always represented as downward sloping, meaning that as price decreases, consumers will buy more of the good.<ref name="axes">Unlike most ], supply & demand curves are plotted with the independent variable (price) on the vertical axis and the dependent variable (quantity supplied or demanded) on the horizontal axis.</ref> | |||
* Pro-Capitalist: | |||
** Collection of wealth in relatively few hands serves a function that in the end benefits all. (see ]) | |||
** Capitalist economies concentrate ] in the hands of those that are the most productive in terms of providing goods and services that society values. | |||
** The prospect of becoming wealthier than others serves as an incentive to produce (see ]). | |||
** A significant cause of poverty is the lack of capitalism. | |||
** Capitalism hasn't been properly implemented yet. | |||
** Wealth distribution concentrated in the hands of the minority of individuals is the natural outcome of capitalism since being more productive than others is a matter of being willing to exert oneself and most people are naturally content to "just get by" with minimal effort. | |||
** Financial markets and banks where most wealth is stored act as a means of redistribution of wealth (see ] and ]). Some say that this causes the simple dollar amounts assigned to a persons "net worth" to be completely misleading and inflated. | |||
Just like the supply curves reflect ] curves, demand curves are determined by ] curves.<ref>{{cite web|title=Marginal Utility and Demand |url=http://www.amosweb.com/cgi-bin/awb_nav.pl?s=wpd&c=dsp&k=marginal+utility+and+demand |access-date=9 February 2007 |archive-date=6 November 2006 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20061106121422/http://www.amosweb.com/cgi-bin/awb_nav.pl?s=wpd&c=dsp&k=marginal+utility+and+demand |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
* Anti-Capitalist: | |||
** Wealth is not beneficial to everyone - not even the wealthy. | |||
** Perhaps government interference in markets protects the wealthy. | |||
** Uneven distribution of wealth shows capitalism to be faulty, or immoral. | |||
** Many people have little wealth left over after living expenses, so they can't make it grow quickly. | |||
** Wealth is defined and judged incorrectly, in many different ways. | |||
=== Equilibrium === | |||
=== Competition, survival of the fittest and evolving network structure === | |||
{{further|Economic equilibrium}} | |||
Capitalist economies have large numbers of companies and people free to enter into many types of arrangements with each other. The economy reacts to various changes in technologies, discoveries, and other situations, by means of companies and individuals re-assessing their arrangements with each other. Therefore, the control mechanisms of the economy, and the way that information flows through it, evolve over time, and are subject to a kind of "survival of the fittest" form of selection and evolution not unlike biological entities. | |||
In the context of supply and demand, economic equilibrium refers to a state where economic forces such as ] are balanced and in the absence of external influences the (]) values of economic variables will not change. For example, in the standard text-book model of ] equilibrium occurs at the point at which quantity demanded and quantity supplied are equal.<ref>{{cite book |author-link=Hal Varian |first=Hal R. |last=Varian |title=Microeconomic Analysis |edition=Third |publisher=Norton |location=New York |year=1992 |isbn=978-0-393-95735-8 |url=https://archive.org/details/microeconomicana00vari_0}}</ref> Market equilibrium, in this case, refers to a condition where a market price is established through competition such that the amount of goods or services sought by ] is equal to the amount of goods or services produced by ]. This price is often called the competitive price or ] price and will tend not to change unless demand or supply changes. | |||
=== Partial equilibrium === | |||
Analysis of the ] of connections and arrangements in the economy has shown a degree of similarity to other networks such as the phone system or the Internet. has examples of networks of company board members. Networks of customer links, and monetary flows exhibit similar structures. | |||
{{Main|Partial equilibrium}} | |||
Partial equilibrium, as the name suggests, takes into consideration only a part of the market to attain equilibrium. Jain proposes (attributed to ]): "A partial equilibrium is one which is based on only a restricted range of data, a standard example is price of a single product, the prices of all other products being held fixed during the analysis".<ref>{{cite book |last=Jain |first=T.R. |title=Microeconomics and Basic Mathematics |year=2006 |publisher=VK Publications |location=New Delhi |isbn=978-81-87140-89-4 |page=28 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=fUUoFwco2Z8C }}{{Dead link|date=January 2023 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}</ref> | |||
=== History === | |||
=== Unknown/unapproved direction of capitalist economies === | |||
According to Hamid S. Hosseini, the "power of supply and demand" was discussed to some extent by several early Muslim scholars, such as fourteenth century ] scholar ], who wrote: "If desire for goods increases while its availability decreases, its price rises. On the other hand, if availability of the good increases and the desire for it decreases, the price comes down".<ref name=Hosseini>{{cite book |title=A Companion to the History of Economic Thought |chapter=Contributions of Medieval Muslim Scholars to the History of Economics and their Impact: A Refutation of the Schumpeterian Great Gap |last=Hosseini |first=Hamid S. |editor1-last=Biddle |editor1-first=Jeff E. |editor2-last=Davis |editor2-first=Jon B. |editor3-last=Samuels |editor3-first=Warren J. |year=2003 |publisher=Blackwell |location=Malden, Massachusetts |isbn=978-0-631-22573-7 |doi=10.1002/9780470999059.ch3 |pages=28–45 }} (citing Hamid S. Hosseini, 1995. "Understanding the Market Mechanism Before Adam Smith: Economic Thought in Medieval Islam," ''History of Political Economy'', Vol. 27, No. 3, 539–561).</ref> | |||
While there is a great deal of planning within companies and other organisations in capitalist economies, there is no economy-wide direction, or even any reliable prediction or knowledge of how the economy will behave or perform more than a year into the future. While nearly all transactions may be approved of and planned by the people taking part, many society-wide phenomena emerging from the transactions or markets are often not planned, predicted, or approved or authorised by anyone. A common feature in modern capitalist economies is for the State to maintain a certain degree of economic planning in order to stop huge economic fluctuations and additionally to give capitalist economies more longer-term aim. | |||
]]] | |||
Some argue that it is impossible to make accurate long term predictions about things like the weather or the economy, using arguments from ]. They see the unplanned development of capitalism as one of its greatest strengths, arguing that many solutions are tried and that real-world competition finds a good solution. This in contrast to ] of society which often decides for an incorrect solution due to faulty forecasting. | |||
]'s 1691 work ''Some Considerations on the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money''<ref>John Locke (1691) {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150324135856/https://www.marxists.org/reference/subject/economics/locke/contents.htm |date=24 March 2015 }}</ref> includes an early and clear description{{primary source inline|date=February 2022}} of supply and demand and their relationship. In this description, demand is ]: "The price of any commodity rises or falls by the proportion of the number of buyer and sellers" and "that which regulates the price... is nothing else but their quantity in proportion to their rent". | |||
] titled one chapter of his 1817 work '']'' "On the Influence of Demand and Supply on Price".<ref name=Humphrey>Thomas M. Humphrey, 1992. "Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses before Alfred Marshall", ''Economic Review'', Mar/Apr, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, pp. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121019100824/http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/economic_review/1992/pdf/er780201.pdf |date=19 October 2012 }}.</ref> | |||
=== Employment/unemployment === | |||
In ''Principles of Political Economy and Taxation'', Ricardo more rigorously laid down the idea of the assumptions that were used to build his ideas of supply and demand. | |||
Since individuals typically earn income through finding a company for which to work, it is possible that not all individuals will be able to find a company that will want their labor at a given time. This would not be such a big problem in an economy in which individuals had access to free resources, such as free access to land, to provide for themselves, but when ownership of the bulk of productive resources is collected in relatively few hands, most individuals are made dependent on employment for their well being. It is normal that all real capitalist economies have fluctuating ] rates typically between 3 and 15%. Some economists have used the term the "natural rate of unemployment" to describe this situation. | |||
In his 1870 essay "On the Graphical Representation of Supply and Demand", ] in the course of "introduc the diagrammatic method into the English economic literature" published the first drawing of supply and demand curves therein,<ref>A.D. Brownlie and M.F. Lloyd Prichard, 1963. "Professor Fleeming Jenkin, 1833–1885 Pioneer in Engineering and Political Economy", ''Oxford Economic Papers'', 15(3), p. 211.</ref> including ] from a shift of supply or demand and application to the labor market.<ref>Fleeming Jenkin, 1870. "The Graphical Representation of the Laws of Supply and Demand, and their Application to Labour", in Alexander Grant, ed., ''Recess Studies'', Edinburgh. Ch. VI, pp. 151–185. Edinburgh. Scroll to chapter {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200716052536/https://books.google.com/books?id=NC5BAAAAIAAJ |date=16 July 2020 }}.</ref> The model was further developed and popularized by ] in the 1890 textbook '']''.<ref name="Humphrey" /> | |||
Depressed or stagnant economies have been known to reach unemployment rates have reached levels of 30%, while events such as war mobilization (a good example is ]) have resulted in 1-2% unemployment, often called "full employment". A typical rate of unemployment in Western economies would range from a low of 5% to a high of 10%. Some economists consider a certain level of unemployment to be necessary for capitalist economies to function. Some political figures have claimed that the "natural rate of unemployment" shows the inefficiencies of a capitalist economy, since not all resources, human labor in this case, are efficiently allocated. | |||
== Types == | |||
Some ] economists, such as ], argue that higher unemployment is chiefly a result of ] laws, and is not a necessary part of a capitalist economy. Hazlitt argues in '']'' that if the value of the work of potential employees is less than the minimum wage, it would be a loss to the employer to employ these people. Thus, if there is ''any'' person whose productive capacity as an employee (for any employers) is less than the minimum wage, then that person will necessarily be unemployed -- so unemployment will exist whenever the legal minimum wage exceeds the actual value of the least productive members of the ]. Likewise, if the amount of money a person can receive on ] nears or meets the amount they could make by working, the person will have a reduced incentive to work. | |||
{{more citations needed section|date=March 2020}} | |||
There are many variants of capitalism in existence that differ according to country and region.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Hall |first1=Peter A. |last2=Soskice |first2=David |title=Varieties Of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage |date=20 September 2001 |publisher=Oxford University Press, U.S.A. |isbn=0-19-924775-7}}</ref> They vary in their institutional makeup and by their economic policies. The common features among all the different forms of capitalism are that they are predominantly based on the private ownership of the means of production and the production of goods and services for profit; the market-based allocation of resources; and the accumulation of capital. | |||
They include advanced capitalism, corporate capitalism, finance capitalism, free-market capitalism, mercantilism, social capitalism, state capitalism and welfare capitalism. Other theoretical variants of capitalism include ], ], ], ], ], and ]. | |||
Some unemployment is voluntary, as when not accepting a possible job because searching for a better one, or when voluntarily living on savings or in a non-wage-earning role such as a traditional ]. Many measures of unemployment do not include these types of unemployment -- they count only people who are actively seeking employment and have not been able to find offers. | |||
=== Advanced === | |||
=== Size of government, taxes, regulations and market failures === | |||
{{Main|Advanced capitalism}} | |||
Many consider an economy with lower taxes, smaller government and fewer regulations to be more capitalistic. ] claim that capitalism require no government or taxes. Others doubt that property rights could exist in such a system and consider ] to be the most capitalistic economy. | |||
Advanced capitalism is the situation that pertains to a society in which the capitalist model has been integrated and developed deeply and extensively for a prolonged period. Various writers identify ] as an influential early theorist of advanced capitalism, even if he did not use the term himself. In his writings, Gramsci sought to explain how capitalism had adapted to avoid the revolutionary overthrow that had seemed inevitable in the 19th century. At the heart of his explanation was the decline of raw coercion as a tool of class power, replaced by use of ] institutions to manipulate public ideology in the capitalists' favour.<ref>Lears, T.J. Jackson (1985) "The Concept of Cultural Hegemony"</ref><ref>Holub, Renate (2005) ''Antonio Gramsci: Beyond Marxism and Postmodernism''</ref><ref>] (2012) ''Ecology and Revolution: Global Crisis and the Political Challenge''</ref> | |||
] has been a major contributor to the analysis of advanced-capitalistic societies. Habermas observed four general features that characterise advanced capitalism: | |||
The last century saw a very large increase in these variables in western countries. Combined U.S. government spending increased from 3-4% of GDP to 33%. An average for 16 industrial nations jumped from 8% of GDP to 45%. Thus it can be argued that the degree of capitalism has seen a remarkable ''decline'' in Western nations. | |||
# Concentration of industrial activity in a few large firms. | |||
# Constant reliance on the state to stabilise the economic system. | |||
# A formally democratic government that legitimises the activities of the state and dissipates opposition to the system. | |||
# The use of nominal wage increases to pacify the most restless segments of the work force.<ref>Habermas, 1988: 37, 75.</ref> | |||
=== Corporate === | |||
Related to this is the question of market failures. A ] is a case in which a market fails to efficiently provide or allocate goods and services. Examples could be ], health care, unemployment or wealth inequality. ] argue that there are no market failures. ] that the markets always fail. Between these extremes there are a wide spectrum of political ideologies with different views on market failures and how to prevent them. | |||
{{Main|Corporate capitalism}} | |||
{{See also|Crony capitalism|State monopoly capitalism}} | |||
Corporate capitalism is a free or mixed-market capitalist economy characterized by the dominance of hierarchical, bureaucratic corporations. | |||
=== Finance === | |||
One explanation for the apparent decline in capitalism is that the Western nations have increasingly regulated various market failures. Libertarians would instead argue that the regulations restrict competition, that the taxes go to the special interest groups with the most political clout and that the almost constantly expanding governments do things less efficiently than the private sector. One warning historical example being the constantly growing size of taxes and regulations in Rome before the fall of that civilization. | |||
{{Main|Finance capitalism}} | |||
{{See also|Capitalist mode of production (Marxist theory)}} | |||
Finance capitalism is the subordination of processes of ] to the accumulation of ] profits in a ]. In their critique of capitalism, ] and ] both emphasise the role of ] as the determining and ] interest in capitalist society, particularly in the ].<ref>] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150402214909/https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1916/imp-hsc/ch03.htm |date=2 April 2015 }}</ref><ref>{{cite magazine|url=http://monthlyreview.org/2009/10/01/monopoly-finance-capital-and-the-paradox-of-accumulation/|title= Monopoly-Finance Capital and the Paradox of Accumulation |first1=John Bellamy |last1=Foster |author1-link=John Bellamy Foster |first2=Robert W. |last2=McChesney |author2-link=Robert W. McChesney |date=1 October 2009 |magazine=] |access-date=27 August 2016 |archive-date=28 August 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160828081218/http://monthlyreview.org/2009/10/01/monopoly-finance-capital-and-the-paradox-of-accumulation/ |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
] is credited with first bringing the term finance capitalism into prominence through ''Finance Capital'', his 1910 study of the links between German trusts, banks and monopolies—a study subsumed by ] into '']'' (1917), his analysis of the imperialist relations of the great world powers.<ref>Frederic Jameson, 'Culture and Finance Capital', in ''The Jameson Reader'' (2005) p. 257</ref> Lenin concluded that the banks at that time operated as "the chief nerve centres of the whole capitalist system of national economy".<ref>Quoted in E.H. Carr, ''The Bolshevik Revolution 2'' (1971) p. 137</ref> For the ] (founded in 1919), the phrase "dictatorship of finance capitalism"<ref>Quoted in F.A Voight, ''Unto Caesar'' (1938) p. 22</ref> became a regular one. | |||
==Other approaches== | |||
=== Capitalism in political ideologies === | |||
''Main article: ]'' | |||
] would later point to two earlier periods when finance capitalism had emerged in human history—with the Genoese in the 16th century and with the Dutch in the 17th and 18th centuries—although at those points it developed from commercial capitalism.<ref>C. J.Calhoun/G. Derluguian, ''Business as Usual'' (2011) p. 57</ref>{{request quotation|date=December 2016}} ] extended Braudel's analysis to suggest that a predominance of finance capitalism is a recurring, long-term phenomenon, whenever a previous phase of commercial/industrial capitalist expansion reaches a plateau.<ref>Jameson, pp. 259–260</ref> | |||
=== Marxist critique of capitalism === | |||
] and others criticize capitalism for enriching capitalists (owners of ]) at the expense of workers without necessarily working themselves ("the rich get richer, and the poor get poorer"), and for the degree of control over the lives of workers enjoyed by owners. Supporters of capitalism counter this criticism by claiming that ownership of productive capacity provides motivation to owners to increase productive capacity and so generally increase the average material wealth ("we all get richer"). Opponents of capitalism counter this by pointing out the unchanged after-tax income of the poorest quintile of the US population during the last two decades. While at the same time the average income and especially the income of the US rich have increased. . Supporters of capitalism point out that the percentage of people in developing countries living below $1 per day have halved in only twenty years, especially in countries like China that have embraced capitalism . | |||
=== Free market === | |||
Marxists believe that capitalism allows capitalists - the owners of capital - to ] workers. The existence of private property is seen as a restriction on freedom. Marxists also argue that capitalism has inherent contradictions that will inevitably lead to its collapse. Capitalism is seen as just one stage in the evolution of the economy of a society. | |||
{{Main|Free-market capitalism}} | |||
{{See also|Laissez-faire}} | |||
{{More citations needed|section|date=December 2021}} | |||
A capitalist free-market economy is an economic system where prices for goods and services are set entirely by the forces of ] and are expected, by its adherents, to reach their point of ] without intervention by government policy. It typically entails support for highly ] and ] of the ]. ''Laissez-faire'' capitalism is a more extensive form of this free-market economy, but one in which the role of the state is limited to protecting ]. In ] theory, property rights are protected by private firms and market-generated law. According to anarcho-capitalists, this entails property rights without statutory law through market-generated tort, contract and property law, and self-sustaining private industry. | |||
] argued that free market exchange and capitalism are to some degree opposed; free market exchange involves ] public transactions and a large number of ], while capitalism involves a small number of participants using their capital to control the market via private transactions, control of information, and limitation of competition.<ref name="Braudel Ranum Ranum Johns Hopkins University 1977 p. 47-63">{{cite book |last1=Braudel |first1=F. |author-link=Fernand Braudel |last2=Ranum |first2=P.M. |last3=Ranum |first3=P.P. |title=Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism |publisher=] |series=Johns Hopkins symposia in comparative history |year=1977 |isbn=978-0-8018-1901-8 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=1eVdAAAAIAAJ |access-date=6 April 2022 |pages=47–63}}</ref> | |||
Marxists also often argue that the structure of capitalism necessarily leads to unjust exploitation of workers, regardless of whether or not the political system is one of an elected democracy. For this reason Marxists typically emphasise the capitalist economic system of Western countries rather than the democratic political system. A capitalist system is an economic system - although often associated with democratic political systems, they are independent from each other. Capitalist systems have often functioned under unelected governments, some examples being ], ], and ] under the rule of General ]. | |||
=== Mercantile === | |||
In ] differences in terminology sometimes confuse and complicate discussions of ]. Under ], which is the official state ideology, capitalism refers to a stage of history in which there is a class system in which the proletariat is exploited by the bourgeoisie. In the official Chinese ideology, China is currently in the primary stage of ]. However, because of ]'s dictum to ], this view does not prevent China from undertaking policies which in the West would be considered capitalistic including employing wage labor, increasing unemployment to motivate those who are still working, transforming state owned enterprises into joint stock companies, and encouraging the growth of the joint venture and private capitalist sectors. | |||
