Revision as of 17:47, 20 August 2022 editFresheneesz (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users9,055 edits Correcting incorrect statement about clay tokens being used as representative money. The source given only says "probably" and does not have a supporting source or supporting evidence given. I gave a source directly contradicting that.← Previous edit | Latest revision as of 13:50, 11 November 2024 edit undoWk4arnaud (talk | contribs)9 edits Coins can be representative money if they intrinsic value is much less than their face value. Coins are not "printed" as in paper notes, but forged or minted. | ||
(4 intermediate revisions by 4 users not shown) | |||
Line 2: | Line 2: | ||
] | ] | ||
'''Representative money''' or '''receipt money''' is any ], |
'''Representative money''' or '''receipt money''' is any ], physical or digital, that represents something of ], but has little or no value of its own (]). Unlike some forms of ] (which may have no ] backing), genuine representative money must have something of intrinsic value supporting the ].<ref name=mundell/> | ||
More specifically, the term ''representative money'' has been used variously to mean: | More specifically, the term ''representative money'' has been used variously to mean: | ||
* A claim on a commodity, for example ] and ].<ref name="mundell">Robert A. Mundell, , Discussion Paper #:0102-08, Department of Economics, ], February 2002.</ref><ref>Jon Hooks, ''Economics:fundamentals for financial services providers'', {{ISBN|0-89982-494-3}}, {{ISBN|978-0-89982-494-9}} Retrieved September 9, 2009</ref><ref name="p.30">William Howard Steiner, ''Money and banking'', , H. Holt and company, 1941.</ref> In this sense it may be called "]". | * A claim on a commodity, for example ] and ]s.<ref name="mundell">Robert A. Mundell, , Discussion Paper #:0102-08, Department of Economics, ], February 2002.</ref><ref>Jon Hooks, ''Economics:fundamentals for financial services providers'', {{ISBN|0-89982-494-3}}, {{ISBN|978-0-89982-494-9}} Retrieved September 9, 2009</ref><ref name="p.30">William Howard Steiner, ''Money and banking'', , H. Holt and company, 1941.</ref> In this sense it may be called "]". | ||
* Any type of ] that has face value greater than its value as material substance. Used in this sense, most types of ] are a type of representative money.<ref>{{cite book | * Any type of ] that has face value greater than its value as material substance. Used in this sense, most types of ] are a type of representative money.<ref>{{cite book | ||
|title=A Treatise on Money | |title=A Treatise on Money | ||
Line 17: | Line 17: | ||
|publisher=Macmillan & Co Ltd}}</ref> | |publisher=Macmillan & Co Ltd}}</ref> | ||
There is no concrete evidence that the clay tokens used as an accounting tool to keep track of warehouse stores in ancient Mesopotamia were also used as representative money |
There is no concrete evidence that the clay tokens used as an accounting tool to keep track of warehouse stores in ancient Mesopotamia were also used as representative money. | ||
<ref name="Schmandt-Besserat">, </ref><ref>Keynes, J.M. (1930). ''A Treatise on Money''. Volume I, p. 13 | <ref name="Schmandt-Besserat">, </ref><ref>Keynes, J.M. (1930). ''A Treatise on Money''. Volume I, p. 13</ref> However, the idea has been suggested.<ref name=mundell/> | ||
</ref> | |||
however the idea has been suggested.<ref name=mundell/> | |||
In 1895 economist ] wrote that credit expansion and contraction was in fact the expansion and contraction of representative money.<ref>], ''A treatise on money and essays on monetary problems''], Chapter VI, Effects of Credit or "Representative Money" on prices, , A. and C. Black, 1895.</ref> | In 1895 economist ] wrote that credit expansion and contraction was in fact the expansion and contraction of representative money.<ref>], ''A treatise on money and essays on monetary problems''], Chapter VI, Effects of Credit or "Representative Money" on prices, , A. and C. Black, 1895.</ref> |
Latest revision as of 13:50, 11 November 2024
Any type of money that has face value greater than its value as material substanceRepresentative money or receipt money is any medium of exchange, physical or digital, that represents something of value, but has little or no value of its own (intrinsic value). Unlike some forms of fiat money (which may have no commodity backing), genuine representative money must have something of intrinsic value supporting the face value.
More specifically, the term representative money has been used variously to mean:
- A claim on a commodity, for example gold and silver certificates. In this sense it may be called "commodity-backed money".
- Any type of money that has face value greater than its value as material substance. Used in this sense, most types of fiat money are a type of representative money.
There is no concrete evidence that the clay tokens used as an accounting tool to keep track of warehouse stores in ancient Mesopotamia were also used as representative money. However, the idea has been suggested.
In 1895 economist Joseph Shield Nicholson wrote that credit expansion and contraction was in fact the expansion and contraction of representative money.
In 1934 economist William Howard Steiner wrote that the term was used "at one time to signify that a certain amount of bullion was stored in the Treasury while the equivalent paper in circulation" represented the bullion.
See also
References
- ^ Robert A. Mundell, The Birth of Coinage, Discussion Paper #:0102-08, Department of Economics, Columbia University, February 2002.
- Jon Hooks, Economics:fundamentals for financial services providers, p. 201 ISBN 0-89982-494-3, ISBN 978-0-89982-494-9 Retrieved September 9, 2009
- ^ William Howard Steiner, Money and banking, p. 30, H. Holt and company, 1941.
- John Maynard Keynes (1965) . "1. The Classification of Money". A Treatise on Money. Vol. 1. Macmillan & Co Ltd. p. 7.
Fiat Money is Representative (or token) Money (i.e something the intrinsic value of the material substance of which is divorced from its monetary face value)
- Denise Schmandt-Besserat, Tokens: their Significance for the Origin of Counting and Writing
- Keynes, J.M. (1930). A Treatise on Money. Volume I, p. 13
- Joseph Shield Nicholson, A treatise on money and essays on monetary problems], Chapter VI, Effects of Credit or "Representative Money" on prices, pp. 72–74, A. and C. Black, 1895.
Medium of exchange | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Commodity money |
| |||||
Money (Fiat/Token) | ||||||
General |
|