Revision as of 06:45, 2 January 2006 editRJII (talk | contribs)25,810 edits most call it economic fascism← Previous edit | Revision as of 06:46, 2 January 2006 edit undoRose Garden (talk | contribs)1,220 edits Rv. See talk for reasons for reversion. Read carefully and please talk rather than revert.Next edit → | ||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{TotallyDisputed}} | {{TotallyDisputed}} | ||
{{fascism}} | {{fascism}} | ||
The '''economics of fascism''' is the set of economic practices and characteristics common to ] regimes in the 1920s and 1930s, with the most often cited characteristic being the presence of private or quasi-private ownership of the means of production that was ''heavily'' coordinated by government. |
The '''economics of fascism''' is the set of economic practices and characteristics common to ] regimes in the 1920s and 1930s, with the most often cited characteristic being the presence of private or quasi-private ownership of the means of production that was ''heavily'' coordinated by government. Some theorists call the economics of fascism "economic fascism". | ||
==The economics of fascism as a "third way"== | ==The economics of fascism as a "third way"== | ||
Line 14: | Line 14: | ||
==Features of other economies thought to be similar to those in fascist Italy and Germany== | ==Features of other economies thought to be similar to those in fascist Italy and Germany== | ||
Economic fascism was practiced in ] under ] and ] under ]. Some argue that economic fascism was attempted in the U.S. under Franklin Roosevelt with the implentation of the ]. | |||
] said, in 1976, "Fascism was really the basis for the ]. It was Mussolini's success in Italy, with his government-directed economy, that led the early New Dealers to say 'But Mussolini keeps the trains running on time.'" Richard Ebeling argues that the U.S. Supreme Court stopped economic fascism from being implemented in the U.S. when it struck down significant parts of the New Deal, such as the NRA and AAA, as being ]. {{ref|Ebeling||}} The Supreme Court declared the NRA to be unconstitutional by a unanimous decision, stating that "a statutory plan to regulate and control agricultural production, a matter beyond the powers delegated to the federal government..." The AAA was struck down on the grounds that its codes were an illegal delegation of legislative authority to the executive branch and an excessive use of the ]. | ] said, in 1976, "Fascism was really the basis for the ]. It was Mussolini's success in Italy, with his government-directed economy, that led the early New Dealers to say 'But Mussolini keeps the trains running on time.'" Richard Ebeling argues that the U.S. Supreme Court stopped economic fascism from being implemented in the U.S. when it struck down significant parts of the New Deal, such as the NRA and AAA, as being ]. {{ref|Ebeling||}} The Supreme Court declared the NRA to be unconstitutional by a unanimous decision, stating that "a statutory plan to regulate and control agricultural production, a matter beyond the powers delegated to the federal government..." The AAA was struck down on the grounds that its codes were an illegal delegation of legislative authority to the executive branch and an excessive use of the ]. | ||
Revision as of 06:46, 2 January 2006
The economics of fascism is the set of economic practices and characteristics common to fascist regimes in the 1920s and 1930s, with the most often cited characteristic being the presence of private or quasi-private ownership of the means of production that was heavily coordinated by government. Some theorists call the economics of fascism "economic fascism".
The economics of fascism as a "third way"
A fascist economy differs from capitalism, in which the means of production are largely privately owned and mostly privately controlled in a mainly free market. It also differs from socialism, in which in theory the means of production should be owned by the state.
A common view on private property in a fascist economy is, as Thomas R. Eddlem puts it, " simply heavy government regulation and control of what is only nominally private property." Some scholars, however, dispute the extent of this regulation. Christoph Buchheim and Jonas Scherner argue that the view that private property in the Nazi economy existed in name only is incorrect. They say that while there was substantial central planning of private industry, the severity of the restrictions did not arise to the level of rendering private property a mere formality. Buchheim and Scherner describe the system as a "state-directed private ownership economy." Michael Coren, in writing of distributivism, an economic theory that underlay the support by some for a fascist economy in the 1930s, said that "economic fascism both capitalism and socialism." There, the some refer to fascist economic systems as a 'third way' whose proponents advocated them as a solution to avoid the perceived inegalitarian dangers of too strong of an enforcement of private property rights while at the same time avoiding the total abolition of private ownership of the means of production. Mussolini referred to his economic system as a "third way," noting it to be distinct from both socialism and capitalism.