{{Main|Mercantilism}} | |||
{{See also|Protectionism}} | |||
] in the early 19th century]] | |||
Mercantilism is a nationalist form of early capitalism that came into existence approximately in the late 16th century. It is characterized by the intertwining of national business interests with state-interest and imperialism. Consequently, the state apparatus is used to advance national business interests abroad. An example of this is colonists living in America who were only allowed to trade with and purchase goods from their respective mother countries (e.g., United Kingdom, France and Portugal). Mercantilism was driven by the belief that the wealth of a nation is increased through a positive balance of trade with other nations—it corresponds to the phase of capitalist development sometimes called the ]. | |||
=== Social === | |||
=== Which Economies are "Capitalist" ? === | |||
{{Main|Social market economy}} | |||
In mainstream economics, a capitalist economy is one where the overwhelming majority of production and consumption is private and is handled through a free market that includes free enterprise. However, exactly where to draw the line in labeling economies is a matter of some debate. | |||
{{See also|Nordic model}} | |||
A social market economy is a free-market or mixed-market capitalist system, sometimes classified as a ], where government intervention in price formation is kept to a minimum, but the state provides significant services in areas such as social security, health care, unemployment benefits and the recognition of ] through national ] arrangements. | |||
This model is prominent in Western and Northern European countries as well as Japan, albeit in slightly different configurations. The vast majority of enterprises are privately owned in this economic model. | |||
Some believe that it is inaccurate to call any of the major industrialized economies "capitalist" because of the level of government intervention in the economy. For example, some assert that the market in the United States of America is significantly less than "free", and that therefore it is more appropriately termed a '']'' that is merely skewed more toward capitalism than most national economies, rather than being a true representation of capitalism. Still others might say that the U.S. economy is capitalist, but the U.K. economy is a "mixed economy," and so on, depending upon their perception of how much economic freedom exists in those locales. | |||
] is the contemporary model of capitalism and adaptation of the social market model that exists in continental Western Europe today. | |||
Many Greens, Marxists and anti-Globalists agree that the governments of the major industrial economies are not serving in the role of protecting "the free market", but would go on to say that these governments are, in fact, acting to protect the owners of capital and corporations as their first priority, sometimes expressed as "socialism for the rich, capitalism (cut throat competition) for the poor." These critics, therefore, would assert that the correct term for the core industrial nations is neither capitalism, nor mixed economy, but ]. Libertarians and other free-market advocates may also share this opinion regarding some or all of the major economies. | |||
=== State === | |||
Nevertheless, mainstream economists, for their part, admit that the present economic systems have diverged from earlier forms labeled "capitalism", and many believe that some of the modern economies are still best described as being "capitalism" rather than "mixed economy" or "corporatist." | |||
{{Main|State capitalism}} | |||
State capitalism is a capitalist market economy dominated by state-owned enterprises, where the state enterprises are organized as commercial, profit-seeking businesses. The designation has been used broadly throughout the 20th century to designate a number of different economic forms, ranging from state-ownership in market economies to the command economies of the former ]. According to Aldo Musacchio, a professor at Harvard Business School, state capitalism is a system in which governments, whether democratic or autocratic, exercise a widespread influence on the economy either through direct ownership or various subsidies. Musacchio notes a number of differences between today's state capitalism and its predecessors. In his opinion, gone are the days when governments appointed bureaucrats to run companies: the world's largest state-owned enterprises are now traded on the public markets and kept in good health by large institutional investors. Contemporary state capitalism is associated with the ], ] and the economy of Norway.<ref>{{cite news |last=Musacchio |first=Aldo |url=http://www.economist.com/debate/days/view/802 |title=Economist Debates: State capitalism: Statements |newspaper=The Economist |access-date=20 June 2012 |archive-date=16 July 2012 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120716050641/http://economist.com/debate/days/view/802 |url-status=live }}</ref> Alternatively, ] defines state capitalism as "an economic system in which private capitalism is modified by a varying degree of government ownership and control".<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150703131303/http://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/state%20capitalism |date=3 July 2015 }}. ]. Retrieved 7 July 2015.</ref> | |||
In ''Socialism: Utopian and Scientific'', ] argued that state-owned enterprises would characterize the final stage of capitalism, consisting of ownership and management of large-scale production and communication by the ].<ref>{{cite web |first=Frederick |last=Engels |author-link=Friedrich Engels |url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1880/soc-utop/ch03.htm |title=Socialism: Utopian and Scientific (Chpt. 3) |publisher=] |access-date=8 January 2014 |archive-date=9 May 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200509191523/https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1880/soc-utop/ch03.htm |url-status=live}}</ref> In his writings, ] characterized the economy of Soviet Russia as state capitalist, believing state capitalism to be an early step toward the development of socialism.<ref>V.I. Lenin. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150907043921/https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1921/apr/21.htm |date=7 September 2015 }}. ''Lenin's Collected Works'', 1st English ed., Progress Publishers, Moscow, 1965, vol. 32, pp. 329–365.</ref><ref>V.I. Lenin. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150618071802/https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1922/nov/14b.htm |date=18 June 2015 }}. ''Lenin Collected Works'', Progress Publishers, 1971, Moscow, vol. 42, pp. 425c–427a.</ref> | |||
Another classification, associated largely with the ] of economics, regards most present economic systems as a perversion of capitalism, sometimes called ], and envisages a de-cronied capitalist ideal. | |||
Some economists and left-wing academics including ] and ], as well as many Marxist philosophers and revolutionaries such as ] and ], argue that the economies of the former ] and Eastern Bloc represented a form of state capitalism because their internal organization within enterprises and the system of wage labor remained intact.<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190728140836/https://www.hetsa.org.au/pdf/34-A-08.pdf |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20221009/https://www.hetsa.org.au/pdf/34-A-08.pdf |archive-date=9 October 2022 |url-status=live |date=28 July 2019 }}, M.C. Howard and J.E. King</ref><ref>] (1986). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150924051230/http://www.chomsky.info/articles/1986----.htm |date=24 September 2015 }}. ''Our Generation''. Retrieved 9 July 2015.</ref><ref>] (27 June 2015). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180311070639/http://www.truth-out.org/news/item/31567-socialism-means-abolishing-the-distinction-between-bosses-and-employees |date=11 March 2018 }}. ''].'' Retrieved 9 July 2015.</ref><ref>{{cite web|first1=Raya |last1=Dunayevskaya |author-link1=Raya Dunayevskaya |date=1941 |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/dunayevskaya/works/1941/ussr-capitalist.htm |title=The Union of Soviet Socialist Republics is a Capitalist Society |website=] |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191207212742/https://www.marxists.org/archive/dunayevskaya/works/1941/ussr-capitalist.htm |archive-date=7 December 2019}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|first1=C.L.R. |last1=James |author-link1=C.L.R. James |first2=Raya |last2=Dunayevskaya |author-link2=Raya Dunayevskaya |first3=Grace Lee |last3=Boggs |author-link3=Grace Lee Boggs |date=1950 |url=https://libcom.org/files/State%20capitalism%20and%20world%20revolution%20-%20CLR%20James.pdf |title=State Capitalism and World Revolution |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200619014753/https://libcom.org/files/State%20capitalism%20and%20world%20revolution%20-%20CLR%20James.pdf |archive-date=19 June 2020}}</ref> | |||
Some use the phrase "]" to distinguish between "ordinary capitalism," believing that there is a difference. Some also use the phrase to differentiate their preferred economic system from present economic systems which they believe are wrongly labeled as capitalism by many. These also say that the phrase "laissez-faire capitalism" is redundant, pointing out that the common definition of capitalism explicitly refers to trade occuring in a "free market." These assert that "capitalism" is already a laissez-faire system by definition. | |||
The term is not used by ] economists to describe state ownership of the means of production. The economist ] argued that the designation of state capitalism was a new label for the old labels of state socialism and planned economy and differed only in non-essentials from these earlier designations.<ref>{{cite book|first=Ludwig |last=Von Mises |author-link=Ludwig Von Mises |title=Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis |publisher=LibertyClassics |place=Indianapolis |year=1979 |isbn=978-0-913966-63-1 |url=https://archive.org/details/socialismeconomi00vonm |access-date=31 May 2007 |quote=The socialist movement takes great pains to circulate frequently new labels for its ideally constructed state. Each worn-out label is replaced by another which raises hopes of an ultimate solution of the insoluble basic problem of Socialism—until it becomes obvious that nothing has been changed but the name. The most recent slogan is 'State Capitalism.' It is not commonly realized that this covers nothing more than what used to be called Planned Economy and State Socialism, and that State Capitalism, Planned Economy, and State Socialism diverge only in non-essentials from the "classic" ideal of egalitarian Socialism. |url-access=registration}}</ref> | |||
Proponents of the world-system perspective suggest that the whole globe has been incorporated into a single capitalist world-economy. Even though a state may be socialist, it works in relation to a much larger, overarching capitalist world-economy. | |||
=== |
=== Welfare === | ||
{{Main|Welfare capitalism}} | |||
There are two ] used in economic research, one published by the ](a ] thinktank) and the ], another published by the ]. Both attempt to measure of the degree of capitalism in countries. They use statistics from independent organizations like the ] to score countries in various categories like the size of government, degree of taxes, security of property rights, degree of free trade and size of market regulations. Many peer-reviewed papers have been published using this material on the relationship between capitalism and for example poverty . The more capitalistic countries have much higher average income per person, higher income of the poorest 10%, higher life-expectancy, higher literacy, lower infant mortality, higher access to water sources and less corrupton. The share of income in percent going to the poorest 10% is the same for both more and less capitalistic countries . Other studies have shown similar results . | |||
{{See also|Economic interventionism|Mixed economy}} | |||
Welfare capitalism is capitalism that includes social welfare policies. Today, welfare capitalism is most often associated with the models of capitalism found in Central Mainland and Northern Europe such as the ], ] and ]. In some cases, welfare capitalism exists within a mixed economy, but welfare states can and do exist independently of policies common to mixed economies such as ] and extensive regulation. | |||
A mixed economy is a largely market-based capitalist economy consisting of both private and public ownership of the means of production and ] through macroeconomic policies intended to correct ]s, reduce unemployment and keep inflation low. The degree of intervention in markets varies among different countries. Some mixed economies such as France under ] also featured a degree of ] over a largely capitalist-based economy. | |||
Attempts to decide the importance of the subcomponents of the indexes have often yielded contradictory results. However, strong property rights may be particularly important. The economist ] has argued that weak property rights, especially for the poor, play a major role in poverty and underdevelopment in developing countries | |||
. Many developing countries are now trying to strengthen and simplify their property rights system after the successful application of his ideas in Peru . | |||
Most modern capitalist economies are defined as mixed economies to some degree<ins>,</ins> however French economist ] state that capitalist economies might shift to a much more ''laissez-faire'' approach in the near future.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Piketty |first=Thomas |title=Le capital au XXIe siècle |year=2013 |isbn=978-2-02-108228-9 |pages=799, 800 |language=fr |chapter=Repenser l'impôt progressif sur le revenu |publisher=Éditions du Seuil |trans-chapter=To rethink income tax progressivity |quote=Si cette régressivité fiscale au sommet de la hiérarchie sociale devait se confirmer et s'amplifier à l'avenir, il est bien évident qu'une telle sécession fiscale des plus riches est potentiellement extrêmement dommageable pour le consentement fiscal dans son ensemble s'en trouve amoindri . Il est vital pour l'État social moderne que le système fiscal qui le sous-tend conserve un minimum de progressivité. |trans-quote=If tax regressivity on top of the social hierarchy may settle in and escalate in the future, it is obvious that such a tax secession between the richest and the other classes will be highly harmful towards the agreement over the taxation system which will weaken. It is essential for the modern social system that the taxation system preserve a sort of tax progressivity.}}</ref> | |||
=== Eco-capitalism === | |||
], also known as "environmental capitalism" or (sometimes<ref>{{cite news|url=https://www.theguardian.com/world/2019/nov/24/b-corps-captalism-for-an-environmentally-endangered-age |title=Green capitalism sometimes also referring to sustainable businesses |first=Oliver |last=Balch |date=24 November 2019 |work=]}}</ref>) "green capitalism", is the view that ] exists in nature as "]" (]s that have ]) on which all ] depends. Therefore, governments should use ] ] (such as a ]) to resolve ]s.<ref>{{cite web|title=Definition of Eco-Capitalism |url=https://www.collinsdictionary.com/dictionary/english/eco-capitalism |website=collinsdictionary.com |access-date= 27 November 2015}}</ref> | |||
The term "Blue Greens" is often applied to those who espouse eco-capitalism. Eco-capitalism can be thought of as the right-wing equivalent to ].<ref>{{cite web|title=The rise of green capitalism |url=http://roadtoparis.info/top-list/rise-green-capitalism/ |website=roadtoparis.info |access-date=27 November 2015}}</ref>{{request quotation|date=August 2019}} | |||
=== Sustainable capitalism === | |||
] is a conceptual form of capitalism based upon ] practices that seek to preserve humanity and the planet, while reducing ] and bearing a resemblance of capitalist ]. A capitalistic economy must expand to survive and find new markets to support this expansion.<ref>{{cite book |doi=10.1109/IPCC.2011.6087226 |chapter=The convergence of sustainable capitalism |title=2011 IEEE International Professional Communication Conference |pages=1–7 |year=2011 |last1=Mitra |first1=Basavadatta |last2=Gadhok |first2=Saagar |last3=Salhotra |first3=Shivam |last4=Agarwal |first4=Sakshi |isbn=978-1-61284-779-5 |s2cid=31292223 }}</ref> Capitalist systems are often destructive to the environment as well as certain individuals without access to proper representation. However, sustainability provides quite the opposite; it implies not only a continuation, but a ].<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Schweickart |first1=David |title=Is Sustainable Capitalism an Oxymoron? |journal=Perspectives on Global Development and Technology |date=1 January 2009 |volume=8 |issue=2–3 |pages=559–580 |doi=10.1163/156914909X424033 }}</ref> Sustainability is often thought of to be related to ], and sustainable capitalism applies sustainable principles to economic governance and social aspects of capitalism as well. | |||
The importance of sustainable capitalism has been more recently recognized, but the concept is not new. Changes to the current economic model would have heavy social environmental and economic implications and require the efforts of individuals, as well as compliance of local, state and federal governments. Controversy surrounds the concept as it requires an increase in sustainable practices and a marked decrease in current consumptive behaviors.<ref name=":2">{{Cite book |title=Sustainable Capitalism and the Pursuit of Well-Being.|last=E.|first=Harrison, Neil|date=1 January 2013|publisher=Routledge|isbn=978-1-306-21804-7|oclc=866837827}}{{page needed|date=March 2019}}</ref> | |||
This is a concept of capitalism described in ] and ]'s manifesto for the ] to describe a long-term political, economic and social structure which would mitigate current threats to the planet and society.<ref name="genfound">{{Cite web |last1=Gore |first1=Al |last2=Blood |first2=David |title=A Manifesto for Sustainable Capitalism |url=https://www.genfound.org/media/pdf-wsj-manifesto-sustainable-capitalism-14-12-11.pdf |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140124005644/https://www.genfound.org/media/pdf-wsj-manifesto-sustainable-capitalism-14-12-11.pdf |archive-date=24 January 2014 |access-date=24 October 2022 |website=Generation Foundation}}</ref> According to their manifesto, sustainable capitalism would integrate the environmental, social and governance (]) aspects into risk assessment in attempt to limit externalities.<ref name=":0b">{{Cite web|url=https://www.generationim.com/media/pdf-generation-sustainable-capitalism-v1.pdf |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20221009/https://www.generationim.com/media/pdf-generation-sustainable-capitalism-v1.pdf |archive-date=9 October 2022 |url-status=live|title=Sustainable Capitalism|access-date=18 February 2017}}</ref> Most of the ideas they list are related to economic changes, and social aspects, but strikingly few are explicitly related to any environmental policy change.<ref name="genfound" /> | |||
== Capital accumulation == | |||
{{Main|Capital accumulation}} | |||
The accumulation of capital is the process of "making money" or growing an initial sum of money through investment in production. Capitalism is based on the accumulation of capital, whereby ] is invested in order to make a profit and then reinvested into further production in a continuous process of accumulation. In Marxian economic theory, this dynamic is called the ]. Capital accumulation forms the basis of capitalism, where economic activity is structured around the accumulation of ], defined as investment in order to realize a financial profit.<ref name="Economist definition">{{cite news | title = Economics A–Z: ''Capital'' | url = http://www.economist.com/economics-a-to-z/c#node-21529870 | website = ] | access-date = 25 March 2015 | archive-date = 7 August 2017 | archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20170807235225/http://www.economist.com/economics-a-to-z/c#node-21529870 | url-status = live }}</ref> In this context, "capital" is defined as money or a financial asset invested for the purpose of making more money (whether in the form of profit, rent, interest, royalties, capital gain or some other kind of return).<ref name="MIA definition">{{cite web | title = Encyclopedia of Marxism – Glossary of terms: ''Capital'' | url = http://marxists.org/glossary/terms/c/a.htm#capital | website = ] | access-date = 25 March 2015 | archive-date = 18 June 2015 | archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20150618083941/https://www.marxists.org/glossary/terms/c/a.htm#capital | url-status = live }}</ref> | |||
In mainstream ], ] and ], capital accumulation is often equated with ] of profit income or savings, especially in ] capital goods. The concentration and centralisation of capital are two of the results of such accumulation. In modern ] and ], the phrase "]" is often used in preference to "accumulation", though the ] (UNCTAD) refers nowadays to "accumulation". The term "accumulation" is occasionally used in ]. | |||
== Wage labor == | |||
{{Main|Wage labour}} | |||
], ], {{Circa|1995}}–2000)]] | |||
Wage labor refers to the sale of ] under a formal or informal ] to an ].<ref name="Steinfeld 2009 3"/> These transactions usually occur in a ] where ]s are market determined.<ref>{{Harvnb|Deakin|Wilkinson|2005}}.<br />{{Harvnb|Marx|1990|p=1005}}, defines wage labour succinctly as "the labour of the worker who sells his own labour-power."</ref> In Marxist economics, these owners of the means of production and suppliers of capital are generally called capitalists. The description of the role of the capitalist has shifted, first referring to a useless intermediary between producers, then to an employer of producers, and finally to the owners of the means of production.<ref name="Williams 1983 51" /> ] includes all physical and mental human resources, including entrepreneurial capacity and management skills, which are required to produce products and services. ] is the act of making goods or services by applying ].<ref>Ragan, Christopher T.S.; Lipsey, Richard G. ''Microeconomics''. 12th Canadian ed. Toronto, Pearson Education, 2008. {{ISBN|978-0-321-31491-8}}</ref><ref>Robbins, Richard H. ''Global problems and the culture of capitalism''. Boston: Allyn & Bacon, 2007. {{ISBN|978-0-205-52487-7}}</ref> | |||
== Criticism == | |||
{{Main|Criticism of capitalism}} | |||
] poster "]" (1911)]] | |||
Criticism of capitalism comes from various political and philosophical approaches, including ], ], ] and ] viewpoints.<ref>{{cite book|last=Tormey|first=Simon|title=Anticapitalism|publisher=One World Publications|year=2004|page=10|isbn=978-1-78074-250-2}}</ref> Of those who oppose it or want to modify it, some believe that capitalism should be removed through ] while others believe that it should be changed slowly through ].<ref>{{cite book|title=Book: Sociology (Boundless)|chapter=16.1C: The Marxist Critique of Capitalism|url=https://socialsci.libretexts.org/@go/page/8462|date=16 December 2020|publisher=LibreTexts|access-date=21 October 2021|quote=Revolutionary socialists believe that capitalism can only be overcome through revolution. Social democrats believe that structural change can come slowly through political reforms to capitalism.}}</ref><ref name="The Cambridge History of Communism p.">{{cite book | editor-last=Pons | editor-first=Silvio | editor-last2=Smith | editor-first2=Stephen A. | title=The Cambridge History of Communism | publisher=Cambridge University Press | date=21 September 2017 | isbn=978-1-316-13702-4 | doi=10.1017/9781316137024 | pages=49–73}}</ref> | |||
Prominent critiques of capitalism allege that it is inherently ],<ref name="competition">{{cite web|url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1845/condition-working-class/ch05.htm|title=Competition – The Condition of the Working Class in England|last=Engels|first=Frederick|access-date=10 March 2008}}</ref><ref name="stanfordexploitation">{{Cite web|date=20 December 2001|title=Exploitation|url=https://plato.stanford.edu/entries/exploitation/|url-status=live|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20201127091753/https://plato.stanford.edu/entries/exploitation/|archive-date=27 November 2020|access-date=26 December 2020|website=]}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Mattei|first=Clara E.|date=2022 |title=The Capital Order: How Economists Invented Austerity and Paved the Way to Fascism|pages=17–18|url=https://press.uchicago.edu/ucp/books/book/chicago/C/bo181707138.html|location= |publisher=]|isbn=978-0-226-81839-9}}</ref> ],<ref>"Alienation." Pp. 10. in ''A Dictionary of Philosophy'' (rev. 2nd ed.). 1984.</ref> ],<ref name="onfreetrade">{{cite web|url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1888/free-trade/index.htm|title=On the Question of Free Trade|last=Engels|first=Frederick|access-date=11 March 2008}}</ref><ref name="isrcrisis">{{cite web|url=http://www.isreview.org/issues/32/crisis_theory.shtml|title=Marx's Theory of Economic Crisis|last=Easterling|first=Earl|publisher=International Socialist Review|access-date=13 March 2008|archive-date=27 February 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210227033442/https://isreview.org/issues/32/crisis_theory.shtml|url-status=dead}}</ref> ],<ref name="extinction">{{cite book|last=Dawson|first=Ashley|author-link=Ashley Dawson|title=Extinction: A Radical History|date=2016|publisher=]|url=http://www.orbooks.com/catalog/extinction-by-ashley-dawson/|page=41|isbn=978-1-944869-01-4|access-date=20 August 2016|archive-date=17 September 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160917203814/http://www.orbooks.com/catalog/extinction-by-ashley-dawson/|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |last=Nelson |first=Anitra |date=31 January 2024 |title=Degrowth as a Concept and Practice : Introduction |url=https://commonslibrary.org/degrowth-as-a-concept-and-practice-introduction/ |access-date=24 February 2024 |website=The Commons Social Change Library |language=en-AU}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |title=Earth at risk: An urgent call to end the age of destruction and forge a just and sustainable future |journal=PNAS Nexus |date=4 April 2024 |volume=3 |issue=4 |doi=10.1093/pnasnexus/pgae106 |url=https://academic.oup.com/pnasnexus/article/3/4/pgae106/7638480?login=false |access-date=4 April 2024|pmc=10986754 |last1=Fletcher |first1=Charles |last2=Ripple |first2=William J. |last3=Newsome |first3=Thomas |last4=Barnard |first4=Phoebe |last5=Beamer |first5=Kamanamaikalani |last6=Behl |first6=Aishwarya |last7=Bowen |first7=Jay |last8=Cooney |first8=Michael |last9=Crist |first9=Eileen |last10=Field |first10=Christopher |last11=Hiser |first11=Krista |last12=Karl |first12=David M. |last13=King |first13=David A. |last14=Mann |first14=Michael E. |last15=McGregor |first15=Davianna P. |last16=Mora |first16=Camilo |last17=Oreskes |first17=Naomi |last18=Wilson |first18=Michael |pages=pgae106 |pmid=38566756 }}</ref> and ]<ref>{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=BlEpAQAAMAAJ|title=Beyond the Profits System: Possibilities for a post-capitalist era|last=Shutt|first=Harry|date=March 2010|publisher=Zed Books|isbn=978-1-84813-417-1}}</ref><ref name="isrwaste">{{cite web|url=http://www.isreview.org/issues/53/garbage.shtml|title=The Conquest of Garbage|last=Rogers|first=Heather|website=isreview.org|publisher=International Socialist Review (1997)|access-date=13 March 2008|archive-date=10 May 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210510142346/http://www.isreview.org/issues/53/garbage.shtml|url-status=dead}}</ref><ref name="part6">{{cite web|url=http://www.chass.utoronto.ca/~reak/eco100/100_6.htm|title=Monopoly, Imperfect Competition, and Oligopoly|last=Rea|first=K.J.|access-date=11 March 2008|archive-date=12 June 2010|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100612201706/http://www.chass.utoronto.ca/~reak/eco100/100_6.htm|url-status=dead}}</ref>—and that it creates massive ],<ref name="King 2021">{{cite web|last=King|first=Matthew Wilburn|title=Why the next stage of capitalism is coming|website=BBC Future|date=25 May 2021|url=https://www.bbc.com/future/article/20210525-why-the-next-stage-of-capitalism-is-coming|access-date=21 October 2021}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Ghodsee|first1=Kristen|last2=Orenstein|first2=Mitchell A.|author-link1=Kristen Ghodsee|date=2021|title=Taking Stock of Shock: Social Consequences of the 1989 Revolutions|publisher=]|page=192|doi=10.1093/oso/9780197549230.001.0001 |isbn=978-0-19-754924-7|quote=Without an accompanying welfare state in which social programs funded by a progressive income tax redistribute from the rich to the poor, capitalism can be a deeply unfair system where a small, well-connected elite captures a majority of the wealth and power, and not necessarily through meritocratic processes.}}</ref> ] people,<ref name="openDemocracy">{{cite web | title=Commodification: the essence of our time | website=openDemocracy | url=https://www.opendemocracy.net/en/opendemocracyuk/commodification-essence-of-our-time/ | access-date=21 October 2021 | author= Colin Leys | date = 2 April 2021}}</ref><ref name="Renegade Inc 2019">{{cite web | title=The Commodification of Everything | website=Renegade Inc | date=25 August 2019 | url=http://renegadeinc.com/the-commodification-of-everything/ | access-date=21 October 2021 | author=Daniel Margrain | archive-date=21 October 2021 | archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211021224916/https://renegadeinc.com/the-commodification-of-everything/ | url-status=dead }}</ref> ],<ref name="extinction" /><ref>{{cite book|last=Hickel|first=Jason|author-link=Jason Hickel|title=Less is More: How Degrowth Will Save the World |year=2021|publisher=Windmill Books|pages=39–40|isbn=978-1-78609-121-5|quote=It was only with the rise of capitalism over the past few hundred years, and the breathtaking acceleration of industrialization from the 1950s, that on a planetary scale things began to tip out of balance.}}</ref> is ],<ref name="Merkel pp. 109–128">{{cite journal | last=Merkel | first=Wolfgang | title=Is capitalism compatible with democracy? | journal=Zeitschrift für Vergleichende Politikwissenschaft | publisher=Springer Science and Business Media LLC | volume=8 | issue=2 | date=26 July 2014 | issn=1865-2646 | doi=10.1007/s12286-014-0199-4 | pages=109–128| hdl=10419/270951 | s2cid=150776013 | hdl-access=free }}</ref><ref name="Reich 2009">{{cite web | last=Reich | first=Robert B. | title=How Capitalism Is Killing Democracy | website=Foreign Policy | date=12 October 2009 | url=https://foreignpolicy.com/2009/10/12/how-capitalism-is-killing-democracy/ | access-date=21 October 2021}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Slobodian|first=Quinn |author-link=Quinn Slobodian|date=2023 |title=Crack-Up Capitalism: Market Radicals and the Dream of a World Without Democracy|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=tIlrEAAAQBAJ&pg=PT10|location= |publisher=]|page=10 |isbn=978-1-250-75389-2}} | |||
</ref> embeds ] and ] between nation states,<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Patnaik |first1=Utsa |title='Neo-Marxian' Theories of Capitalism and Underdevelopment: Towards a Critique |journal=Social Scientist |date=1982 |volume=10 |issue=11 |pages=3–32 |doi=10.2307/3516858 |jstor=3516858 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/3516858 |issn=0970-0293}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Warke |first1=Thomas W. |title=The Marxian Theory of Underdevelopment: A Review Article |journal=The Journal of Developing Areas |date=1973 |volume=7 |issue=4 |pages=699–710 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/4190085#:~:text=it%20is%20Lenin%20who%20laid,modern%20Marxian%20theory%20of%20underdevelopment.&text=and%20tends%20to%20perpetuate%20the,masses%20in%20the%20backward%20country.&text=world%20production%20and%20trade%20and,dualisms%20within%20under%2D%20developed%20economies. |issn=0022-037X}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Martins |first1=Carlos Eduardo |title=The Longue Durée of the Marxist Theory of Dependency and the Twenty-First Century |journal=Latin American Perspectives |date=January 2022 |volume=49 |issue=1 |pages=18–35 |doi=10.1177/0094582X211052029 |url=https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1177/0094582X211052029 |language=en |issn=0094-582X}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Peck |first1=Jamie |last2=Varadarajan |first2=Latha |title=Uneven Regional Development |journal=International Encyclopedia of Geography: People, the Earth, Environment and Technology |date=6 March 2017 |pages=1–13 |doi=10.1002/9781118786352.wbieg0721 |url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1002/9781118786352.wbieg0721 |publisher=John Wiley & Sons, Ltd |isbn=9780470659632 |language=en}}</ref> and leads to an erosion of ]<ref>{{cite journal|last=Abeles|first=Marc|date=2006|title=Globalization, Power, and Survival: an Anthropological Perspective|url=https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00125880/file/M_Abeles_2006_AQ.pdf |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20221009/https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00125880/file/M_Abeles_2006_AQ.pdf |archive-date=9 October 2022 |url-status=live|journal=Anthropological Quarterly|volume=79|issue=3|pages=484–486|doi=10.1353/anq.2006.0030|s2cid=144220354}}</ref> because of its ] of ] expansion and ].<ref>{{cite journal|last=Farid|first=Hilmar|date=2005|title=Indonesia's original sin: mass killings and capitalist expansion, 1965–66|journal=]|volume=6|issue=1|pages=3–16|doi=10.1080/1462394042000326879|s2cid=145130614}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|last=Blakeley|first=Ruth|date=2009|title=State Terrorism and Neoliberalism: The North in the South|url=http://www.routledge.com/books/details/9780415462402/|publisher=]|pages=, , |isbn=978-0-415-68617-4}}</ref><ref>''Lenin's Selected Works'', Progress Publishers, 1963, Moscow, Volume 1, pp. 667–766</ref> | |||
Other critics argue that such inequities are not due to the ethic-neutral construct of the economic system commonly known as capitalism, but to the ethics of those who shape and execute the system. For example, some contend that Milton Friedman's (human) ethic of 'maximizing shareholder value' creates a harmful form of capitalism,<ref>{{Cite book |last=Stout |first=Lynn |author-link=Lynn Stout |title=The Shareholder Value Myth |publisher=Berrett-Koehler Publishers, Inc. |year=2012 |isbn=978-1-60509-813-5 |location=San Francisco, CA |pages=15–23}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book |last=Gelles |first=David |author-link=David Gelles |title=The Man Who Broke Capitalism |publisher=Simon & Schuster |year=2022 |isbn=978-1-9821-7644-0 |location=New York |pages=1–13}}</ref> while a ] or John Bogle (human) ethic of 'enough' creates a sustainable form.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Fuller |first=Millard |author-link=Millard Fuller|title=The Theology of the Hammer |publisher=Smyth & Helwys Publishing |year=1994 |isbn=1-880837-92-7 |location=Macon, GA |pages=31–39}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book |last=Bogle |first=John |title=Enough |publisher=John Wiley & Sons |year=2009 |isbn=978-0-470-52423-7 |location=Hoboken, New Jersey |pages=229–248}}</ref> Equitable ethics and unified ethical decision-making is theorized to create a less damaging form of capitalism.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Knowlton & Hedges |title=Better Capitalism |publisher=Wipf & Stock Publishers |year=2021 |isbn=978-1-7252-8093-9 |location=Eugene, OR |pages=34–37, 235–242}}</ref> | |||
] has been argued to not be a fundamental part of capitalism,<ref name="x107">{{cite journal | last=Haslett | first=D. W. | title=Is Inheritance Justified? | journal=Philosophy & Public Affairs | publisher=Wiley | volume=15 | issue=2 | year=1986 | issn=0048-3915 | jstor=2265382 | pages=122–155 | url=http://www.jstor.org/stable/2265382 | access-date=17 August 2024}}</ref> instead part of ].<ref name="e543">{{cite journal | last=Pérez-González | first=Francisco | title=Inherited Control and Firm Performance | journal=American Economic Review | volume=96 | issue=5 | date=1 November 2006 | issn=0002-8282 | doi=10.1257/aer.96.5.1559 | pages=1559–1588}}</ref> | |||
== See also == | == See also == | ||
{{cols|colwidth=16em}} | |||
{{wikiquote}} | |||
* ] | |||
* Related topics: ], ], ], ] | |||
* |
* ] | ||
* ] | |||
* Related ideologies: ] (], ], ], ]), ] (]), ], ], ] (], ], ], ]), ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* '']'' | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
{{colend}} | |||
== |
== References == | ||
; Notes | |||
* | |||
{{reflist}} | |||
* | |||
* | |||
* | |||
* | |||
* | |||
* | |||
* - Distributed Capitalism | |||
* | |||
* | |||
* | |||
* | |||
; Bibliography | |||
==Books== | |||
{{refbegin|30em}} | |||
* Chandler, Alfred D., Jr. ''The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business''. Cambridge, Mass., and London: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1977. | |||
* {{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=w_6PqBp64y0C&pg=PA2|title=Capitalism, Ethics and the Paradoxon of Self-Exploitation|last=Bacher|first=Christian|publisher=GRIN Verlag|year=2007|isbn=978-3-638-63658-2|location=Munich|page=2|access-date=27 June 2015|archive-date=1 November 2015|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151101095357/https://books.google.com/books?id=w_6PqBp64y0C&lpg=PP1&pg=PA2|url-status=live}} | |||
* Landes, David S. ''The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present''. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1969. | |||
* {{cite book | last = Boldizzoni | first = Francesco | author-link = Francesco Boldizzoni | title = Foretelling the End of Capitalism: Intellectual Misadventures since Karl Marx | publisher= Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press| year = 2020 | isbn = 978-0-674-91932-7}} | |||
* Rostow, W. W. ''The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto''. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1960. | |||
* {{cite journal|last= Carsel|first= Wilfred|year= 1940|title= The Slaveholders' Indictment of Northern Wage Slavery|journal= ]|volume= 6|issue= 4|pages= 504–520|jstor= 2192167|doi= 10.2307/2192167}} | |||
* Rand, Ayn, ''Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal'' ISBN 0451147952 | |||
* {{cite book|title= The Law of the Labour Market: Industrialization, Employment, and Legal Evolution|last2= Wilkinson|first2= Frank|publisher=Oxford University Press|year= 2005|isbn= 978-0-19-815281-1|location= Oxford|last1= Deakin|first1= Simon|author1-link= Simon Deakin|author2-link= Frank Wilkinson}} | |||
* Smith, Adam, ''The Wealth of Nations (An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of)'' | |||
* {{cite book|title=Business Ethics|url=https://archive.org/details/businessethics00dege|url-access=registration|last=De George|first=Richard T.|publisher=Macmillan|year=1986|isbn=978-0-02-328010-8|location=New York|page=}} | |||
* {{cite book|title= Britain's Gulag: The Brutal End of Empire in Kenya|last= Elkins|first= Caroline|publisher= ]|year= 2005|isbn= 978-0-224-07363-9|location= London|author-link= Caroline Elkins}} | |||
* {{cite book|url= https://books.google.com/books?id=ECdb7EjiBnEC|title= Cannibals All! or, Slaves Without Masters|last= Fitzhugh|first= George|publisher= A. Morris|year= 1857|isbn= 978-1-4290-1643-8|location= Richmond, VA|author-link= George Fitzhugh|access-date= 27 June 2015|archive-date= 18 October 2015|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20151018025643/https://books.google.com/books?id=ECdb7EjiBnEC|url-status= live}} | |||
* {{cite book|title=Capitalism A Very Short Introduction|last=Fulcher|first=James|publisher=Oxford University Press|year=2004|isbn=978-0-19-280218-7|location=Oxford|url=https://archive.org/details/capitalismverysh00fulc_0}} | |||
* {{cite book|title= Fragments of an Anarchist Anthropology|last= Graeber|first= David|publisher= Prickly Paradigm Press|year= 2004|isbn= 978-0-9728196-4-0|title-link= Fragments of an Anarchist Anthropology}} | |||
* {{cite book|title= Possibilities: Essays on Hierarchy, Rebellion and Desire|last= Graeber|first= David|publisher= AK Press|year= 2007|isbn= 978-1-904859-66-6}} | |||
* {{cite journal|last2= Benoit|first2= Cecilia|year= 2007|title= From Wage Slaves to Wage Workers: Cultural Opportunity Structures and the Evolution of the Wage Demands of the Knights of Labor and the American Federation of Labor, 1880–1900|journal= ]|volume= 85|issue= 3|pages= 1393–411|doi=10.1353/sof.2007.0037|jstor= 4494978|last1= Hallgrimsdottir|first1= Helga Kristin|s2cid= 154551793}} | |||
* {{cite book|url= https://www.academia.edu/4199690|title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 1: Global Markets and Capitalism|last2= Gills|first2= Barry|publisher= SAGE Publications|year= 2007|location= London|last1= James|first1= Paul|author-link= Paul James (academic)|access-date= 17 May 2014|archive-date= 23 September 2020|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063538/https://www.academia.edu/4199690/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol_1_Global_Markets_and_Capitalism_2007_|url-status= live}} | |||
* Krahn, Harvey J., and Graham S. Lowe (1993). ''Work, Industry, and Canadian Society''. 2nd ed. Scarborough, Ont.: Nelson Canada. xii, 430 p. {{ISBN|0-17-603540-0}} | |||
* {{cite book|title= The Penguin Dictionary of Sociology|last2=Urry|first2= John|publisher= Penguin Books|year= 2000|isbn= 978-0-14-051380-6|edition= 4th|location= London|pages= 36–40|chapter=Capitalism|last1= Lash|first1=Scott|author-link1=Scott Lash|author-link2=John Urry (sociologist)|editor1-first= Nicholas|editor1-last=Abercrombie|editor2-first=Stephen|editor2-last=Hill|editor3-first= Bryan S|editor3-last=Turner|editor3-link=Bryan S. Turner}} | |||
* {{cite journal|date= August 2011|title= The Current Crisis and the Essence of Capitalism|url= http://www.themontrealreview.com/2009/The-current-crisis-and-the-essence-of-capitalism.php|journal= The Montreal Review|issn= 0707-9656|last1= McCraw|first1= Thomas K.|author-link= Thomas K. McCraw|access-date= 14 August 2011|archive-date= 8 September 2011|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20110908122337/http://www.themontrealreview.com/2009/The-current-crisis-and-the-essence-of-capitalism.php|url-status= live}} | |||
* {{cite journal|last= Nelson|first= John O.|year= 1995|title= That a Worker's Labour Cannot Be a Commodity|journal= ]|volume= 70|issue= 272|pages= 157–165|doi=10.1017/s0031819100065359|jstor= 3751199|s2cid= 171054136}} | |||
* {{cite book|url=https://archive.org/details/unset0000unse_o9p3/page/1|title=Profit Theory and Capitalism|publisher=University of Pennsylvania Press |year=1983|isbn=978-0-8122-7863-7|location=Philadelphia|page=|author=Obrinsky, Mark}} | |||
* {{cite book|title= The Kaiser's Holocaust: Germany's Forgotten Genocide|last2= Erichsen|first2= Casper W.|publisher= ]|year= 2010|isbn= 978-0-571-23141-6|location= London|last1= Olusoga|first1= David}} | |||
* {{cite book|url= http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/wage-labour/|title= Wage Labour and Capital|last= Marx|first= Karl|year= 1847|author-link= Karl Marx|access-date= 25 March 2015|archive-date= 6 September 2019|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20190906075046/https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/wage-labour/|url-status= live}} | |||
* {{cite book|title= Capital, Volume I|last= Marx|first= Karl|publisher= Penguin Classics|year= 1990|isbn= 978-0-14-044568-8|location= London|orig-year= 1867|title-link= Capital, Volume I}} | |||
* {{cite book|title= The Wages of Whiteness: Race and the Making of the American Working Class|last= Roediger|first= David|publisher= ]|year= 2007a|isbn= 978-1-84467-145-8|edition= revised and expanded|location= London & New York|author-link= David Roediger|orig-year= 1991}} | |||
* {{cite journal|last= Roediger|first= David|year= 2007b|title= An Outmoded Approach to Labour and Slavery|journal= ]|volume= 60|pages= 245–250|jstor= 25149808|author-link= David Roediger}} | |||
* {{cite journal|last= Steinfeld|first= Robert|year= 2009|title= Coercion/Consent in Labor|url= http://www.compas.ox.ac.uk/fileadmin/files/Publications/working_papers/WP_2009/WP0966%20Steinfeld.pdf|series= COMPAS Working Paper No. 66|location= Oxford|publisher= University of Oxford|access-date= 3 March 2013|url-status= dead|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20140301173031/http://www.compas.ox.ac.uk/fileadmin/files/Publications/working_papers/WP_2009/WP0966%20Steinfeld.pdf|archive-date= 1 March 2014}} | |||
* {{cite book|title=Europe and the People Without History|last=Wolf|first=Eric R.|publisher=University of California Press|year=1982|isbn=978-0-520-04459-3|location=Berkeley|author-link=Eric Wolf|title-link=Europe and the People Without History}} | |||
* {{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=FZPyKjVguVoC|title=The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View|last=Wood|first=Ellen Meiksins|publisher=Verso|year=2002|isbn=978-1-85984-392-5|location=London|author-link=Ellen Meiksins Wood|access-date=27 June 2015|archive-date=28 November 2015|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151128060418/https://books.google.com/books?id=FZPyKjVguVoC|url-status=live}} | |||
* {{cite book|title= Peasant Revolution in Ethiopia: The Tigray People's Liberation Front, 1975–1991|last= Young|first= John|publisher= Cambridge University Press|year= 1997|isbn= 978-0-521-02606-2|location= Cambridge}} | |||
{{refend}} | |||
== Further reading == | |||
{{refbegin|colwidth=30em}} | |||
* ] (2011). ''America Beyond Capitalism: Reclaiming Our Wealth, Our Liberty, and Our Democracy, 2nd Edition.'' Democracy Collaborative Press. {{ISBN|0-9847857-0-1}}. | |||
* {{cite book|last1=Altvater |first1=Elmar |last2=Crist|first2=Eileen|last3=Haraway|first3=Donna|author3-link=Donna Haraway|last4=Hartley|first4=Daniel|last5=Parenti|first5=Christian|last6=McBrien|first6=Justin|last7=Moore|first7=Jason|title=Anthropocene or Capitalocene? Nature, History, and the Crisis of Capitalism|date=2016|publisher=PM Press|isbn=978-1-62963-148-6}} | |||
* Ascher, Ivan. ''Portfolio Society: On the Capitalist Mode of Prediction.'' Zone Books, 2016. {{ISBN|978-1935408741}} | |||
* ] ''The Half Has Never Been Told: Slavery and the Making of American Capitalism.'' New York, ], 2014. {{ISBN|0-465-00296-X}}. | |||
* {{cite book | first = Richard | last = Barbrook | year = 2006 | title = The Class of the New | edition = paperback | publisher = OpenMute | location = London | isbn = 978-0-9550664-7-4 | url = http://www.theclassofthenew.net | access-date = 11 June 2019 | archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20180801045453/http://www.theclassofthenew.net/ | archive-date = 1 August 2018 | url-status = dead }} | |||