However, while a signifant amount of control over private property is a core characteristic of the facscist economies, some others note additional aspects they believe to be essential. For example, author and journalist John T. Flynn, in 1944 noted three elements: "1) The institution of planned consumption of the spending-borrowing government. 2) The planned economy 3) Militarism as an economic institution" . However, Lawrence Dennis, in his 1936 book The Coming American Fascism promotes what he called a non-militaristic "fascist" economic system for the U.S.; he argues that in the absence of war that laissez-faire cannot satisfy the needs of the masses.
Government and business collusion
Geatano Salvemini said in 1936: "In actual fact, it is the State, i.e., the taxpayer who has become responsible to private enterprise. In Fascist Italy the State pays for the blunders of private enterprise... Profit is private and individual. Loss is public and social." Likewise, Jutta Schmitt, a lecturer in Political Science at the University de Los Andes in Venezuela says that "profit production depends on a considerable degree on State-guaranteed profit and the growing interaction and 'melting' of economic monopolies with their political representation in the State apparatus" and that "the main objective of economic fascism is the elevation of the profit rate in times of economic recession to the detriment of the working class." Schmitt, a socialist, notes that the economy in fascism has been referred to as "planned capitalism." Anthony Gregory, says that economic fascism is designed for government and business's "mutual benefit: profits for the corporate interests, expanded tax revenue, and augmented central planning powers for the state."
Features of other economies thought to be similar to those in fascist Italy and Germany
Ronald Reagan said, in 1976, "Fascism was really the basis for the New Deal. It was Mussolini's success in Italy, with his government-directed economy, that led the early New Dealers to say 'But Mussolini keeps the trains running on time.'" Richard Ebeling argues that the U.S. Supreme Court stopped economic fascism from being implemented in the U.S. when it struck down significant parts of the New Deal, such as the NRA and AAA, as being unconstitutional. The Supreme Court declared the NRA to be unconstitutional by a unanimous decision, stating that "a statutory plan to regulate and control agricultural production, a matter beyond the powers delegated to the federal government..." The AAA was struck down on the grounds that its codes were an illegal delegation of legislative authority to the executive branch and an excessive use of the Commerce Clause of the U.S Constitution.
References
- Eddlem, Thomas R. Introduction. And Not a Shot is Fired by Jan Kozak, Appleton, WI: Robert Welch University Press, 1999.
- Buchheim, Christoph and Scherner, Jonas. The Role of Private Property in the Nazi Economy: The Case of Industry University of Mannheim, Germany
- Coren, Michael Gilbert: The Man Who Was G.K. Chesterton Reed Business Information, Inc, 1990.
- Richman, Sheldon Fascism Concise Encyclopedia of Economics 1993, 2002.
- Flynn, John T. As We Go Marching 1944.
- Dennis, Larence. The Coming American Fascism 1936.
- Slavemini, Geatano. Under the Axe of Fascism 1936.
- Anthony, Gregory Why the Supreme Court Should Have Just Shut Up 2005.
- Ebeling, Richard M. When the Supreme Court Stopped Economic Fascism in America
Footnotes
1. Capitalism is defined by the Merriam-Webster Dictionary (unabridged) as "an economic system characterized by private or corporation ownership of capital goods, by investments that are determined by private decision rather than by state control, and by prices, production, and the distribution of goods that are determined mainly in a free market."
2. Socialism is defined by the Merriam-Webster Dictionary (unabridged) as "any of various theories or social and political movements advocating or aiming at collective or governmental ownership and administration of the means of production and control of the distribution of goods."
See also
External links
- The Role of Private Property in the Nazi Economy: The Case of Industry (pdf) by Christoph Buchheim and Jonas Scherner
- Economic Fascism by Thomas DiLorenzo
- When the Supreme Court Stopped Economic Fascism in America by Richard M. Ebeling
- Fascism by Sheldon Richman - discusses economic fascism
- The Coming American Fascism by Lawrence Dennis - advocates a non-militaristic economic fascism for the U.S. for the benefit of the working class
- The ‘Political Economy of Fascism’: Myth or Reality: or Myth and Reality? by David Baker
- Audio and Video files from various theorists recorded from the Economics of Fascism conference at the Ludwig von Mises Institute Oct 7-8, 2005