* {{cite book|last1= Block |first1= Fred |author1-link= Fred L. Block |last2= Somers |first2= Margaret R. |year= 2014|title= The Power of Market Fundamentalism: Karl Polyani's Critique|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= Harvard University Press|isbn= 978-0-674-05071-6}} | |||
* {{cite book | last = Boldizzoni | first = Francesco | author-link = Francesco Boldizzoni | title = Foretelling the End of Capitalism: Intellectual Misadventures since Karl Marx | publisher= Harvard University Press| year = 2020 | isbn = 978-0-674-91932-7}} | |||
* ]. ''Civilization and Capitalism, 15th-18th Century'', 3 volumes. | |||
* Callinicos, Alex. "Wage Labour and State Capitalism – A reply to Peter Binns and Mike Haynes", ''International Socialism'', 2nd series, 12, Spring 1979. | |||
* {{cite book |last1=Case |first1=Anne |last2=Deaton |first2=Angus |author-link1=Anne Case |author-link2=Angus Deaton |date=2020 |title=Deaths of Despair and the Future of Capitalism |url=https://press.princeton.edu/books/hardcover/9780691190785/deaths-of-despair-and-the-future-of-capitalism |publisher=] |isbn=978-0-691-19078-5 |access-date=6 March 2020 |archive-date=7 March 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200307062358/https://press.princeton.edu/books/hardcover/9780691190785/deaths-of-despair-and-the-future-of-capitalism |url-status=live }} | |||
* Farl, Erich. "The Genealogy of State Capitalism". In: ''International'' London, vol. 2, no. 1, 1973. | |||
* {{cite book |last=Fisher|first=Mark |author-link=Mark Fisher|date=2009 |title=]|location= |publisher= ]|isbn=978-1-84694-317-1}} | |||
* Gough, Ian. '' {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120207145856/http://www.newleftreview.org/?view=558 |date=7 February 2012 }}'' New Left Review. | |||
* ] '']'' (eng. translation by T. McCarthy). Boston, Beacon. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151120102451/https://books.google.com/books?id=3WFy6vsyLNEC |date=20 November 2015 }}; . | |||
* {{cite book | last = Harvey | first = David | author-link = David Harvey | title = Seventeen Contradictions and the End of Capitalism | publisher= Oxford University Press| year = 2014 | isbn = 978-0-19-936026-0}} | |||
* ] and ] (2014). ''American Capitalism: A Reader.'' Simon & Schuster. {{ISBN|978-1-4767-8431-1}}. | |||
* {{cite book |last1=Ingham |first1=Geoffrey |title=Capitalism: With a New Postscript on the Financial Crisis and Its Aftermath |date=2008 |publisher=] |location=Cambridge |isbn=9780745636481}} | |||
* {{cite book | year= 2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | author-link= Paul James (academic) | last2= Patomäki | first2= Heikki | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 2: Global Finance and the New Global Economy | url= https://www.academia.edu/4211923 | publisher= SAGE Publications | location= London | access-date= 28 January 2018 | archive-date= 23 September 2020 | archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063542/https://www.academia.edu/4211923/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol_2_Global_Finance_and_the_New_Global_Economy_2007_ | url-status= live }} | |||
* {{cite book | year= 2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | author-link= Paul James (academic) | last2= Palen | first2= Ronen | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 3: Global Economic Regimes and Institutions | url= https://www.academia.edu/4251331 | publisher= Sage Publications | location= London | access-date= 28 January 2018 | archive-date= 23 September 2020 | archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063542/https://www.academia.edu/4251331/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol_3_Global_Economic_Regimes_and_Institutions_2007_ | url-status= live }} | |||
* {{cite book | year= 2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | author-link= Paul James (academic) | last2= O'Brien | first2= Robert | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 4: Globalizing Labour | url= https://www.academia.edu/4303461 | publisher= Sage Publications | location= London | access-date= 28 January 2018 | archive-date= 23 September 2020 | archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063543/https://www.academia.edu/4303461/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol_4_Globalizing_Labour_2007_ | url-status= live }} | |||
* Jameson, Fredric (1991). '']''. | |||
* {{cite book |last1=Kocka |first1=Jürgen |title=Capitalism: A Short History |date=2016 |publisher=] |location=Princeton |isbn=978-0691165226}} | |||
* Kotler, Philip (2015). ''Confronting Capitalism: Real Solutions for a Troubled Economic System.'' AMACOM. {{ISBN|978-0814436455}} | |||
* Mandel, Ernest (1999). ''Late Capitalism.'' {{ISBN|978-1859842027}} | |||
* {{cite book | last = Mander | first = Jerry | author-link = Jerry Mander | title = The Capitalism Papers: Fatal Flaws of an Obsolete System | publisher= Counterpoint | year = 2012 | isbn = 978-1-61902-158-7}} | |||
* Marcel van der Linden, ''Western Marxism and the Soviet Union''. New York, Brill Publishers, 2007. | |||
* Mayfield, Anthony. "Economics", in his ''On the Brink: Resource Depletion, Debt Collapse, and Super-technology'' (: On the Brink Publishing, 2013), pp. 50–104. | |||
* {{cite book|last1= Musacchio |first1= Aldo |last2= Lazzarini |first2= Sergio G. |year= 2014|title= Reinventing State Capitalism: Leviathan in Business, Brazil and Beyond|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= Harvard University Press|isbn= 978-0-674-72968-1}} | |||
* {{cite book|last=Newitz|first=Annalee|title=Pretend We're Dead: Capitalist Monsters in American Pop Culture|date=2006|publisher=Duke University Press|location=Durham, NC|isbn=978-0-8223-3745-4|url=https://www.dukeupress.edu/Pretend-Were-Dead/|access-date=26 October 2016|archive-date=26 October 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161026234517/https://www.dukeupress.edu/Pretend-Were-Dead/|url-status=live}} | |||
* {{cite book |last1=Nitzan|first1=Jonathan |author-link1=Jonathan Nitzan|last2=Bichler|first2=Shimshon |author-link2=Shimshon Bichler|date=2009 |title=Capital as Power: A Study of Order and Creorder|url= |location= |publisher=]|page= |isbn=978-0-415-49680-3}} | |||
* Panitch, Leo, and Sam Gindin (2012). ''The Making of Global Capitalism: the Political Economy of American Empire''. London, Verso. {{ISBN|978-1-84467-742-9}}. | |||
* {{cite book|last= Piketty |first= Thomas |author-link= Thomas Piketty |year= 2014|title= Capital in the Twenty-First Century|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= ]|isbn= 978-0-674-43000-6 |title-link= Capital in the Twenty-First Century}} | |||
* {{cite book|last= Piketty |first= Thomas |year= 2020|title=Capital and Ideology|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= Belknap Press|isbn=978-0-674-98082-2|title-link= Capital and Ideology }} | |||
* ] (2001). '']: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time.'' ]; 2nd ed. {{ISBN|0-8070-5643-X}} | |||
* {{cite book|title= Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life|last=Reisman|first= George|year= 1998|isbn= 978-0-915463-73-2 | |||
|publisher =Jameson Books}} | |||
* ] (2009). ''Money, Greed, and God: Why Capitalism is the Solution and Not the Problem''. New York: ]. {{ISBN|978-0-06-137561-3}} | |||
* ] (2013). ''The Failure of Laissez-faire Capitalism: towards a New Economics for a Full World''. Atlanta, Ga.: Clarity Press. {{ISBN|978-0-9860362-5-5}} | |||
* ] ''Global Capitalism and the Crisis of Humanity.'' Cambridge University Press, 2014. {{ISBN|1-107-69111-7}} | |||
* {{cite book |last=Schram |first=Sanford F. |title=The Return of Ordinary Capitalism: Neoliberalism, Precarity, Occupy |year=2015 |publisher=Oxford University Press |url=https://global.oup.com/academic/product/the-return-of-ordinary-capitalism-9780190253011?cc=us& |isbn=978-0-19-025302-8 |access-date=12 February 2017 |archive-date=23 September 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063546/https://global.oup.com/academic/product/the-return-of-ordinary-capitalism-9780190253011?cc=us&lang=en& |url-status=live }} | |||
* Hoevet, Ocean. (New Palgrave article) | |||
* ] (1916) ''Der moderne Kapitalismus. Historisch-systematische Darstellung des gesamteuropäischen Wirtschaftslebens von seinen Anfängen bis zur Gegenwart.'' Final edn. 1916, repr. 1969, paperback edn. (3 vols. in 6): 1987 Munich: dtv. (Also in Spanish; no English translation yet.) | |||
* {{cite book |last1=Sonenscher |first1=Michael |title=Capitalism: The Story behind the Word |date=2022 |publisher=] |location=Princeton |isbn=9780691237206}} | |||
* ], "Better, Faster, Stronger" (review of ], ''The Philosopher of Palo Alto: Mark Weisner, Xerox PARC, and the Original Internet of Things'', University of Chicago Press, 347 pp.; and ], ''Palo Alto: A History of California, Capitalism, and the World'', Little, Brown, 708 pp.), '']'', vol. LXX, no. 14 (21 September 2023), pp. 38–40. " a place where the contradictions are sharpened to their finest points, above all the defining and enduring contradictions between ] and antidemocratic practice. There is nothing as American as celebrating ] while subverting it. Or as ]n." (p. 40.) | |||
* {{cite book | last = Wallerstein| first = Immanuel | author-link = Immanuel Wallerstein | title = Historical Capitalism | publisher= ] | year = 1983 | isbn = 978-0-86091-761-8}} | |||
* {{cite book | last = Wolff | first = Richard D. | author-link = Richard D. Wolff | title = Democracy at Work: A Cure for Capitalism | publisher= ] | year = 2012 | isbn = 978-1-60846-247-6}} | |||
* {{cite book | last = Wood | first = Ellen Meiksins | author-link = Ellen Meiksins Wood | title = The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View | publisher= ] | year = 2002 | isbn = 978-1-85984-392-5}} | |||
{{refend}} | |||
== External links == | |||
] | |||
{{Commons category|Capitalism}} | |||
] | |||
{{EB1922 Poster}} | |||
] | |||
{{Wikiquote}} | |||
{{Wiktionary}} | |||
* {{In Our Time|Capitalism|p00545kv|Capitalism}} | |||
* at '']'' Online. | |||
* {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180123134446/http://www.hup.harvard.edu/features/capitalism-and-its-discontents.html |date=23 January 2018 }}. ]. | |||
{{library resources box|by=no|onlinebooks=no|others=no|about=yes|label=Capitalism}} | |||
{{Aspects of capitalism}} | |||
] | |||
{{navboxes | |||
] | |||
|list= | |||
] | |||
{{Political ideologies}} | |||
] | |||
{{Political philosophy}} | |||
] | |||
{{Marxist & Communist phraseology}} | |||
] | |||
{{Western culture}} | |||
] | |||
}} | |||
] | |||
{{Portal bar|Companies|Capitalism|Law|Liberalism|Libertarianism|Politics}} | |||
] | |||
{{authority control}} | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
{{DEFAULTSORT:Capitalism}} | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] |
Revision as of 12:56, 24 December 2024
Economic system based on private ownership This article is about an economic system. For other uses, see Capitalism (disambiguation). "Capitalist" redirects here. For other uses, see Capitalist (disambiguation).
Part of a series on |
Economic systems |
---|
Major types |
By ideology |
By coordination |
By regional model
|
Sectors |
Property types |
Transition |
Coordination |
Other types |
Capitalism is an economic system based on the private ownership of the means of production and their operation for profit. The defining characteristics of capitalism include private property, capital accumulation, competitive markets, price systems, recognition of property rights, self-interest, economic freedom, meritocracy, work ethic, consumer sovereignty, economic efficiency, decentralized decision-making, profit motive, a financial infrastructure of money and investment that makes possible credit and debt, entrepreneurship, commodification, voluntary exchange, wage labor, production of commodities and services, and a strong emphasis on innovation and economic growth. In a market economy, decision-making and investments are determined by owners of wealth, property, or ability to maneuver capital or production ability in capital and financial markets—whereas prices and the distribution of goods and services are mainly determined by competition in goods and services markets.
Economists, historians, political economists, and sociologists have adopted different perspectives in their analyses of capitalism and have recognized various forms of it in practice. These include laissez-faire or free-market capitalism, anarcho-capitalism, state capitalism, and welfare capitalism. Different forms of capitalism feature varying degrees of free markets, public ownership, obstacles to free competition, and state-sanctioned social policies. The degree of competition in markets and the role of intervention and regulation, as well as the scope of state ownership, vary across different models of capitalism. The extent to which different markets are free and the rules defining private property are matters of politics and policy. Most of the existing capitalist economies are mixed economies that combine elements of free markets with state intervention and in some cases economic planning.
Capitalism in its modern form emerged from agrarianism in England, as well as mercantilist practices by European countries between the 16th and 18th centuries. The Industrial Revolution of the 18th century established capitalism as a dominant mode of production, characterized by factory work and a complex division of labor. Through the process of globalization, capitalism spread across the world in the 19th and 20th centuries, especially before World War I and after the end of the Cold War. During the 19th century, capitalism was largely unregulated by the state, but became more regulated in the post–World War II period through Keynesianism, followed by a return of more unregulated capitalism starting in the 1980s through neoliberalism.
The existence of market economies has been observed under many forms of government and across a vast array of historical periods, geographical locations, and cultural contexts. The modern industrial capitalist societies that exist today developed in Western Europe as a result of the Industrial Revolution. The accumulation of capital is the primary mechanism through which capitalist economies promote economic growth. However, it is a characteristic of such economies that they experience a business cycle of economic growth followed by recessions.
Etymology
The term "capitalist", meaning an owner of capital, appears earlier than the term "capitalism" and dates to the mid-17th century. "Capitalism" is derived from capital, which evolved from capitale, a late Latin word based on caput, meaning "head"—which is also the origin of "chattel" and "cattle" in the sense of movable property (only much later to refer only to livestock). Capitale emerged in the 12th to 13th centuries to refer to funds, stock of merchandise, sum of money or money carrying interest. By 1283, it was used in the sense of the capital assets of a trading firm and was often interchanged with other words—wealth, money, funds, goods, assets, property and so on.
The Hollantse (German: holländische) Mercurius uses "capitalists" in 1633 and 1654 to refer to owners of capital. In French, Étienne Clavier referred to capitalistes in 1788, four years before its first recorded English usage by Arthur Young in his work Travels in France (1792). In his Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817), David Ricardo referred to "the capitalist" many times. English poet Samuel Taylor Coleridge used "capitalist" in his work Table Talk (1823). Pierre-Joseph Proudhon used the term in his first work, What is Property? (1840), to refer to the owners of capital. Benjamin Disraeli used the term in his 1845 work Sybil. Alexander Hamilton used "capitalist" in his Report of Manufactures presented to the United States Congress in 1791.
The initial use of the term "capitalism" in its modern sense is attributed to Louis Blanc in 1850 ("What I call 'capitalism' that is to say the appropriation of capital by some to the exclusion of others") and Pierre-Joseph Proudhon in 1861 ("Economic and social regime in which capital, the source of income, does not generally belong to those who make it work through their labor"). Karl Marx frequently referred to the "capital" and to the "capitalist mode of production" in Das Kapital (1867). Marx did not use the form capitalism but instead used capital, capitalist and capitalist mode of production, which appear frequently. Due to the word being coined by socialist critics of capitalism, economist and historian Robert Hessen stated that the term "capitalism" itself is a term of disparagement and a misnomer for economic individualism. Bernard Harcourt agrees with the statement that the term is a misnomer, adding that it misleadingly suggests that there is such a thing as "capital" that inherently functions in certain ways and is governed by stable economic laws of its own.
In the English language, the term "capitalism" first appears, according to the Oxford English Dictionary (OED), in 1854, in the novel The Newcomes by novelist William Makepeace Thackeray, where the word meant "having ownership of capital". Also according to the OED, Carl Adolph Douai, a German American socialist and abolitionist, used the term "private capitalism" in 1863.
Other terms sometimes used for capitalism are:
- Capitalist mode of production
- Economic liberalism
- Free enterprise
- Free enterprise economy
- Free market
- Free market economy
- Laissez-faire
- Market economy
- Profits system
- Self-regulating market
Definition
There is no universally agreed upon definition of capitalism; it is unclear whether or not capitalism characterizes an entire society, a specific type of social order, or crucial components or elements of a society. Societies officially founded in opposition to capitalism (such as the Soviet Union) have sometimes been argued to actually exhibit characteristics of capitalism. Nancy Fraser describes usage of the term "capitalism" by many authors as "mainly rhetorical, functioning less as an actual concept than as a gesture toward the need for a concept". Scholars who are uncritical of capitalism rarely actually use the term "capitalism". Some doubt that the term "capitalism" possesses valid scientific dignity, and it is generally not discussed in mainstream economics, with economist Daron Acemoglu suggesting that the term "capitalism" should be abandoned entirely. Consequently, understanding of the concept of capitalism tends to be heavily influenced by opponents of capitalism and by the followers and critics of Karl Marx.
History
Main article: History of capitalismCapitalism, in its modern form, can be traced to the emergence of agrarian capitalism and mercantilism in the early Renaissance, in city-states like Florence. Capital has existed incipiently on a small scale for centuries in the form of merchant, renting and lending activities and occasionally as small-scale industry with some wage labor. Simple commodity exchange and consequently simple commodity production, which is the initial basis for the growth of capital from trade, have a very long history. During the Islamic Golden Age, Arabs promulgated capitalist economic policies such as free trade and banking. Their use of Indo-Arabic numerals facilitated bookkeeping. These innovations migrated to Europe through trade partners in cities such as Venice and Pisa. Italian mathematicians traveled the Mediterranean talking to Arab traders and returned to popularize the use of Indo-Arabic numerals in Europe.
Agrarianism
The economic foundations of the feudal agricultural system began to shift substantially in 16th-century England as the manorial system had broken down and land began to become concentrated in the hands of fewer landlords with increasingly large estates. Instead of a serf-based system of labor, workers were increasingly employed as part of a broader and expanding money-based economy. The system put pressure on both landlords and tenants to increase the productivity of agriculture to make profit; the weakened coercive power of the aristocracy to extract peasant surpluses encouraged them to try better methods, and the tenants also had incentive to improve their methods in order to flourish in a competitive labor market. Terms of rent for land were becoming subject to economic market forces rather than to the previous stagnant system of custom and feudal obligation.
Mercantilism
Main article: MercantilismThe economic doctrine prevailing from the 16th to the 18th centuries is commonly called mercantilism. This period, the Age of Discovery, was associated with the geographic exploration of foreign lands by merchant traders, especially from England and the Low Countries. Mercantilism was a system of trade for profit, although commodities were still largely produced by non-capitalist methods. Most scholars consider the era of merchant capitalism and mercantilism as the origin of modern capitalism, although Karl Polanyi argued that the hallmark of capitalism is the establishment of generalized markets for what he called the "fictitious commodities", i.e. land, labor and money. Accordingly, he argued that "not until 1834 was a competitive labor market established in England, hence industrial capitalism as a social system cannot be said to have existed before that date".
England began a large-scale and integrative approach to mercantilism during the Elizabethan Era (1558–1603). A systematic and coherent explanation of balance of trade was made public through Thomas Mun's argument England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, or the Balance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of Our Treasure. It was written in the 1620s and published in 1664.
European merchants, backed by state controls, subsidies and monopolies, made most of their profits by buying and selling goods. In the words of Francis Bacon, the purpose of mercantilism was "the opening and well-balancing of trade; the cherishing of manufacturers; the banishing of idleness; the repressing of waste and excess by sumptuary laws; the improvement and husbanding of the soil; the regulation of prices...".
After the period of the proto-industrialization, the British East India Company and the Dutch East India Company, after massive contributions from the Mughal Bengal, inaugurated an expansive era of commerce and trade. These companies were characterized by their colonial and expansionary powers given to them by nation-states. During this era, merchants, who had traded under the previous stage of mercantilism, invested capital in the East India Companies and other colonies, seeking a return on investment.
Industrial Revolution
Main article: Industrial RevolutionIn the mid-18th century a group of economic theorists, led by David Hume (1711–1776) and Adam Smith (1723–1790), challenged fundamental mercantilist doctrines—such as the belief that the world's wealth remained constant and that a state could only increase its wealth at the expense of another state.
During the Industrial Revolution, industrialists replaced merchants as a dominant factor in the capitalist system and effected the decline of the traditional handicraft skills of artisans, guilds and journeymen. Industrial capitalism marked the development of the factory system of manufacturing, characterized by a complex division of labor between and within work process and the routine of work tasks; and eventually established the domination of the capitalist mode of production.
Industrial Britain eventually abandoned the protectionist policy formerly prescribed by mercantilism. In the 19th century, Richard Cobden (1804–1865) and John Bright (1811–1889), who based their beliefs on the Manchester School, initiated a movement to lower tariffs. In the 1840s Britain adopted a less protectionist policy, with the 1846 repeal of the Corn Laws and the 1849 repeal of the Navigation Acts. Britain reduced tariffs and quotas, in line with David Ricardo's advocacy of free trade.
Modernity
Broader processes of globalization carried capitalism across the world. By the beginning of the nineteenth century, a series of loosely connected market systems had come together as a relatively integrated global system, in turn intensifying processes of economic and other globalization. Late in the 20th century, capitalism overcame a challenge by centrally-planned economies and is now the encompassing system worldwide, with the mixed economy as its dominant form in the industrialized Western world.
Industrialization allowed cheap production of household items using economies of scale, while rapid population growth created sustained demand for commodities. The imperialism of the 18th-century decisively shaped globalization.
After the First and Second Opium Wars (1839–60) by Britain and France and the completion of the British conquest of India by 1858 and the French conquest of Africa, Polynesia and Indochina by 1887, vast populations of Asia became consumers of European exports. Europeans colonized areas of Africa and the Pacific islands. Colonisation by Europeans, notably of Africa by the British and French, yielded valuable natural resources such as rubber, diamonds and coal and helped fuel trade and investment between the European imperial powers, their colonies and the United States:
The inhabitant of London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea, the various products of the whole earth, and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep. Militarism and imperialism of racial and cultural rivalries were little more than the amusements of his daily newspaper. What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man was that age which came to an end in August 1914.
From the 1870s to the early 1920s, the global financial system was mainly tied to the gold standard. The United Kingdom first formally adopted this standard in 1821. Soon to follow were Canada in 1853, Newfoundland in 1865, the United States and Germany (de jure) in 1873. New technologies, such as the telegraph, the transatlantic cable, the radiotelephone, the steamship and railways allowed goods and information to move around the world to an unprecedented degree.
In the United States, the term "capitalist" primarily referred to powerful businessmen until the 1920s due to widespread societal skepticism and criticism of capitalism and its most ardent supporters.
Contemporary capitalist societies developed in the West from 1950 to the present and this type of system continues throughout the world—relevant examples started in the United States after the 1950s, France after the 1960s, Spain after the 1970s, Poland after 2015, and others. At this stage most capitalist markets are considered developed and characterized by developed private and public markets for equity and debt, a high standard of living (as characterized by the World Bank and the IMF), large institutional investors and a well-funded banking system. A significant managerial class has emerged and decides on a significant proportion of investments and other decisions. A different future than that envisioned by Marx has started to emerge—explored and described by Anthony Crosland in the United Kingdom in his 1956 book The Future of Socialism and by John Kenneth Galbraith in North America in his 1958 book The Affluent Society, 90 years after Marx's research on the state of capitalism in 1867.
The postwar boom ended in the late 1960s and early 1970s and the economic situation grew worse with the rise of stagflation. Monetarism, a modification of Keynesianism that is more compatible with laissez-faire analyses, gained increasing prominence in the capitalist world, especially under the years in office of Ronald Reagan in the United States (1981–1989) and of Margaret Thatcher in the United Kingdom (1979–1990). Public and political interest began shifting away from the so-called collectivist concerns of Keynes's managed capitalism to a focus on individual choice, called "remarketized capitalism".
The end of the Cold War and the dissolution of the Soviet Union allowed for capitalism to become a truly global system in a way not seen since before World War I. The development of the neoliberal global economy would have been impossible without the fall of communism.
Harvard Kennedy School economist Dani Rodrik distinguishes between three historical variants of capitalism:
- Capitalism 1.0 during the 19th century entailed largely unregulated markets with a minimal role for the state (aside from national defense, and protecting property rights);
- Capitalism 2.0 during the post-World War II years entailed Keynesianism, a substantial role for the state in regulating markets, and strong welfare states;
- Capitalism 2.1 entailed a combination of unregulated markets, globalization, and various national obligations by states.
Relationship to democracy
The relationship between democracy and capitalism is a contentious area in theory and in popular political movements. The extension of adult-male suffrage in 19th-century Britain occurred along with the development of industrial capitalism and representative democracy became widespread at the same time as capitalism, leading capitalists to posit a causal or mutual relationship between them. However, according to some authors in the 20th-century, capitalism also accompanied a variety of political formations quite distinct from liberal democracies, including fascist regimes, absolute monarchies and single-party states. Democratic peace theory asserts that democracies seldom fight other democracies, but others suggest this may be because of political similarity or stability, rather than because they are "democratic" or "capitalist". Critics argue that though economic growth under capitalism has led to democracy, it may not do so in the future as authoritarian régimes have been able to manage economic growth using some of capitalism's competitive principles without making concessions to greater political freedom.
Political scientists Torben Iversen and David Soskice see democracy and capitalism as mutually supportive. Robert Dahl argued in On Democracy that capitalism was beneficial for democracy because economic growth and a large middle class were good for democracy. He also argued that a market economy provided a substitute for government control of the economy, which reduces the risks of tyranny and authoritarianism.
In his book The Road to Serfdom (1944), Friedrich Hayek (1899–1992) asserted that the free-market understanding of economic freedom as present in capitalism is a requisite of political freedom. He argued that the market mechanism is the only way of deciding what to produce and how to distribute the items without using coercion. Milton Friedman and Ronald Reagan also promoted this view. Friedman claimed that centralized economic operations are always accompanied by political repression. In his view, transactions in a market economy are voluntary and the wide diversity that voluntary activity permits is a fundamental threat to repressive political leaders and greatly diminishes their power to coerce. Some of Friedman's views were shared by John Maynard Keynes, who believed that capitalism was vital for freedom to survive and thrive. Freedom House, an American think-tank that conducts international research on, and advocates for, democracy, political freedom and human rights, has argued that "there is a high and statistically significant correlation between the level of political freedom as measured by Freedom House and economic freedom as measured by the Wall Street Journal/Heritage Foundation survey".
In Capital in the Twenty-First Century (2013), Thomas Piketty of the Paris School of Economics asserted that inequality is the inevitable consequence of economic growth in a capitalist economy and the resulting concentration of wealth can destabilize democratic societies and undermine the ideals of social justice upon which they are built.
States with capitalistic economic systems have thrived under political regimes deemed to be authoritarian or oppressive. Singapore has a successful open market economy as a result of its competitive, business-friendly climate and robust rule of law. Nonetheless, it often comes under fire for its style of government which, though democratic and consistently one of the least corrupt, operates largely under a one-party rule. Furthermore, it does not vigorously defend freedom of expression as evidenced by its government-regulated press, and its penchant for upholding laws protecting ethnic and religious harmony, judicial dignity and personal reputation. The private (capitalist) sector in the People's Republic of China has grown exponentially and thrived since its inception, despite having an authoritarian government. Augusto Pinochet's rule in Chile led to economic growth and high levels of inequality by using authoritarian means to create a safe environment for investment and capitalism. Similarly, Suharto's authoritarian reign and extirpation of the Communist Party of Indonesia allowed for the expansion of capitalism in Indonesia.
The term "capitalism" in its modern sense is often attributed to Karl Marx. In his Das Kapital, Marx analyzed the "capitalist mode of production" using a method of understanding today known as Marxism. However, Marx himself rarely used the term "capitalism" while it was used twice in the more political interpretations of his work, primarily authored by his collaborator Friedrich Engels. In the 20th century, defenders of the capitalist system often replaced the term "capitalism" with phrases such as free enterprise and private enterprise and replaced "capitalist" with rentier and investor in reaction to the negative connotations associated with capitalism.
Characteristics
Further information: Academic perspectives on capitalismIn general, capitalism as an economic system and mode of production can be summarized by the following:
- Capital accumulation: production for profit and accumulation as the implicit purpose of all or most of production, constriction or elimination of production formerly carried out on a common social or private household basis.
- Commodity production: production for exchange on a market; to maximize exchange-value instead of use-value.
- Exchange of goods or services, can be enabled by contracts. Exchange of services can be in form of wage labor.
- Private ownership of the means of production:
- The investment of money to make a profit.
- The use of the price mechanism to allocate resources between competing uses.
- Economically efficient use of the factors of production and raw materials due to maximization of value added in the production process.
- Freedom of capitalists to act in their self-interest in managing their business and investments.
- Capital suppliance by "the single owner of a firm, or by shareholders in the case of a joint-stock company."
Market
In free market and laissez-faire forms of capitalism, markets are used most extensively with minimal or no regulation over the pricing mechanism. In mixed economies, which are almost universal today, markets continue to play a dominant role, but they are regulated to some extent by the state in order to correct market failures, promote social welfare, conserve natural resources, fund defense and public safety or other rationale. In state capitalist systems, markets are relied upon the least, with the state relying heavily on state-owned enterprises or indirect economic planning to accumulate capital.
Competition arises when more than one producer is trying to sell the same or similar products to the same buyers. Adherents of the capitalist theory believe that competition leads to innovation and more affordable prices. Monopolies or cartels can develop, especially if there is no competition. A monopoly occurs when a firm has exclusivity over a market. Hence, the firm can engage in rent seeking behaviors such as limiting output and raising prices because it has no fear of competition.
Governments have implemented legislation for the purpose of preventing the creation of monopolies and cartels. In 1890, the Sherman Antitrust Act became the first legislation passed by the United States Congress to limit monopolies.
Wage labor
Main article: Wage laborWage labor, usually referred to as paid work, paid employment, or paid labor, refers to the socioeconomic relationship between a worker and an employer in which the worker sells their labor power under a formal or informal employment contract. These transactions usually occur in a labor market where wages or salaries are market-determined.
In exchange for the money paid as wages (usual for short-term work-contracts) or salaries (in permanent employment contracts), the work product generally becomes the undifferentiated property of the employer. A wage laborer is a person whose primary means of income is from the selling of their labor in this way.
Profit motive
Main article: Profit motiveThe profit motive, in the theory of capitalism, is the desire to earn income in the form of profit. Stated differently, the reason for a business's existence is to turn a profit. The profit motive functions according to rational choice theory, or the theory that individuals tend to pursue what is in their own best interests. Accordingly, businesses seek to benefit themselves and/or their shareholders by maximizing profit.
In capitalist theoretics, the profit motive is said to ensure that resources are being allocated efficiently. For instance, Austrian economist Henry Hazlitt explains: "If there is no profit in making an article, it is a sign that the labor and capital devoted to its production are misdirected: the value of the resources that must be used up in making the article is greater than the value of the article itself".
Socialist theorists note that, unlike mercantilists, capitalists accumulate their profits while expecting their profit rates to remain the same. This causes problems as earnings in the rest of society do not increase in the same proportion.
Private property
Main article: Private propertyThe relationship between the state, its formal mechanisms, and capitalist societies has been debated in many fields of social and political theory, with active discussion since the 19th century. Hernando de Soto is a contemporary Peruvian economist who has argued that an important characteristic of capitalism is the functioning state protection of property rights in a formal property system where ownership and transactions are clearly recorded.
According to de Soto, this is the process by which physical assets are transformed into capital, which in turn may be used in many more ways and much more efficiently in the market economy. A number of Marxian economists have argued that the inclosure acts in England and similar legislation elsewhere were an integral part of capitalist primitive accumulation and that specific legal frameworks of private land ownership have been integral to the development of capitalism.
Private property rights are not absolute, as in many countries the state has the power to seize private property, typically for public use, under the powers of eminent domain.
Market competition
Main article: Competition (economics)In capitalist economics, market competition is the rivalry among sellers trying to achieve such goals as increasing profits, market share and sales volume by varying the elements of the marketing mix: price, product, distribution and promotion. Merriam-Webster defines competition in business as "the effort of two or more parties acting independently to secure the business of a third party by offering the most favourable terms". It was described by Adam Smith in The Wealth of Nations (1776) and later economists as allocating productive resources to their most highly valued uses and encouraging efficiency. Smith and other classical economists before Antoine Augustine Cournot were referring to price and non-price rivalry among producers to sell their goods on best terms by bidding of buyers, not necessarily to a large number of sellers nor to a market in final equilibrium. Competition is widespread throughout the market process. It is a condition where "buyers tend to compete with other buyers, and sellers tend to compete with other sellers". In offering goods for exchange, buyers competitively bid to purchase specific quantities of specific goods which are available, or might be available if sellers were to choose to offer such goods. Similarly, sellers bid against other sellers in offering goods on the market, competing for the attention and exchange resources of buyers. Competition results from scarcity, as it is not possible to satisfy all conceivable human wants, and occurs as people try to meet the criteria being used to determine allocation.
In the works of Adam Smith, the idea of capitalism is made possible through competition which creates growth. Although capitalism had not entered mainstream economics at the time of Smith, it is vital to the construction of his ideal society. One of the foundational blocks of capitalism is competition. Smith believed that a prosperous society is one where "everyone should be free to enter and leave the market and change trades as often as he pleases." He believed that the freedom to act in one's self-interest is essential for the success of a capitalist society. In response to the idea that if all participants focus on their own goals, society's well-being will be water under the bridge, Smith maintains that despite the concerns of intellectuals, "global trends will hardly be altered if they refrain from pursuing their personal ends." He insisted that the actions of a few participants cannot alter the course of society. Instead, Smith maintained that they should focus on personal progress instead and that this will result in overall growth to the whole.
Competition between participants, "who are all endeavoring to justle one another out of employment, obliges every man to endeavor to execute his work" through competition towards growth.
Economic growth
Further information: Economic growthThis section needs expansion. You can help by adding to it. (January 2021) |
Economic growth is a characteristic tendency of capitalist economies. However, capitalist economies may experience fluctuations in growth that cannot be accounted for by demographic or technological changes. These fluctuations, which involve sustained periods of economic growth and recession, are referred to as business cycles in macroeconomics. Economic growth is measured as growth in investment, economic output, and economic consumption per capita. Changes in hours of employment on their own are not considered as a factor of economic growth.
As a mode of production
Further information: Mode of productionThe capitalist mode of production refers to the systems of organising production and distribution within capitalist societies. Private money-making in various forms (renting, banking, merchant trade, production for profit and so on) preceded the development of the capitalist mode of production as such.
The term capitalist mode of production is defined by private ownership of the means of production, extraction of surplus value by the owning class for the purpose of capital accumulation, wage-based labor and, at least as far as commodities are concerned, being market-based.
Capitalism in the form of money-making activity has existed in the shape of merchants and money-lenders who acted as intermediaries between consumers and producers engaging in simple commodity production (hence the reference to "merchant capitalism") since the beginnings of civilisation. What is specific about the "capitalist mode of production" is that most of the inputs and outputs of production are supplied through the market (i.e. they are commodities) and essentially all production is in this mode. By contrast, in flourishing feudalism most or all of the factors of production, including labor, are owned by the feudal ruling class outright and the products may also be consumed without a market of any kind, it is production for use within the feudal social unit and for limited trade. This has the important consequence that, under capitalism, the whole organisation of the production process is reshaped and re-organised to conform with economic rationality as bounded by capitalism, which is expressed in price relationships between inputs and outputs (wages, non-labor factor costs, sales and profits) rather than the larger rational context faced by society overall—that is, the whole process is organised and re-shaped in order to conform to "commercial logic". Essentially, capital accumulation comes to define economic rationality in capitalist production.
A society, region or nation is capitalist if the predominant source of incomes and products being distributed is capitalist activity, but even so this does not yet mean necessarily that the capitalist mode of production is dominant in that society.
Mixed economies rely on the nation they are in to provide some goods or services, while the free market produces and maintains the rest.
Role of government
Government agencies regulate the standards of service in many industries, such as airlines and broadcasting, as well as financing a wide range of programs. In addition, the government regulates the flow of capital and uses financial tools such as the interest rate to control such factors as inflation and unemployment.
Supply and demand
Main article: Supply and demandIn capitalist economic structures, supply and demand is an economic model of price determination in a market. It postulates that in a perfectly competitive market, the unit price for a particular good will vary until it settles at a point where the quantity demanded by consumers (at the current price) will equal the quantity supplied by producers (at the current price), resulting in an economic equilibrium for price and quantity.
The "basic laws" of supply and demand, as described by David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam, are the following four:
- If demand increases (demand curve shifts to the right) and supply remains unchanged, then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price.
- If demand decreases (demand curve shifts to the left) and supply remains unchanged, then a surplus occurs, leading to a lower equilibrium price.
- If demand remains unchanged and supply increases (supply curve shifts to the right), then a surplus occurs, leading to a lower equilibrium price.
- If demand remains unchanged and supply decreases (supply curve shifts to the left), then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price.
Supply schedule
A supply schedule is a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied.
Demand schedule
A demand schedule, depicted graphically as the demand curve, represents the amount of some goods that buyers are willing and able to purchase at various prices, assuming all determinants of demand other than the price of the good in question, such as income, tastes and preferences, the price of substitute goods and the price of complementary goods, remain the same. According to the law of demand, the demand curve is almost always represented as downward sloping, meaning that as price decreases, consumers will buy more of the good.
Just like the supply curves reflect marginal cost curves, demand curves are determined by marginal utility curves.
Equilibrium
Further information: Economic equilibriumIn the context of supply and demand, economic equilibrium refers to a state where economic forces such as supply and demand are balanced and in the absence of external influences the (equilibrium) values of economic variables will not change. For example, in the standard text-book model of perfect competition equilibrium occurs at the point at which quantity demanded and quantity supplied are equal. Market equilibrium, in this case, refers to a condition where a market price is established through competition such that the amount of goods or services sought by buyers is equal to the amount of goods or services produced by sellers. This price is often called the competitive price or market clearing price and will tend not to change unless demand or supply changes.
Partial equilibrium
Main article: Partial equilibriumPartial equilibrium, as the name suggests, takes into consideration only a part of the market to attain equilibrium. Jain proposes (attributed to George Stigler): "A partial equilibrium is one which is based on only a restricted range of data, a standard example is price of a single product, the prices of all other products being held fixed during the analysis".
History
According to Hamid S. Hosseini, the "power of supply and demand" was discussed to some extent by several early Muslim scholars, such as fourteenth century Mamluk scholar Ibn Taymiyyah, who wrote: "If desire for goods increases while its availability decreases, its price rises. On the other hand, if availability of the good increases and the desire for it decreases, the price comes down".
John Locke's 1691 work Some Considerations on the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money includes an early and clear description of supply and demand and their relationship. In this description, demand is rent: "The price of any commodity rises or falls by the proportion of the number of buyer and sellers" and "that which regulates the price... is nothing else but their quantity in proportion to their rent".
David Ricardo titled one chapter of his 1817 work Principles of Political Economy and Taxation "On the Influence of Demand and Supply on Price". In Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Ricardo more rigorously laid down the idea of the assumptions that were used to build his ideas of supply and demand.
In his 1870 essay "On the Graphical Representation of Supply and Demand", Fleeming Jenkin in the course of "introduc the diagrammatic method into the English economic literature" published the first drawing of supply and demand curves therein, including comparative statics from a shift of supply or demand and application to the labor market. The model was further developed and popularized by Alfred Marshall in the 1890 textbook Principles of Economics.
Types
This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (March 2020) (Learn how and when to remove this message) |
There are many variants of capitalism in existence that differ according to country and region. They vary in their institutional makeup and by their economic policies. The common features among all the different forms of capitalism are that they are predominantly based on the private ownership of the means of production and the production of goods and services for profit; the market-based allocation of resources; and the accumulation of capital.
They include advanced capitalism, corporate capitalism, finance capitalism, free-market capitalism, mercantilism, social capitalism, state capitalism and welfare capitalism. Other theoretical variants of capitalism include anarcho-capitalism, community capitalism, humanistic capitalism, neo-capitalism, state monopoly capitalism, and technocapitalism.
Advanced
Main article: Advanced capitalismAdvanced capitalism is the situation that pertains to a society in which the capitalist model has been integrated and developed deeply and extensively for a prolonged period. Various writers identify Antonio Gramsci as an influential early theorist of advanced capitalism, even if he did not use the term himself. In his writings, Gramsci sought to explain how capitalism had adapted to avoid the revolutionary overthrow that had seemed inevitable in the 19th century. At the heart of his explanation was the decline of raw coercion as a tool of class power, replaced by use of civil society institutions to manipulate public ideology in the capitalists' favour.
Jürgen Habermas has been a major contributor to the analysis of advanced-capitalistic societies. Habermas observed four general features that characterise advanced capitalism:
- Concentration of industrial activity in a few large firms.
- Constant reliance on the state to stabilise the economic system.
- A formally democratic government that legitimises the activities of the state and dissipates opposition to the system.
- The use of nominal wage increases to pacify the most restless segments of the work force.
Corporate
Main article: Corporate capitalism See also: Crony capitalism and State monopoly capitalismCorporate capitalism is a free or mixed-market capitalist economy characterized by the dominance of hierarchical, bureaucratic corporations.
Finance
Main article: Finance capitalism See also: Capitalist mode of production (Marxist theory)Finance capitalism is the subordination of processes of production to the accumulation of money profits in a financial system. In their critique of capitalism, Marxism and Leninism both emphasise the role of finance capital as the determining and ruling-class interest in capitalist society, particularly in the latter stages.
Rudolf Hilferding is credited with first bringing the term finance capitalism into prominence through Finance Capital, his 1910 study of the links between German trusts, banks and monopolies—a study subsumed by Vladimir Lenin into Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism (1917), his analysis of the imperialist relations of the great world powers. Lenin concluded that the banks at that time operated as "the chief nerve centres of the whole capitalist system of national economy". For the Comintern (founded in 1919), the phrase "dictatorship of finance capitalism" became a regular one.
Fernand Braudel would later point to two earlier periods when finance capitalism had emerged in human history—with the Genoese in the 16th century and with the Dutch in the 17th and 18th centuries—although at those points it developed from commercial capitalism. Giovanni Arrighi extended Braudel's analysis to suggest that a predominance of finance capitalism is a recurring, long-term phenomenon, whenever a previous phase of commercial/industrial capitalist expansion reaches a plateau.
Free market
Main article: Free-market capitalism See also: Laissez-faireThis section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. Find sources: "Capitalism" – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (December 2021) (Learn how and when to remove this message) |
A capitalist free-market economy is an economic system where prices for goods and services are set entirely by the forces of supply and demand and are expected, by its adherents, to reach their point of equilibrium without intervention by government policy. It typically entails support for highly competitive markets and private ownership of the means of production. Laissez-faire capitalism is a more extensive form of this free-market economy, but one in which the role of the state is limited to protecting property rights. In anarcho-capitalist theory, property rights are protected by private firms and market-generated law. According to anarcho-capitalists, this entails property rights without statutory law through market-generated tort, contract and property law, and self-sustaining private industry.
Fernand Braudel argued that free market exchange and capitalism are to some degree opposed; free market exchange involves transparent public transactions and a large number of equal competitors, while capitalism involves a small number of participants using their capital to control the market via private transactions, control of information, and limitation of competition.
Mercantile
Main article: Mercantilism See also: ProtectionismMercantilism is a nationalist form of early capitalism that came into existence approximately in the late 16th century. It is characterized by the intertwining of national business interests with state-interest and imperialism. Consequently, the state apparatus is used to advance national business interests abroad. An example of this is colonists living in America who were only allowed to trade with and purchase goods from their respective mother countries (e.g., United Kingdom, France and Portugal). Mercantilism was driven by the belief that the wealth of a nation is increased through a positive balance of trade with other nations—it corresponds to the phase of capitalist development sometimes called the primitive accumulation of capital.
Social
Main article: Social market economy See also: Nordic modelA social market economy is a free-market or mixed-market capitalist system, sometimes classified as a coordinated market economy, where government intervention in price formation is kept to a minimum, but the state provides significant services in areas such as social security, health care, unemployment benefits and the recognition of labor rights through national collective bargaining arrangements.
This model is prominent in Western and Northern European countries as well as Japan, albeit in slightly different configurations. The vast majority of enterprises are privately owned in this economic model.
Rhine capitalism is the contemporary model of capitalism and adaptation of the social market model that exists in continental Western Europe today.
State
Main article: State capitalismState capitalism is a capitalist market economy dominated by state-owned enterprises, where the state enterprises are organized as commercial, profit-seeking businesses. The designation has been used broadly throughout the 20th century to designate a number of different economic forms, ranging from state-ownership in market economies to the command economies of the former Eastern Bloc. According to Aldo Musacchio, a professor at Harvard Business School, state capitalism is a system in which governments, whether democratic or autocratic, exercise a widespread influence on the economy either through direct ownership or various subsidies. Musacchio notes a number of differences between today's state capitalism and its predecessors. In his opinion, gone are the days when governments appointed bureaucrats to run companies: the world's largest state-owned enterprises are now traded on the public markets and kept in good health by large institutional investors. Contemporary state capitalism is associated with the East Asian model of capitalism, dirigisme and the economy of Norway. Alternatively, Merriam-Webster defines state capitalism as "an economic system in which private capitalism is modified by a varying degree of government ownership and control".
In Socialism: Utopian and Scientific, Friedrich Engels argued that state-owned enterprises would characterize the final stage of capitalism, consisting of ownership and management of large-scale production and communication by the bourgeois state. In his writings, Vladimir Lenin characterized the economy of Soviet Russia as state capitalist, believing state capitalism to be an early step toward the development of socialism.
Some economists and left-wing academics including Richard D. Wolff and Noam Chomsky, as well as many Marxist philosophers and revolutionaries such as Raya Dunayevskaya and C.L.R. James, argue that the economies of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Bloc represented a form of state capitalism because their internal organization within enterprises and the system of wage labor remained intact.
The term is not used by Austrian School economists to describe state ownership of the means of production. The economist Ludwig von Mises argued that the designation of state capitalism was a new label for the old labels of state socialism and planned economy and differed only in non-essentials from these earlier designations.
Welfare
Main article: Welfare capitalism See also: Economic interventionism and Mixed economyWelfare capitalism is capitalism that includes social welfare policies. Today, welfare capitalism is most often associated with the models of capitalism found in Central Mainland and Northern Europe such as the Nordic model, social market economy and Rhine capitalism. In some cases, welfare capitalism exists within a mixed economy, but welfare states can and do exist independently of policies common to mixed economies such as state interventionism and extensive regulation.
A mixed economy is a largely market-based capitalist economy consisting of both private and public ownership of the means of production and economic interventionism through macroeconomic policies intended to correct market failures, reduce unemployment and keep inflation low. The degree of intervention in markets varies among different countries. Some mixed economies such as France under dirigisme also featured a degree of indirect economic planning over a largely capitalist-based economy.
Most modern capitalist economies are defined as mixed economies to some degree, however French economist Thomas Piketty state that capitalist economies might shift to a much more laissez-faire approach in the near future.
Eco-capitalism
Eco-capitalism, also known as "environmental capitalism" or (sometimes) "green capitalism", is the view that capital exists in nature as "natural capital" (ecosystems that have ecological yield) on which all wealth depends. Therefore, governments should use market-based policy-instruments (such as a carbon tax) to resolve environmental problems.
The term "Blue Greens" is often applied to those who espouse eco-capitalism. Eco-capitalism can be thought of as the right-wing equivalent to Red Greens.
Sustainable capitalism
Sustainable capitalism is a conceptual form of capitalism based upon sustainable practices that seek to preserve humanity and the planet, while reducing externalities and bearing a resemblance of capitalist economic policy. A capitalistic economy must expand to survive and find new markets to support this expansion. Capitalist systems are often destructive to the environment as well as certain individuals without access to proper representation. However, sustainability provides quite the opposite; it implies not only a continuation, but a replenishing of resources. Sustainability is often thought of to be related to environmentalism, and sustainable capitalism applies sustainable principles to economic governance and social aspects of capitalism as well.
The importance of sustainable capitalism has been more recently recognized, but the concept is not new. Changes to the current economic model would have heavy social environmental and economic implications and require the efforts of individuals, as well as compliance of local, state and federal governments. Controversy surrounds the concept as it requires an increase in sustainable practices and a marked decrease in current consumptive behaviors.
This is a concept of capitalism described in Al Gore and David Blood's manifesto for the Generation Investment Management to describe a long-term political, economic and social structure which would mitigate current threats to the planet and society. According to their manifesto, sustainable capitalism would integrate the environmental, social and governance (ESG) aspects into risk assessment in attempt to limit externalities. Most of the ideas they list are related to economic changes, and social aspects, but strikingly few are explicitly related to any environmental policy change.
Capital accumulation
Main article: Capital accumulationThe accumulation of capital is the process of "making money" or growing an initial sum of money through investment in production. Capitalism is based on the accumulation of capital, whereby financial capital is invested in order to make a profit and then reinvested into further production in a continuous process of accumulation. In Marxian economic theory, this dynamic is called the law of value. Capital accumulation forms the basis of capitalism, where economic activity is structured around the accumulation of capital, defined as investment in order to realize a financial profit. In this context, "capital" is defined as money or a financial asset invested for the purpose of making more money (whether in the form of profit, rent, interest, royalties, capital gain or some other kind of return).
In mainstream economics, accounting and Marxian economics, capital accumulation is often equated with investment of profit income or savings, especially in real capital goods. The concentration and centralisation of capital are two of the results of such accumulation. In modern macroeconomics and econometrics, the phrase "capital formation" is often used in preference to "accumulation", though the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) refers nowadays to "accumulation". The term "accumulation" is occasionally used in national accounts.
Wage labor
Main article: Wage labourWage labor refers to the sale of labor under a formal or informal employment contract to an employer. These transactions usually occur in a labor market where wages are market determined. In Marxist economics, these owners of the means of production and suppliers of capital are generally called capitalists. The description of the role of the capitalist has shifted, first referring to a useless intermediary between producers, then to an employer of producers, and finally to the owners of the means of production. Labor includes all physical and mental human resources, including entrepreneurial capacity and management skills, which are required to produce products and services. Production is the act of making goods or services by applying labor power.
Criticism
Main article: Criticism of capitalismCriticism of capitalism comes from various political and philosophical approaches, including anarchist, socialist, religious and nationalist viewpoints. Of those who oppose it or want to modify it, some believe that capitalism should be removed through revolution while others believe that it should be changed slowly through political reforms.
Prominent critiques of capitalism allege that it is inherently exploitative, alienating, unstable, unsustainable, and economically inefficient—and that it creates massive economic inequality, commodifies people, degrades the environment, is undemocratic, embeds uneven and underdevelopment between nation states, and leads to an erosion of human rights because of its incentivization of imperialist expansion and war.
Other critics argue that such inequities are not due to the ethic-neutral construct of the economic system commonly known as capitalism, but to the ethics of those who shape and execute the system. For example, some contend that Milton Friedman's (human) ethic of 'maximizing shareholder value' creates a harmful form of capitalism, while a Millard Fuller or John Bogle (human) ethic of 'enough' creates a sustainable form. Equitable ethics and unified ethical decision-making is theorized to create a less damaging form of capitalism.
Inheritance has been argued to not be a fundamental part of capitalism, instead part of nepotism.
See also
- Anti-capitalism
- Advanced capitalism
- Ancient economic thought
- Bailout Capitalism
- Capitalism (disambiguation)
- Christian views on poverty and wealth
- Communism
- Corporatocracy
- Crony capitalism
- Economic sociology
- Free market
- Global financial crisis in September 2008
- Humanistic economics
- Invisible hand
- Late capitalism
- Le Livre noir du capitalisme
- Market socialism
- Peak capitalism
- Perspectives on capitalism by school of thought
- Post-capitalism
- Post-Fordism
- Racial capitalism
- Rent-seeking
- Socialism
- State monopoly capitalism
- Surveillance capitalism
- Perestroika
References
- Notes
- Zimbalist, Andrew; Sherman, Howard J.; Brown, Stuart (October 1988). Comparing Economic Systems: A Political-Economic Approach. Harcourt College Publishing. pp. 6–7. ISBN 978-0-15-512403-5.
Pure capitalism is defined as a system wherein all of the means of production (physical capital) are privately owned and run by the capitalist class for a profit, while most other people are workers who work for a salary or wage (and who do not own the capital or the product).
- Rosser, Mariana V.; Rosser, J Barkley (23 July 2003). Comparative Economics in a Transforming World Economy. MIT Press. p. 7. ISBN 978-0-262-18234-8.
In capitalist economies, land and produced means of production (the capital stock) are owned by private individuals or groups of private individuals organized as firms.
- Jenks, Chris. Core Sociological Dichotomies. London; Thousand Oaks, CA; New Delhi: SAGE Publishing. p. 383.
Capitalism, as a mode of production, is an economic system of manufacture and exchange which is geared toward the production and sale of commodities within a market for profit, where the manufacture of commodities consists of the use of the formally free labor of workers in exchange for a wage to create commodities in which the manufacturer extracts surplus value from the labor of the workers in terms of the difference between the wages paid to the worker and the value of the commodity produced by him/her to generate that profit.
- Gilpin, Robert (2018). The Challenge of Global Capitalism : The World Economy in the 21st Century. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-18647-4. OCLC 1076397003.
- Sternberg, Elaine (2015). "Defining Capitalism". Economic Affairs. 35 (3): 380–396. doi:10.1111/ecaf.12141. ISSN 0265-0665. S2CID 219373247.
- Heilbroner, Robert L. (2018). "Capitalism". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 1378–1389. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_154. ISBN 978-1-349-95189-5.
- Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2015). Conceptualizing Capitalism: Institutions, Evolution, Future. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 9780226168142.
- ^ Harris, Neal; Delanty, Gerard (2023). "What is capitalism? Toward a working definition". Social Science Information. 62 (3): 323–344. doi:10.1177/05390184231203878.
- Berend, Ivan T. (2015). "Capitalism". International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences (Second Edition): 94–98. doi:10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.62003-2. ISBN 978-0-08-097087-5.
- Antonio, Robert J.; Bonanno, Alessandro (2012). "Capitalism". The Wiley-Blackwell Encyclopedia of Globalization. doi:10.1002/9780470670590.wbeog060. ISBN 978-1-4051-8824-1.
- Beamish, Rob (2018). "Capitalism". Core Concepts in Sociology. pp. 17–22. doi:10.1002/9781394260331.ch6. ISBN 978-1-119-16861-4.
- Gregory, Paul; Stuart, Robert (2013). The Global Economy and its Economic Systems. South-Western College Publishing. p. 41. ISBN 978-1-285-05535-0.
Capitalism is characterized by private ownership of the factors of production. Decision making is decentralized and rests with the owners of the factors of production. Their decision making is coordinated by the market, which provides the necessary information. Material incentives are used to motivate participants.
- Gregory, Paul; Stuart, Robert (2013). The Global Economy and its Economic Systems. South-Western College Publishing. p. 107. ISBN 978-1-285-05535-0.
Real-world capitalist systems are mixed, some having higher shares of public ownership than others. The mix changes when privatization or nationalization occurs. Privatization is when property that had been state-owned is transferred to private owners. Nationalization occurs when privately owned property becomes publicly owned.
- ^ Macmillan Dictionary of Modern Economics (3rd ed.). 1986. p. 54.
- Bronk, Richard (Summer 2000). "Which model of capitalism?". OECD Observer. Vol. 1999, no. 221–222. OECD. pp. 12–15. Archived from the original on 6 April 2018. Retrieved 6 April 2018.
- Stilwell, Frank (2002). Political Economy: the Contest of Economic Ideas (1st ed.). Melbourne, Australia: Oxford University Press.
- ^ Hodrick, R.; Prescott, E. (1997). "Postwar US business cycles: An empirical investigation" (PDF). Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 29 (1): 1–16. doi:10.2307/2953682. JSTOR 2953682. S2CID 154995815.
- ^ Braudel, Fernand (1979). The Wheels of Commerce: Civilization and Capitalism 15th–18th Century. Harper and Row.
- ^ James Augustus Henry Murray. "Capital". A New English Dictionary on Historical Principles. Oxford English Press. Vol. 2. p. 93.
- E.g., "L'Angleterre a-t-elle l'heureux privilège de n'avoir ni Agioteurs, ni Banquiers, ni Faiseurs de services, ni Capitalistes ?" in (1788) De la foi publique envers les créanciers de l'état : lettres à M. Linguet sur le n° CXVI de ses annales p. 19 Archived 19 March 2015 at the Wayback Machine
- Arthur Young. Travels in France.
- Ricardo, David. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. 1821. John Murray Publisher, 3rd edition.
- Samuel Taylor Coleridge. Tabel The Complete Works of Samuel Taylor Coleridge Archived 23 February 2020 at the Wayback Machine. p. 267.
- Saunders, Peter (1995). Capitalism. University of Minnesota Press. p. 1.
- ^ MEW, 23, & Das Kapital. Kritik der politischen Oekonomie. Erster Band-Verlag von Otto Meissner (1867)
- The use of the word "capitalism" appears in Theories of Surplus Value, volume II. ToSV was edited by Kautsky.
- Hessen, Robert (2008) "Capitalism", in Henderson, David R. (ed.) The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics p. 57
- Harcourt, Bernard E. (2020) For Coöperation and the Abolition of Capital, Or, How to Get Beyond Our Extractive Punitive Society and Achieve a Just Society, Rochester, NY: Columbia Public Law Research Paper No. 14-672, p. 31
- James Augustus Henry Murray. "Capitalism" p. 94.
- Mandel, Ernst (2002). An Introduction to Marxist Economic Theory. Resistance Books. p. 24. ISBN 978-1-876646-30-1. Archived from the original on 15 February 2017. Retrieved 29 January 2017.
- Werhane, P. H. (1994). "Adam Smith and His Legacy for Modern Capitalism". The Review of Metaphysics. 47 (3).
- ^ "Free enterprise". Roget's 21st Century Thesaurus (Third ed.). Philip Lief Group. 2008.
- ^ Capitalism. Encyclopædia Britannica. 10 November 2014. Archived from the original on 29 June 2011. Retrieved 24 March 2015.
- Barrons Dictionary of Finance and Investment Terms. 1995. p. 74.
- "Market economy". Merriam-Webster Unabridged Dictionary.
- Shutt, Harry (2010). Beyond the Profits System: Possibilities for the Post-Capitalist Era. Zed Books. ISBN 978-1-84813-417-1.
- ^ Wolf, Harald (2004). "Capitalism". In Ritzer, George (ed.). Encyclopedia of Social Theory. Sage Publications. pp. 76–80. ISBN 978-1-4522-6546-9.
- Howard, M.C.; King, J.E. (January 2001). "'State Capitalism' in the Soviet Union". History of Economics Review. 34 (1): 110–126. doi:10.1080/10370196.2001.11733360. ISSN 1037-0196. S2CID 42809979.
- ^ Delacroix, Jacques (2007). "Capitalism". In Ritzer, George (ed.). Encyclopedia of Social Theory. Wiley. doi:10.1002/9781405165518.wbeosc004. ISBN 978-1-4051-2433-1.
- Acemoglu, Daron (2017). "Capitalism". In Frey, Bruno S.; Iselin, David (eds.). Economic Ideas You Should Forget. Springer. pp. 1–3. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-47458-8_1. ISBN 978-3-319-47457-1.
- Behringer, Wolfgang (2011). "Core and Periphery: The Holy Roman Empire as a Communication(s) Universe". The Holy Roman Empire, 1495–1806 (PDF). Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 347–358. ISBN 978-0-19-960297-1. Archived (PDF) from the original on 9 October 2022. Retrieved 7 August 2022.
- "Cradle of capitalism". The Economist. 16 April 2009. Archived from the original on 18 January 2018. Retrieved 9 March 2015.
- Warburton, David (2003). Macroeconomics from the beginning: The General Theory, Ancient Markets, and the Rate of Interest. Paris: Recherches et Publications. p. 49.
- Koehler, Benedikt (2014). Early Islam and the Birth of Capitalism. Lexington Books. p. 2.
In Baghdad, by the early tenth century a fully-fledged banking sector had come into being...
- Brenner, Robert (1 January 1982). "The Agrarian Roots of European Capitalism". Past & Present (97): 16–113. doi:10.1093/past/97.1.16. JSTOR 650630.
- "The Agrarian Origins of Capitalism". July 1998. Archived from the original on 11 December 2019. Retrieved 17 December 2012.
- An Introduction to Marxist Economic Theory. Resistance Books. 2002. ISBN 978-1-876646-30-1. Archived from the original on 11 December 2016. Retrieved 27 August 2016 – via Google Books.
- ^ Burnham, Peter (2003). Capitalism: The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics. Oxford University Press.
- ^ Scott, John (2005). Industrialism: A Dictionary of Sociology. Oxford University Press.
- Encyclopædia Britannica (2006)
- Polanyi, Karl (1944). The Great Transformation. Boston: Beacon Press. p. 87.
- Onnekink, David; Rommelse, Gijs (2011). Ideology and Foreign Policy in Early Modern Europe (1650–1750). Ashgate Publishing. p. 257. ISBN 978-1-4094-1914-3. Archived from the original on 19 March 2015. Retrieved 27 June 2015.
- Quoted in Clark, George (1961). The Seventeenth Century. New York: Oxford University Press. p. 24.
- Om Prakash, "Empire, Mughal", History of World Trade Since 1450, edited by John J. McCusker, vol. 1, Macmillan Reference USA, 2006, pp. 237–240, World History in Context. Retrieved 3 August 2017
- Ray, Indrajit (2011). Bengal Industries and the British Industrial Revolution (1757–1857). Routledge. pp. 57, 90, 174. ISBN 978-1-136-82552-1. Archived from the original on 29 May 2016. Retrieved 20 June 2019.
- ^ Banaji, Jairus (2007). "Islam, the Mediterranean and the rise of capitalism" (PDF). Journal Historical Materialism. 15: 47–74. doi:10.1163/156920607X171591. Archived from the original (PDF) on 29 March 2018. Retrieved 20 April 2018.
- Economic system:: Market systems. Encyclopædia Britannica. 2006. Archived from the original on 24 May 2009. Retrieved 4 January 2009.
- Watt steam engine image located in the lobby of the Superior Technical School of Industrial Engineers of the UPM (Madrid).
- Hume, David (1752). Political Discourses. Edinburgh: A. Kincaid & A. Donaldson.
- Burnham, Peter (1996). "Capitalism". In McLean, Iain; McMillan, Alistair (eds.). The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics. Oxford Quick Reference (3 ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press (published 2009). ISBN 978-0-19-101827-5. Archived from the original on 27 July 2020. Retrieved 14 September 2019.
Industrial capitalism, which Marx dates from the last third of the eighteenth century, finally establishes the domination of the capitalist mode of production.
- "Laissez-faire". Archived from the original on 2 December 2008.
- Burnham, Peter (1996). "Capitalism". In McLean, Iain; McMillan, Alistair (eds.). The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics. Oxford Quick Reference (3 ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press (published 2009). ISBN 978-0-19-101827-5. Archived from the original on 27 July 2020. Retrieved 14 September 2019.
For most analysts, mid- to late-nineteenth century Britain is seen as the apotheosis of the laissez-faire phase of capitalism. This phase took off in Britain in the 1840s with the repeal of the Corn Laws, and the Navigation Acts, and the passing of the Banking Act.
- ^ James, Paul; Gills, Barry (2007). Globalization and Economy, Vol. 1: Global Markets and Capitalism. London: SAGE Publications. p. xxxiii.
- "Impact of Global Capitalism on the Environment of Developing Economies" (PDF). Impact of Global Capitalism on the Environment of Developing Economies: The Case of Nigeria: 84. Archived (PDF) from the original on 20 March 2020. Retrieved 31 July 2020.
- James, Fulcher (2004). Capitalism, A Very Short Introduction. Oxford University Press. p. 99. ISBN 978-0-19-280218-7.
In one respect there can, however, be little doubt that capitalism has gone global and that is in the elimination of alternative systems
- Thomas, Martin; Thompson, Andrew (1 January 2014). "Empire and Globalisation: from 'High Imperialism' to Decolonisation". The International History Review. 36 (1): 142–170. doi:10.1080/07075332.2013.828643. ISSN 0707-5332. S2CID 153987517.
- "Globalization and Empire" (PDF). Globalization and Empire. Archived (PDF) from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 31 July 2020.
- "Europe and the causes of globalization" (PDF). Europe and the Causes of Globalization, 1790 to 2000. Archived (PDF) from the original on 7 December 2017. Retrieved 31 July 2020.
- "Commanding Heights: Episode One: The Battle of Ideas". PBS. 24 October 1929. Archived from the original on 30 March 2010. Retrieved 31 July 2010.
- Eichengreen, Barry (6 August 2019). Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System (3rd ed.). Princeton University Press. doi:10.2307/j.ctvd58rxg. ISBN 978-0-691-19458-5. LCCN 2019018286. S2CID 240840930.
- Eichengreen, Barry; Esteves, Rui Pedro (2021). "International Finance". In Fukao, Kyoji; Broadberry, Stephen (eds.). The Cambridge Economic History of the Modern World. Vol. 2: 1870 to the Present. Cambridge University Press. pp. 501–525. ISBN 978-1-107-15948-8.
- Bordo, Michael D.; Eichengreen, Barry; Irwin, Douglas A. (June 1999). "Is Globalization Today Really Different than Globalization a Hundred Years Ago?". NBER. doi:10.3386/w7195.
- Andrews, Thomas G. (2008). Killing for Coal: America's Deadliest Labor War. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. p. 64. ISBN 978-0-674-03101-2.
- Crosland, Anthony (1956). The Future of Socialism. United Kingdom: Jonathan Cape.
- Galbraith, John Kenneth (1958). The Affluent Society. United States: Houghton Mifflin.
- Shiller, Robert (2012). Finance and The Good Society. United States: Princeton University Press.
- Barnes, Trevor J. (2004). Reading economic geography. Blackwell Publishing. p. 127. ISBN 978-0-631-23554-5.
- Fulcher, James (2004). Capitalism (1st ed.). New York: Oxford University Press.
- Gerstle, Gary (2022). The Rise and Fall of the Neoliberal Order: America and the World in the Free Market Era. Oxford University Press. pp. 10–12. ISBN 978-0-19-751964-6.
- Bartel, Fritz (2022). The Triumph of Broken Promises: The End of the Cold War and the Rise of Neoliberalism. Harvard University Press. pp. 5–6, 19. ISBN 978-0-674-97678-8.
- Rodrik, Dani (2009), Hemerijck, Anton; Knapen, Ben; van Doorne, Ellen (eds.), "Capitalism 3.0", Aftershocks, Amsterdam University Press, pp. 185–193, ISBN 978-90-8964-192-2, JSTOR j.ctt46mtqx.23, retrieved 14 January 2021
- Milner, Helen V (2021). "Is Global Capitalism Compatible with Democracy? Inequality, Insecurity, and Interdependence". International Studies Quarterly. 65 (4): 1097–1110. doi:10.1093/isq/sqab056.
- Epstein, Gady. "The Winners And Losers in Chinese Capitalism". Forbes. Archived from the original on 5 November 2015. Retrieved 28 October 2015.
- "The rise of state capitalism". The Economist. ISSN 0013-0613. Archived from the original on 15 June 2020. Retrieved 24 October 2015.
- Mesquita, Bruce Bueno de (September 2005). "Development and Democracy". Foreign Affairs. Archived from the original on 20 February 2008. Retrieved 26 February 2008.
- Siegle, Joseph; Weinstein, Michael; Halperin, Morton (1 September 2004). "Why Democracies Excel" (PDF). Foreign Affairs. 83 (5): 57. doi:10.2307/20034067. JSTOR 20034067. Archived (PDF) from the original on 12 April 2019. Retrieved 26 August 2018.
- Iversen, Torben; Soskice, David (2019). Democracy and Prosperity: Reinventing Capitalism through a Turbulent Century. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-18273-5. JSTOR j.ctv4g1r3n.
- ^ Dahl, Robert A. (2020). On Democracy. Yale University Press. ISBN 978-0-300-25799-1.
- Pryor, Frederic L. (2010). "Capitalism and freedom?". Economic Systems. 34 (1): 91–104. doi:10.1016/j.ecosys.2009.09.003.
- Hayek, Friedrich (1944). "The Road to Serfdom". Nature. 154 (3911). University of Chicago Press: 473–474. Bibcode:1944Natur.154..473C. doi:10.1038/154473a0. ISBN 978-0-226-32061-8. S2CID 4071358.
- Bellamy, Richard (2003). The Cambridge History of Twentieth-Century Political Thought. Cambridge University Press. p. 60. ISBN 978-0-521-56354-3.
- Karatnycky, Adrian (2001). Freedom in the World: The Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties. Transaction Publishers. p. 11. ISBN 978-0-7658-0101-2.
- Piketty, Thomas (2014). Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Belknap Press. p. 571. ISBN 978-0-674-43000-6.
- "Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015". Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015 – By Country / Territory. Transparency International. Archived from the original on 31 March 2016. Retrieved 20 September 2016.
- Klein, Naomi (2008). The Shock Doctrine: The Rise of Disaster Capitalism. Picador. ISBN 0-312-42799-9 p. 105 Archived 19 March 2015 at the Wayback Machine.
- Farid, Hilmar (2005). "Indonesia's original sin: mass killings and capitalist expansion, 1965–66". Inter-Asia Cultural Studies. 6 (1): 3–16. doi:10.1080/1462394042000326879. S2CID 145130614.
- Robinson, Geoffrey B. (2018). The Killing Season: A History of the Indonesian Massacres, 1965–66. Princeton University Press. p. 177. ISBN 978-1-4008-8886-3. Archived from the original on 19 April 2019. Retrieved 1 August 2018.
- ""capitalism, n.2". OED Online". Archived from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 19 January 2013.
- ^ Williams, Raymond (1983). "Capitalism". Keywords: A vocabulary of culture and society, revised edition. Oxford University Press. p. 51. ISBN 978-0-19-520469-8.
- "Althusser and the Renewal of Marxist Social Theory". Archived from the original on 2 April 2015. Retrieved 24 March 2015.
- ^ Marx, Karl. "Thirty Two". Economic Manuscripts: Capital Vol. I. Archived from the original on 21 February 2015. Retrieved 24 March 2015 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
- ^ "The contradictions of capitalism – Democratic Socialist Perspective". dsp.org.au. Archived from the original on 6 April 2015.
- Goldberg, Victor P. (21 November 2012). "Contracts". The Oxford Handbook of Capitalism. Oxford University Press. pp. 250–274. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780195391176.013.0010. ISBN 978-0-19-539117-6.
- ^ Steinfeld 2009, p. 3: "All labor contracts were/are designed legally to bind a worker in one way or another to fulfill the labor obligations the worker has undertaken. That is one of the principal purposes of labor contracts."
- James Fulcher, Capitalism A Very Short Introduction, "the investment of money in order to make a profit, the essential feature of capitalism", p. 14, Oxford, 2004, ISBN 978-0-19-280218-7.
- Reisman, George (1998). Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life. Jameson Books. ISBN 0-915463-73-3.
- Hunt, E.K.; Lautzenheiser, Mark (2014). History of Economic Thought: A Critical Perspective. PHI Learning. ISBN 978-0-7656-2599-1.
- Reisman, George (1998). Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life. Jameson Books. ISBN 978-0-915463-73-2.
- ^ Wright, Edmund, ed. (2006). The Desk Encyclopedia of World History. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 111–112. ISBN 978-0-7394-7809-7.
- James Fulcher, Capitalism A Very Short Introduction, "...in the wake of the 1970 crisis, the neoliberal model of capitalism became intellectually and ideologically dominant", p. 58, Oxford, 2004, ISBN 978-0-19-280218-7.
- "Monopoly". Investopedia. 24 November 2003. Archived from the original on 22 February 2017. Retrieved 2 March 2017.
- Deakin & Wilkinson 2005
- Editorial Board (2013). "W". Concise Dictionary of Economics. V&S Publishers. p. 278. ISBN 978-93-5057-032-6.
-
Compare:
Duska, Ronald F. (1997). "The Why's of Business Revisited". Contemporary Reflections on Business Ethics. Issues in Business Ethics. Vol. 23. Dordrecht: Springer Science & Business Media (published 2007). p. 41. ISBN 978-1-4020-4984-2. Retrieved 8 July 2019.
In microeconomics courses, profit maximization is frequently given as the goal of the firm. ... In microeconomics, profit maximization functions largely as a theoretical goal, with economists using it to prove how firms behave rationally to increase profit. Unfortunately, it ignores many real-world complexities.
- Hazlitt, Henry. "The Function of Profits". Economics in One Lesson. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. Web. 22 April 2013.
- "What is capitalism" Australian Socialist https://search.informit.org/doi/10.3316/informit.818838886883514
- Hernando de Soto. "The mystery of capital". Archived from the original on 8 February 2008. Retrieved 26 February 2008.
- Karl Marx. "Capital, v. 1. Part VIII: primitive accumulation". Archived from the original on 3 March 2008. Retrieved 26 February 2008.
- N.F.R. Crafts (April 1978). "Enclosure and labor supply revisited". Explorations in Economic History. 15 (2): 172–183. doi:10.1016/0014-4983(78)90019-0.
- "Definition of COMPETITION". Archived from the original on 4 July 2008. Retrieved 24 March 2015.
- Stigler, George J. (2008). "competition". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.). Archived from the original on 15 February 2015.
- Blaug, Mark (2008). "Invisible hand". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Vol. 4 (2nd ed.). p. 565. Archived from the original on 5 June 2013.
- ^ Heyne, Paul; Boettke, Peter J.; Prychitko, David L. (2014). The Economic Way of Thinking (13th ed.). Pearson. pp. 102–106. ISBN 978-0-13-299129-2.
- ^ Warsh, David (2007). Knowledge and the Wealth of Nations. W.W. Norton. p. 42.
- Lippit, Victor (2005). Capitalism. ProQuest: Taylor & Francis. p. 2.
- Joff, Michael (2011). "The root cause of economic growth under capitalism". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 35 (5): 873–896. doi:10.1093/cje/beq054.
The tendency for capitalist economies to grow is one of their most characteristic properties.
- Baumol, William J. (2004). The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 9780691116303.
- Encyclopedia of Marxism at marxism.org. "Capitalism". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 7 May 2019. Retrieved 8 July 2011.
- "Capitalism". Investopedia. Retrieved 14 February 2022.
- "Capitalism." World Book Encyclopedia. 1988. p. 194.
- Besanko, David; Braeutigam, Ronald (2010). Microeconomics (4th ed.). Wiley.
- "Supply". Boundless Economics. 13 June 2017. Retrieved 27 October 2021.
- Unlike most graphs, supply & demand curves are plotted with the independent variable (price) on the vertical axis and the dependent variable (quantity supplied or demanded) on the horizontal axis.
- "Marginal Utility and Demand". Archived from the original on 6 November 2006. Retrieved 9 February 2007.
- Varian, Hal R. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (Third ed.). New York: Norton. ISBN 978-0-393-95735-8.
- Jain, T.R. (2006). Microeconomics and Basic Mathematics. New Delhi: VK Publications. p. 28. ISBN 978-81-87140-89-4.
- Hosseini, Hamid S. (2003). "Contributions of Medieval Muslim Scholars to the History of Economics and their Impact: A Refutation of the Schumpeterian Great Gap". In Biddle, Jeff E.; Davis, Jon B.; Samuels, Warren J. (eds.). A Companion to the History of Economic Thought. Malden, Massachusetts: Blackwell. pp. 28–45 . doi:10.1002/9780470999059.ch3. ISBN 978-0-631-22573-7. (citing Hamid S. Hosseini, 1995. "Understanding the Market Mechanism Before Adam Smith: Economic Thought in Medieval Islam," History of Political Economy, Vol. 27, No. 3, 539–561).
- John Locke (1691) Some Considerations on the consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money Archived 24 March 2015 at the Wayback Machine
- ^ Thomas M. Humphrey, 1992. "Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses before Alfred Marshall", Economic Review, Mar/Apr, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, pp. 3–23 Archived 19 October 2012 at the Wayback Machine.
- A.D. Brownlie and M.F. Lloyd Prichard, 1963. "Professor Fleeming Jenkin, 1833–1885 Pioneer in Engineering and Political Economy", Oxford Economic Papers, 15(3), p. 211.
- Fleeming Jenkin, 1870. "The Graphical Representation of the Laws of Supply and Demand, and their Application to Labour", in Alexander Grant, ed., Recess Studies, Edinburgh. Ch. VI, pp. 151–185. Edinburgh. Scroll to chapter link Archived 16 July 2020 at the Wayback Machine.
- Hall, Peter A.; Soskice, David (20 September 2001). Varieties Of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford University Press, U.S.A. ISBN 0-19-924775-7.
- Lears, T.J. Jackson (1985) "The Concept of Cultural Hegemony"
- Holub, Renate (2005) Antonio Gramsci: Beyond Marxism and Postmodernism
- Boggs, Carl (2012) Ecology and Revolution: Global Crisis and the Political Challenge
- Habermas, 1988: 37, 75.
- Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism ibid. Finance Capital and the Finance Oligarchy Archived 2 April 2015 at the Wayback Machine
- Foster, John Bellamy; McChesney, Robert W. (1 October 2009). "Monopoly-Finance Capital and the Paradox of Accumulation". Monthly Review. Archived from the original on 28 August 2016. Retrieved 27 August 2016.
- Frederic Jameson, 'Culture and Finance Capital', in The Jameson Reader (2005) p. 257
- Quoted in E.H. Carr, The Bolshevik Revolution 2 (1971) p. 137
- Quoted in F.A Voight, Unto Caesar (1938) p. 22
- C. J.Calhoun/G. Derluguian, Business as Usual (2011) p. 57
- Jameson, pp. 259–260
- Braudel, F.; Ranum, P.M.; Ranum, P.P. (1977). Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism. Johns Hopkins symposia in comparative history. Johns Hopkins University Press. pp. 47–63. ISBN 978-0-8018-1901-8. Retrieved 6 April 2022.
- Musacchio, Aldo. "Economist Debates: State capitalism: Statements". The Economist. Archived from the original on 16 July 2012. Retrieved 20 June 2012.
- State capitalism Archived 3 July 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Merriam-Webster. Retrieved 7 July 2015.
- Engels, Frederick. "Socialism: Utopian and Scientific (Chpt. 3)". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 9 May 2020. Retrieved 8 January 2014.
- V.I. Lenin. The Tax in Kind Archived 7 September 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Lenin's Collected Works, 1st English ed., Progress Publishers, Moscow, 1965, vol. 32, pp. 329–365.
- V.I. Lenin. To the Russian Colony in North America Archived 18 June 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Lenin Collected Works, Progress Publishers, 1971, Moscow, vol. 42, pp. 425c–427a.
- "State capitalism" in the Soviet Union Archived 28 July 2019 at the Wayback Machine, M.C. Howard and J.E. King
- Noam Chomsky (1986). The Soviet Union Versus Socialism Archived 24 September 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Our Generation. Retrieved 9 July 2015.
- Richard D. Wolff (27 June 2015). Socialism Means Abolishing the Distinction Between Bosses and Employees Archived 11 March 2018 at the Wayback Machine. Truthout. Retrieved 9 July 2015.
- Dunayevskaya, Raya (1941). "The Union of Soviet Socialist Republics is a Capitalist Society". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 7 December 2019.
- James, C.L.R.; Dunayevskaya, Raya; Boggs, Grace Lee (1950). "State Capitalism and World Revolution" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 19 June 2020.
- Von Mises, Ludwig (1979). Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis. Indianapolis: LibertyClassics. ISBN 978-0-913966-63-1. Retrieved 31 May 2007.
The socialist movement takes great pains to circulate frequently new labels for its ideally constructed state. Each worn-out label is replaced by another which raises hopes of an ultimate solution of the insoluble basic problem of Socialism—until it becomes obvious that nothing has been changed but the name. The most recent slogan is 'State Capitalism.' It is not commonly realized that this covers nothing more than what used to be called Planned Economy and State Socialism, and that State Capitalism, Planned Economy, and State Socialism diverge only in non-essentials from the "classic" ideal of egalitarian Socialism.
- Piketty, Thomas (2013). "Repenser l'impôt progressif sur le revenu" [To rethink income tax progressivity]. Le capital au XXIe siècle (in French). Éditions du Seuil. pp. 799, 800. ISBN 978-2-02-108228-9.
Si cette régressivité fiscale au sommet de la hiérarchie sociale devait se confirmer et s'amplifier à l'avenir, il est bien évident qu'une telle sécession fiscale des plus riches est potentiellement extrêmement dommageable pour le consentement fiscal dans son ensemble s'en trouve amoindri . Il est vital pour l'État social moderne que le système fiscal qui le sous-tend conserve un minimum de progressivité.
[If tax regressivity on top of the social hierarchy may settle in and escalate in the future, it is obvious that such a tax secession between the richest and the other classes will be highly harmful towards the agreement over the taxation system which will weaken. It is essential for the modern social system that the taxation system preserve a sort of tax progressivity.] - Balch, Oliver (24 November 2019). "Green capitalism sometimes also referring to sustainable businesses". The Guardian.
- "Definition of Eco-Capitalism". collinsdictionary.com. Retrieved 27 November 2015.
- "The rise of green capitalism". roadtoparis.info. Retrieved 27 November 2015.
- Mitra, Basavadatta; Gadhok, Saagar; Salhotra, Shivam; Agarwal, Sakshi (2011). "The convergence of sustainable capitalism". 2011 IEEE International Professional Communication Conference. pp. 1–7. doi:10.1109/IPCC.2011.6087226. ISBN 978-1-61284-779-5. S2CID 31292223.
- Schweickart, David (1 January 2009). "Is Sustainable Capitalism an Oxymoron?". Perspectives on Global Development and Technology. 8 (2–3): 559–580. doi:10.1163/156914909X424033.
- E., Harrison, Neil (1 January 2013). Sustainable Capitalism and the Pursuit of Well-Being. Routledge. ISBN 978-1-306-21804-7. OCLC 866837827.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - ^ Gore, Al; Blood, David. "A Manifesto for Sustainable Capitalism" (PDF). Generation Foundation. Archived from the original (PDF) on 24 January 2014. Retrieved 24 October 2022.
- "Sustainable Capitalism" (PDF). Archived (PDF) from the original on 9 October 2022. Retrieved 18 February 2017.
- "Economics A–Z: Capital". The Economist. Archived from the original on 7 August 2017. Retrieved 25 March 2015.
- "Encyclopedia of Marxism – Glossary of terms: Capital". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 18 June 2015. Retrieved 25 March 2015.
- Deakin & Wilkinson 2005.
Marx 1990, p. 1005, defines wage labour succinctly as "the labour of the worker who sells his own labour-power." - Ragan, Christopher T.S.; Lipsey, Richard G. Microeconomics. 12th Canadian ed. Toronto, Pearson Education, 2008. ISBN 978-0-321-31491-8
- Robbins, Richard H. Global problems and the culture of capitalism. Boston: Allyn & Bacon, 2007. ISBN 978-0-205-52487-7
- Tormey, Simon (2004). Anticapitalism. One World Publications. p. 10. ISBN 978-1-78074-250-2.
- "16.1C: The Marxist Critique of Capitalism". Book: Sociology (Boundless). LibreTexts. 16 December 2020. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
Revolutionary socialists believe that capitalism can only be overcome through revolution. Social democrats believe that structural change can come slowly through political reforms to capitalism.
- Pons, Silvio; Smith, Stephen A., eds. (21 September 2017). The Cambridge History of Communism. Cambridge University Press. pp. 49–73. doi:10.1017/9781316137024. ISBN 978-1-316-13702-4.
- Engels, Frederick. "Competition – The Condition of the Working Class in England". Retrieved 10 March 2008.
- "Exploitation". Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. 20 December 2001. Archived from the original on 27 November 2020. Retrieved 26 December 2020.
- Mattei, Clara E. (2022). The Capital Order: How Economists Invented Austerity and Paved the Way to Fascism. University of Chicago Press. pp. 17–18. ISBN 978-0-226-81839-9.
- "Alienation." Pp. 10. in A Dictionary of Philosophy (rev. 2nd ed.). 1984.
- Engels, Frederick. "On the Question of Free Trade". Retrieved 11 March 2008.
- Easterling, Earl. "Marx's Theory of Economic Crisis". International Socialist Review. Archived from the original on 27 February 2021. Retrieved 13 March 2008.
- ^ Dawson, Ashley (2016). Extinction: A Radical History. OR Books. p. 41. ISBN 978-1-944869-01-4. Archived from the original on 17 September 2016. Retrieved 20 August 2016.
- Nelson, Anitra (31 January 2024). "Degrowth as a Concept and Practice : Introduction". The Commons Social Change Library. Retrieved 24 February 2024.
- Fletcher, Charles; Ripple, William J.; Newsome, Thomas; Barnard, Phoebe; Beamer, Kamanamaikalani; Behl, Aishwarya; Bowen, Jay; Cooney, Michael; Crist, Eileen; Field, Christopher; Hiser, Krista; Karl, David M.; King, David A.; Mann, Michael E.; McGregor, Davianna P.; Mora, Camilo; Oreskes, Naomi; Wilson, Michael (4 April 2024). "Earth at risk: An urgent call to end the age of destruction and forge a just and sustainable future". PNAS Nexus. 3 (4): pgae106. doi:10.1093/pnasnexus/pgae106. PMC 10986754. PMID 38566756. Retrieved 4 April 2024.
- Shutt, Harry (March 2010). Beyond the Profits System: Possibilities for a post-capitalist era. Zed Books. ISBN 978-1-84813-417-1.
- Rogers, Heather. "The Conquest of Garbage". isreview.org. International Socialist Review (1997). Archived from the original on 10 May 2021. Retrieved 13 March 2008.
- Rea, K.J. "Monopoly, Imperfect Competition, and Oligopoly". Archived from the original on 12 June 2010. Retrieved 11 March 2008.
- King, Matthew Wilburn (25 May 2021). "Why the next stage of capitalism is coming". BBC Future. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
- Ghodsee, Kristen; Orenstein, Mitchell A. (2021). Taking Stock of Shock: Social Consequences of the 1989 Revolutions. Oxford University Press. p. 192. doi:10.1093/oso/9780197549230.001.0001. ISBN 978-0-19-754924-7.
Without an accompanying welfare state in which social programs funded by a progressive income tax redistribute from the rich to the poor, capitalism can be a deeply unfair system where a small, well-connected elite captures a majority of the wealth and power, and not necessarily through meritocratic processes.
- Colin Leys (2 April 2021). "Commodification: the essence of our time". openDemocracy. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
- Daniel Margrain (25 August 2019). "The Commodification of Everything". Renegade Inc. Archived from the original on 21 October 2021. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
- Hickel, Jason (2021). Less is More: How Degrowth Will Save the World. Windmill Books. pp. 39–40. ISBN 978-1-78609-121-5.
It was only with the rise of capitalism over the past few hundred years, and the breathtaking acceleration of industrialization from the 1950s, that on a planetary scale things began to tip out of balance.
- Merkel, Wolfgang (26 July 2014). "Is capitalism compatible with democracy?". Zeitschrift für Vergleichende Politikwissenschaft. 8 (2). Springer Science and Business Media LLC: 109–128. doi:10.1007/s12286-014-0199-4. hdl:10419/270951. ISSN 1865-2646. S2CID 150776013.
- Reich, Robert B. (12 October 2009). "How Capitalism Is Killing Democracy". Foreign Policy. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
- Slobodian, Quinn (2023). Crack-Up Capitalism: Market Radicals and the Dream of a World Without Democracy. Metropolitan Books. p. 10. ISBN 978-1-250-75389-2.
- Patnaik, Utsa (1982). "'Neo-Marxian' Theories of Capitalism and Underdevelopment: Towards a Critique". Social Scientist. 10 (11): 3–32. doi:10.2307/3516858. ISSN 0970-0293. JSTOR 3516858.
- Warke, Thomas W. (1973). "The Marxian Theory of Underdevelopment: A Review Article". The Journal of Developing Areas. 7 (4): 699–710. ISSN 0022-037X.
- Martins, Carlos Eduardo (January 2022). "The Longue Durée of the Marxist Theory of Dependency and the Twenty-First Century". Latin American Perspectives. 49 (1): 18–35. doi:10.1177/0094582X211052029. ISSN 0094-582X.
- Peck, Jamie; Varadarajan, Latha (6 March 2017). "Uneven Regional Development". International Encyclopedia of Geography: People, the Earth, Environment and Technology. John Wiley & Sons, Ltd: 1–13. doi:10.1002/9781118786352.wbieg0721. ISBN 9780470659632.
- Abeles, Marc (2006). "Globalization, Power, and Survival: an Anthropological Perspective" (PDF). Anthropological Quarterly. 79 (3): 484–486. doi:10.1353/anq.2006.0030. S2CID 144220354. Archived (PDF) from the original on 9 October 2022.
- Farid, Hilmar (2005). "Indonesia's original sin: mass killings and capitalist expansion, 1965–66". Inter-Asia Cultural Studies. 6 (1): 3–16. doi:10.1080/1462394042000326879. S2CID 145130614.
- Blakeley, Ruth (2009). State Terrorism and Neoliberalism: The North in the South. Routledge. pp. 4, 20–23, 88. ISBN 978-0-415-68617-4.
- Lenin's Selected Works, Progress Publishers, 1963, Moscow, Volume 1, pp. 667–766
- Stout, Lynn (2012). The Shareholder Value Myth. San Francisco, CA: Berrett-Koehler Publishers, Inc. pp. 15–23. ISBN 978-1-60509-813-5.
- Gelles, David (2022). The Man Who Broke Capitalism. New York: Simon & Schuster. pp. 1–13. ISBN 978-1-9821-7644-0.
- Fuller, Millard (1994). The Theology of the Hammer. Macon, GA: Smyth & Helwys Publishing. pp. 31–39. ISBN 1-880837-92-7.
- Bogle, John (2009). Enough. Hoboken, New Jersey: John Wiley & Sons. pp. 229–248. ISBN 978-0-470-52423-7.
- Knowlton & Hedges (2021). Better Capitalism. Eugene, OR: Wipf & Stock Publishers. pp. 34–37, 235–242. ISBN 978-1-7252-8093-9.
- Haslett, D. W. (1986). "Is Inheritance Justified?". Philosophy & Public Affairs. 15 (2). Wiley: 122–155. ISSN 0048-3915. JSTOR 2265382. Retrieved 17 August 2024.
- Pérez-González, Francisco (1 November 2006). "Inherited Control and Firm Performance". American Economic Review. 96 (5): 1559–1588. doi:10.1257/aer.96.5.1559. ISSN 0002-8282.
- Bibliography
- Bacher, Christian (2007). Capitalism, Ethics and the Paradoxon of Self-Exploitation. Munich: GRIN Verlag. p. 2. ISBN 978-3-638-63658-2. Archived from the original on 1 November 2015. Retrieved 27 June 2015.
- Boldizzoni, Francesco (2020). Foretelling the End of Capitalism: Intellectual Misadventures since Karl Marx. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-91932-7.
- Carsel, Wilfred (1940). "The Slaveholders' Indictment of Northern Wage Slavery". Journal of Southern History. 6 (4): 504–520. doi:10.2307/2192167. JSTOR 2192167.
- Deakin, Simon; Wilkinson, Frank (2005). The Law of the Labour Market: Industrialization, Employment, and Legal Evolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-815281-1.
- De George, Richard T. (1986). Business Ethics. New York: Macmillan. p. 104. ISBN 978-0-02-328010-8.
- Elkins, Caroline (2005). Britain's Gulag: The Brutal End of Empire in Kenya. London: Jonathan Cape. ISBN 978-0-224-07363-9.
- Fitzhugh, George (1857). Cannibals All! or, Slaves Without Masters. Richmond, VA: A. Morris. ISBN 978-1-4290-1643-8. Archived from the original on 18 October 2015. Retrieved 27 June 2015.
- Fulcher, James (2004). Capitalism A Very Short Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-280218-7.
- Graeber, David (2004). Fragments of an Anarchist Anthropology. Prickly Paradigm Press. ISBN 978-0-9728196-4-0.
- Graeber, David (2007). Possibilities: Essays on Hierarchy, Rebellion and Desire. AK Press. ISBN 978-1-904859-66-6.
- Hallgrimsdottir, Helga Kristin; Benoit, Cecilia (2007). "From Wage Slaves to Wage Workers: Cultural Opportunity Structures and the Evolution of the Wage Demands of the Knights of Labor and the American Federation of Labor, 1880–1900". Social Forces. 85 (3): 1393–411. doi:10.1353/sof.2007.0037. JSTOR 4494978. S2CID 154551793.
- James, Paul; Gills, Barry (2007). Globalization and Economy, Vol. 1: Global Markets and Capitalism. London: SAGE Publications. Archived from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 17 May 2014.
- Krahn, Harvey J., and Graham S. Lowe (1993). Work, Industry, and Canadian Society. 2nd ed. Scarborough, Ont.: Nelson Canada. xii, 430 p. ISBN 0-17-603540-0
- Lash, Scott; Urry, John (2000). "Capitalism". In Abercrombie, Nicholas; Hill, Stephen; Turner, Bryan S (eds.). The Penguin Dictionary of Sociology (4th ed.). London: Penguin Books. pp. 36–40. ISBN 978-0-14-051380-6.
- McCraw, Thomas K. (August 2011). "The Current Crisis and the Essence of Capitalism". The Montreal Review. ISSN 0707-9656. Archived from the original on 8 September 2011. Retrieved 14 August 2011.
- Nelson, John O. (1995). "That a Worker's Labour Cannot Be a Commodity". Philosophy. 70 (272): 157–165. doi:10.1017/s0031819100065359. JSTOR 3751199. S2CID 171054136.
- Obrinsky, Mark (1983). Profit Theory and Capitalism. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press. p. 1. ISBN 978-0-8122-7863-7.
- Olusoga, David; Erichsen, Casper W. (2010). The Kaiser's Holocaust: Germany's Forgotten Genocide. London: Faber and Faber. ISBN 978-0-571-23141-6.
- Marx, Karl (1847). Wage Labour and Capital. Archived from the original on 6 September 2019. Retrieved 25 March 2015.
- Marx, Karl (1990) . Capital, Volume I. London: Penguin Classics. ISBN 978-0-14-044568-8.
- Roediger, David (2007a) . The Wages of Whiteness: Race and the Making of the American Working Class (revised and expanded ed.). London & New York: Verso. ISBN 978-1-84467-145-8.
- Roediger, David (2007b). "An Outmoded Approach to Labour and Slavery". Labour/Le Travail. 60: 245–250. JSTOR 25149808.
- Steinfeld, Robert (2009). "Coercion/Consent in Labor" (PDF). COMPAS Working Paper No. 66. Oxford: University of Oxford. Archived from the original (PDF) on 1 March 2014. Retrieved 3 March 2013.
{{cite journal}}
: Cite journal requires|journal=
(help) - Wolf, Eric R. (1982). Europe and the People Without History. Berkeley: University of California Press. ISBN 978-0-520-04459-3.
- Wood, Ellen Meiksins (2002). The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View. London: Verso. ISBN 978-1-85984-392-5. Archived from the original on 28 November 2015. Retrieved 27 June 2015.
- Young, John (1997). Peasant Revolution in Ethiopia: The Tigray People's Liberation Front, 1975–1991. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-02606-2.
Further reading
- Alperovitz, Gar (2011). America Beyond Capitalism: Reclaiming Our Wealth, Our Liberty, and Our Democracy, 2nd Edition. Democracy Collaborative Press. ISBN 0-9847857-0-1.
- Altvater, Elmar; Crist, Eileen; Haraway, Donna; Hartley, Daniel; Parenti, Christian; McBrien, Justin; Moore, Jason (2016). Anthropocene or Capitalocene? Nature, History, and the Crisis of Capitalism. PM Press. ISBN 978-1-62963-148-6.
- Ascher, Ivan. Portfolio Society: On the Capitalist Mode of Prediction. Zone Books, 2016. ISBN 978-1935408741
- Baptist, Edward E. The Half Has Never Been Told: Slavery and the Making of American Capitalism. New York, Basic Books, 2014. ISBN 0-465-00296-X.
- Barbrook, Richard (2006). The Class of the New (paperback ed.). London: OpenMute. ISBN 978-0-9550664-7-4. Archived from the original on 1 August 2018. Retrieved 11 June 2019.
- Block, Fred; Somers, Margaret R. (2014). The Power of Market Fundamentalism: Karl Polyani's Critique. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-05071-6.
- Boldizzoni, Francesco (2020). Foretelling the End of Capitalism: Intellectual Misadventures since Karl Marx. Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-91932-7.
- Braudel, Fernand. Civilization and Capitalism, 15th-18th Century, 3 volumes.
- Callinicos, Alex. "Wage Labour and State Capitalism – A reply to Peter Binns and Mike Haynes", International Socialism, 2nd series, 12, Spring 1979.
- Case, Anne; Deaton, Angus (2020). Deaths of Despair and the Future of Capitalism. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-19078-5. Archived from the original on 7 March 2020. Retrieved 6 March 2020.
- Farl, Erich. "The Genealogy of State Capitalism". In: International London, vol. 2, no. 1, 1973.
- Fisher, Mark (2009). Capitalist Realism: Is There No Alternative?. John Hunt Publishing. ISBN 978-1-84694-317-1.
- Gough, Ian. State Expenditure in Advanced Capitalism Archived 7 February 2012 at the Wayback Machine New Left Review.
- Habermas, J. Legitimation Crisis (eng. translation by T. McCarthy). Boston, Beacon. From Google books Archived 20 November 2015 at the Wayback Machine; excerpt.
- Harvey, David (2014). Seventeen Contradictions and the End of Capitalism. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-936026-0.
- Hyman, Louis and Edward E. Baptist (2014). American Capitalism: A Reader. Simon & Schuster. ISBN 978-1-4767-8431-1.
- Ingham, Geoffrey (2008). Capitalism: With a New Postscript on the Financial Crisis and Its Aftermath. Cambridge: Polity Press. ISBN 9780745636481.
- James, Paul; Patomäki, Heikki (2007). Globalization and Economy, Vol. 2: Global Finance and the New Global Economy. London: SAGE Publications. Archived from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 28 January 2018.
- James, Paul; Palen, Ronen (2007). Globalization and Economy, Vol. 3: Global Economic Regimes and Institutions. London: Sage Publications. Archived from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 28 January 2018.
- James, Paul; O'Brien, Robert (2007). Globalization and Economy, Vol. 4: Globalizing Labour. London: Sage Publications. Archived from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 28 January 2018.
- Jameson, Fredric (1991). Postmodernism, or, the Cultural Logic of Late Capitalism.
- Kocka, Jürgen (2016). Capitalism: A Short History. Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0691165226.
- Kotler, Philip (2015). Confronting Capitalism: Real Solutions for a Troubled Economic System. AMACOM. ISBN 978-0814436455
- Mandel, Ernest (1999). Late Capitalism. ISBN 978-1859842027
- Mander, Jerry (2012). The Capitalism Papers: Fatal Flaws of an Obsolete System. Counterpoint. ISBN 978-1-61902-158-7.
- Marcel van der Linden, Western Marxism and the Soviet Union. New York, Brill Publishers, 2007.
- Mayfield, Anthony. "Economics", in his On the Brink: Resource Depletion, Debt Collapse, and Super-technology (: On the Brink Publishing, 2013), pp. 50–104.
- Musacchio, Aldo; Lazzarini, Sergio G. (2014). Reinventing State Capitalism: Leviathan in Business, Brazil and Beyond. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-72968-1.
- Newitz, Annalee (2006). Pretend We're Dead: Capitalist Monsters in American Pop Culture. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. ISBN 978-0-8223-3745-4. Archived from the original on 26 October 2016. Retrieved 26 October 2016.
- Nitzan, Jonathan; Bichler, Shimshon (2009). Capital as Power: A Study of Order and Creorder. Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-49680-3.
- Panitch, Leo, and Sam Gindin (2012). The Making of Global Capitalism: the Political Economy of American Empire. London, Verso. ISBN 978-1-84467-742-9.
- Piketty, Thomas (2014). Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press. ISBN 978-0-674-43000-6.
- Piketty, Thomas (2020). Capital and Ideology. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press. ISBN 978-0-674-98082-2.
- Polanyi, Karl (2001). The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time. Beacon Press; 2nd ed. ISBN 0-8070-5643-X
- Reisman, George (1998). Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life. Jameson Books. ISBN 978-0-915463-73-2.
- Richards, Jay W. (2009). Money, Greed, and God: Why Capitalism is the Solution and Not the Problem. New York: HarperOne. ISBN 978-0-06-137561-3
- Roberts, Paul Craig (2013). The Failure of Laissez-faire Capitalism: towards a New Economics for a Full World. Atlanta, Ga.: Clarity Press. ISBN 978-0-9860362-5-5
- Robinson, William I. Global Capitalism and the Crisis of Humanity. Cambridge University Press, 2014. ISBN 1-107-69111-7
- Schram, Sanford F. (2015). The Return of Ordinary Capitalism: Neoliberalism, Precarity, Occupy. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-025302-8. Archived from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 12 February 2017.
- Hoevet, Ocean. "Capital as a Social Relation" (New Palgrave article)
- Sombart, Werner (1916) Der moderne Kapitalismus. Historisch-systematische Darstellung des gesamteuropäischen Wirtschaftslebens von seinen Anfängen bis zur Gegenwart. Final edn. 1916, repr. 1969, paperback edn. (3 vols. in 6): 1987 Munich: dtv. (Also in Spanish; no English translation yet.)
- Sonenscher, Michael (2022). Capitalism: The Story behind the Word. Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 9780691237206.
- Tarnoff, Ben, "Better, Faster, Stronger" (review of John Tinnell, The Philosopher of Palo Alto: Mark Weisner, Xerox PARC, and the Original Internet of Things, University of Chicago Press, 347 pp.; and Malcolm Harris, Palo Alto: A History of California, Capitalism, and the World, Little, Brown, 708 pp.), The New York Review of Books, vol. LXX, no. 14 (21 September 2023), pp. 38–40. " a place where the contradictions are sharpened to their finest points, above all the defining and enduring contradictions between democratic principle and antidemocratic practice. There is nothing as American as celebrating equality while subverting it. Or as Californian." (p. 40.)
- Wallerstein, Immanuel (1983). Historical Capitalism. Verso Books. ISBN 978-0-86091-761-8.
- Wolff, Richard D. (2012). Democracy at Work: A Cure for Capitalism. Haymarket Books. ISBN 978-1-60846-247-6.
- Wood, Ellen Meiksins (2002). The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View. Verso. ISBN 978-1-85984-392-5.
External links
- Capitalism on In Our Time at the BBC
- Capitalism at Encyclopædia Britannica Online.
- Selected Titles on Capitalism and Its Discontents Archived 23 January 2018 at the Wayback Machine. Harvard University Press.
Capitalism
Portals: Categories: