Misplaced Pages

Competition law: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 08:13, 4 July 2007 editTHF (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users, Pending changes reviewers17,107 edits Fix the NPOV problems before removing the tag.← Previous edit Latest revision as of 00:32, 18 December 2024 edit undoHeyElliott (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users118,193 edits WP:LQ, WP:CITEVAR, ceTag: 2017 wikitext editor 
(919 intermediate revisions by more than 100 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Law maintaining market competition}}
{{npov}}
{{redirect2|Antitrust|Anti-Monopoly Law|the film|Antitrust (film){{!}}''Antitrust'' (film)|the law specific to China|Anti Monopoly Law of China}}
] building in ] is home to the influential ] enforcers of U.S. competition laws]]
{{Use dmy dates|date=February 2020}}
{{Competition law}}
'''Competition law''' is the field of ] that promotes or seeks to maintain ] by regulating ] conduct by companies.<ref name="papers.ssrn.com">{{cite SSRN|title=The Role of Competition Law(Act): An Asian Perspective|first1=Rita Yi Man|last1=Li|first2=Yi Lut|last2=Li|date=1 June 2013|ssrn = 2281756}}</ref><ref name="Taylor 2006 1">{{Cite book| last = Taylor| first = Martyn D.| title = International competition law: a new dimension for the WTO?| publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2006| pages = 1| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=wTsfwxMvz_MC| isbn = 978-0-521-86389-6| access-date = 22 March 2023| archive-date = 14 December 2022| archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20221214135313/https://books.google.com/books?id=wTsfwxMvz_MC| url-status = live}}</ref> Competition law is implemented through public and private enforcement.<ref>{{cite web|last1=Cartel Damage Claims (CDC)|title=Cartel Damage Claims (CDC)|url=http://www.carteldamageclaims.com/|website=www.carteldamageclaims.com/|access-date=23 June 2014|archive-date=12 April 2024|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240412052936/https://carteldamageclaims.com/|url-status=live}}</ref> It is also known as '''antitrust law''' (or just '''antitrust'''<ref>{{cite web|url=http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/overview_en.html|title=Antitrust: Overview – Competition – European Commission|website=ec.europa.eu|access-date=27 June 2017|archive-date=5 February 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200205043718/https://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/overview_en.html|url-status=live}}</ref>), '''anti-monopoly law''',<ref name="papers.ssrn.com"/> and '''trade practices law'''; the act of pushing for antitrust measures or attacking monopolistic companies (known as ]) is commonly known as '''trust busting'''.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Trust Busting - Ohio History Central |url=https://ohiohistorycentral.org/w/Trust_Busting |access-date=2023-02-21 |website=ohiohistorycentral.org |archive-date=21 February 2023 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230221231250/https://ohiohistorycentral.org/w/Trust_Busting |url-status=live }}</ref>


The history of competition law reaches back to the ]. The business practices of market traders, ]s and governments have always been subject to scrutiny, and sometimes severe sanctions. Since the 20th century, competition law has become global.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Topping|first1=Simon|last2=Tweedale|first2=Patrick|title=UAE Competition Law: New Regulations and Potential Effect on M&A Transactions|url=https://www.transactionadvisors.com/insights/uae-competition-law-new-regulations-and-potential-effect-ma-transactions|journal=Transaction Advisors|issn=2329-9134|access-date=25 September 2015|archive-date=23 June 2017|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170623090038/https://www.transactionadvisors.com/insights/uae-competition-law-new-regulations-and-potential-effect-ma-transactions|url-status=dead}}</ref> The two largest and most influential systems of competition regulation are ] and ]. National and regional competition authorities across the world have formed international support and enforcement networks.
'''Competition law''', known in the ] as ] ], has three main functions. Firstly, it prohibits agreements aimed to restrict free trading between business entities and their customers. For example, a ] of sport shops who together fix football jersey prices higher than prices resulting from unhindered competition is illegal.<ref>''JJB Sports v OFT CAT 17''</ref> Secondly, competition law can ban the existence or abusive behaviour of a firm dominating the market. One case in point could be a software company who through its ] on computer platforms makes consumers use its media player.<ref>in the E.U. side of the saga, see ''Microsoft v. Commission'' Order, 22 December 2004</ref> Thirdly, to preserve competitive markets, the law supervises the ] of very large corporations. Competition authorities could for instance require that a large packaging company give plastic bottle ]s to competitors before taking over a major ] producer.<ref>Case C-12/03 P, Commission v. Tetra Laval</ref> In this case, as in all three, competition law aims to protect the ] ideal of ] by ensuring business must compete for its share of the ].


Modern competition law has historically evolved on a national level to promote and maintain fair competition in markets principally within the territorial boundaries of ]. National competition law usually does not cover activity beyond territorial borders unless it has significant effects at nation-state level.<ref name="Taylor 2006 1"/> Countries may allow for ] in competition cases based on so-called "effects doctrine".<ref name="Taylor 2006 1"/><ref>JG Castel, 'The Extraterritorial Effects of Antitrust Laws' (1983) 179 Recueil des Cours 9</ref> The protection of international competition is governed by international competition agreements. In 1945, during the negotiations preceding the adoption of the ] (GATT) in 1947, limited international competition obligations were proposed within the ''Charter for an International Trade Organisation''. These obligations were not included in GATT, but in 1994, with the conclusion of the ] of GATT multilateral negotiations, the ] (WTO) was created. The ''Agreement Establishing the WTO'' included a range of limited provisions on various cross-border competition issues on a sector specific basis.<ref>{{Cite book| last = Taylor| first = Martyn D.| title = International competition law: a new dimension for the WTO?| publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2006| page = 2| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=wTsfwxMvz_MC| isbn = 978-0-521-86389-6| access-date = 22 March 2023| archive-date = 14 December 2022| archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20221214135313/https://books.google.com/books?id=wTsfwxMvz_MC| url-status = live}}</ref> Competition law has failed to prevent monopolization of economic activity. "The global economy is dominated by a handful of powerful transnational corporations (TNCs). ... Only 737 top holders accumulate 80% of the control over the value of all ... network control is much more unequally distributed than wealth. In particular, the top ranked actors hold a control ten times bigger than what could be expected based on their wealth. ... Recent works have shown that when a financial network is very densely connected it is prone to systemic risk. Indeed, while in good times the network is seemingly robust, in bad times firms go into distress simultaneously. This knife-edge property was witnessed during the recent (2009) financial turmoil "<ref>{{cite journal | doi=10.1371/journal.pone.0025995 | doi-access=free | title=The Network of Global Corporate Control | date=2011 | last1=Vitali | first1=Stefania | last2=Glattfelder | first2=James B. | last3=Battiston | first3=Stefano | journal=PLOS ONE | volume=6 | issue=10 | pages=e25995 | pmid=22046252 | pmc=3202517 | arxiv=1107.5728 | bibcode=2011PLoSO...625995V }}</ref>
In recent decades, competition law has also been sold as good medicine to provide better ], traditionally funded by ] payers and administered by ] accountable ]s. Hence competition law is closely connected with law on deregulation of access to markets, providing state aids and subsidies, the ] of state owned assets and the use of independent sector regulators, such as the United Kingdom telecommunications watchdog ]. Behind the practice lies the theory, which over the last fifty years has been dominated by ]. Markets are seen as the most efficient method of allocating resources, though sometimes ] and regulation becomes necessary to protect the ideal market model. Behind the theory lies the history, reaching back further than the ]. The business practices of market traders, ] and governments have always been subject to scrutiny, and sometimes severe sanctions. Since the twentieth century, competition law has become global. The two largest, most organised and influential systems of competition regulation are ] and ]. The respective national authorities, the ] (DOJ) and the ] (DGCOMP) have formed international support and enforcement networks. Competition law is growing in importance every day, which warrants for its careful study.


==Starting Point==
==Competition law history==
Competition law, or antitrust law, has three main elements:
] passed tough laws to stop price distortions]]
* prohibiting agreements or practices that restrict free trading and competition between business. This includes in particular the repression of free trade caused by ]s.
As academic Robert Bork writes, "one of the uses of history is to free us of a falsely imagined past."<ref>Bork (1978) p.15; sadly, Bork does not go into "The Historical Foundations of Antitrust Policy" in his book's first chapter earlier than the passage of the Sherman Act 1890</ref>
* banning abusive behavior by a firm ] a market, or anti-competitive practices that tend to lead to such a dominant position. Practices controlled in this way may include ], ], ], and ].
Competition law today deals with concerns very similar to those of governments for over two millenia, though the tools and method to achieve fair economic relations have varied widely. Found under the Roman Emperors and Mediaeval monarchs alike were the use of ]s to stablise prices or support local production, or laws against ] who could force scarcity in the market, charge unfair prices and make secret deals to rip off customers. The concept of "]", however, only came to fruition with 18th century ] and men like ]. Different terms were used to describe this area of the law, including "]", "the law of monopolies", "]" and the "restraint of trade doctrine".
* supervising the ] of large corporations, including some ]s. Transactions that are considered to threaten the competitive process can be prohibited altogether, or approved subject to "remedies" such as an obligation to divest part of the merged business or to offer licenses or access to facilities to enable other businesses to continue competing.

Substance and practice of competition law varies from jurisdiction to jurisdiction. Protecting the interests of consumers (]) and ensuring that entrepreneurs have an opportunity to compete in the ] are often treated as important objectives. Competition law is closely connected with law on deregulation of access to markets, state aids and subsidies, the ] of state owned assets and the establishment of independent sector regulators, among other market-oriented supply-side policies. In recent decades, competition law has been viewed as a way to provide better ].<ref>see, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211006030648/https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/sectors/ |date=6 October 2021 }} page.</ref> ] argued that competition laws can produce adverse effects when they reduce competition by protecting inefficient competitors and when costs of legal intervention are greater than benefits for the consumers.<ref>Bork (1993), p. 56</ref>

==History==
{{Main|History of competition law}}


===Roman legislation=== ===Roman legislation===
An early example was enacted during the ] around 50&nbsp;BC.<ref>This is Julius Caesar's time according to Babled in ''De La Cure Annone chez le Romains''.</ref> To protect the ], heavy fines were imposed on anyone directly, deliberately, and insidiously stopping supply ships.<ref name="Wilberforce 1966 p. 20">Wilberforce (1966) p. 20</ref> Under ] in 301 A.D., an ] imposed the death penalty for anyone violating a tariff system, for example by buying up, concealing, or contriving the scarcity of everyday goods.<ref name="Wilberforce 1966 p. 20"/> More legislation came under the constitution of ] of 483 A.D., which can be traced into Florentine municipal laws of 1322 and 1325.<ref>Wilberforce (1966) p. 22</ref> This provided for confiscation of property and banishment for any trade combination or joint action of monopolies private ''or'' granted by the Emperor. Zeno rescinded all previously granted exclusive rights.<ref name="Wilberforce 1966 p. 21">Wilberforce (1966) p. 21</ref> ] subsequently introduced legislation to pay officials to manage state monopolies.<ref name="Wilberforce 1966 p. 21"/>
{{seealso|Roman law}}
The earliest surviving example of competition law's ancestors appears in the ''Lex Julia de Annona'', enacted during the ] around 50 BC.<ref>This is Julius Caesar's time according to Babled in ''De La Cure Annone chez le Romains''</ref> To protect the corn trade, heavy fines were imposed on anyone directly, deliberately and insidiously stopping supply ships.<ref>Wilberforce (1966) 20</ref> Under ] in 301 AD an edict set a death penalty for anyone violating a tariff system, for example by buying up, concealing or contriving the scarcity of everyday goods.<ref>Wilberforce (1966) 20</ref> The most legislation came under the Constitution of Zeno of 483 AD which can be traced into Florentine Municipal laws of 1322 and 1325.<ref>Wilberforce (1966) 22</ref> It provided for property confiscation and banishment for any trade combinations or joint action of monopolies private ''or'' granted by the Emperor. ] rescinded all previously granted exclusive rights.<ref>Wilberforce (1966) 21</ref> ] also introduced legislation not long after to pay officials to manage state monopolies. As Europe slipped into the ], so did the records of law making until the Middle Ages brought greater expansion of trade in the time of '']''.


===Middle ages=== ===Middle Ages===
Legislation in England to control monopolies and restrictive practices was in force well before the ].<ref name="Wilberforce 1966 p. 21"/> The ] recorded that "]" (i.e. forestalling, the practice of buying up goods before they reach market and then inflating the prices) was one of three ] that ] could carry out through England.<ref>] and ], ''History of English Law'' Vol. II, 453</ref> But concern for fair prices also led to attempts to directly regulate the market. Under ] an act was passed in 1266<ref>51 & 52 Hen. 3, Stat. 1</ref> to fix bread and ale prices in correspondence with grain prices laid down by the ]s. Penalties for breach included ]s, ] and ].<ref>51 & 52 Hen. 3, Stat. 6</ref> A 14th-century statute labelled forestallers as "oppressors of the poor and the community at large and enemies of the whole country".<ref>Wilberforce (1966) p. 23</ref> Under ] the ] of 1349<ref>23 Edw. 3.</ref> fixed wages of artificers and workmen and decreed that foodstuffs should be sold at reasonable prices. On top of existing penalties, the statute stated that overcharging merchants must pay the injured party double the sum he received, an idea that has been replicated in ] ] under ]. Also under Edward III, the following statutory provision outlawed trade combination.<ref>27 Edw. 3, Stat. 2, c. 25</ref>
{{seealso|Lex Mercatoria|Guilds}}
] enacted the Statute of Labourers to cap wages, and provide double damages against infringers]]
Legislation in England to control monopolies and restrictive practices were in force well before the ].<ref>Wilberforce (1966) 21</ref> The ] recorded that "]" (i.e. forestalling, the practice of buying up goods before they reach market and then inflating the prices) was one of three ]s that ] could carry out through England.<ref>] and ], ''History of English Law'' Vol. II, 453</ref> But concern for fair prices also led to attempts to directly regulate the market. Under Henry III an act was passed in 1266<ref>51 & 52 Hen. 3, Stat. 1</ref> to fix bread and ale prices in correspondence with corn prices laid down by the ]s. Penalties for breach included ]s, ] and ].<ref>51 & 52 Hen. 3, Stat. 6</ref> A fourteenth century statute labelled forestallers as "oppressors of the poor and the community at large and enemies of the whole country."<ref>Wilberforce (1966) 23</ref> Under ] the ] of 1349<ref>23 Edw. 3.</ref> fixed wages of artificers and workmen and decreed that foodstuffs should be sold at reasonable prices. On top of existing penalties, the statute stated that overcharging merchants must pay the injured party double the sum he received, an idea that has been replicated in ] ] under ]. Also under Edward III, the following statutory provision in the poetic language of the time outlawed trade combinations.<ref>27 Edw. 3, Stat. 2, c. 25</ref>


<blockquote>"...we have ordained and established, that no merchant or other shall make Confederacy, Conspiracy, Coin, Imagination, or Murmur, or Evil Device in any point that may turn to the Impeachment, Disturbance, Defeating or Decay of the said Staples, or of anything that to them pertaineth, or may pertain."</blockquote> {{blockquote|...&nbsp;we have ordained and established, that no merchant or other shall make Confederacy, Conspiracy, Coin, Imagination, or Murmur, or Evil Device in any point that may turn to the Impeachment, Disturbance, Defeating or Decay of the said Staples, or of anything that to them pertaineth, or may pertain.}}


Examples of legislation in mainland Europe include the ''constitutiones juris metallici'' by ] of ] between 1283 and 1305, condemning combinations of ore traders increasing prices; the Municipal Statutes of Florence in 1322 and 1325 followed ]'s legislation against state monopolies; and under ] in the ] a law was passed "to prevent losses resulting from monopolies and improper contracts which many merchants and artisans made in the Netherlands." In 1553 ] reintroduced tariffs for foodstuffs. ]s in these days were mainly used to stabilise prices, in the face of fluctuations in supply from overseas. So the legislation read here that whereas, In continental Europe, competition principles developed in {{lang|la|]}}. Examples of legislation enshrining competition principles include the ''constitutiones juris metallici'' by ] of ] between 1283 and 1305, condemning combination of ore traders increasing prices; the Municipal Statutes of Florence in 1322 and 1325 followed ]'s legislation against state monopolies; and under ] in the ] a law was passed "to prevent losses resulting from monopolies and improper contracts which many merchants and artisans made in the Netherlands". In 1553, ] reintroduced tariffs for foodstuffs, designed to stabilize prices, in the face of fluctuations in supply from overseas. So the legislation read here that whereas,


<blockquote>"it is very hard and difficult to put certain prices to any such things... prices of such victuals be many times enhanced and raised by the Greedy Covetousness and Appetites of the Owners of such Victuals, by occasion of ingrossing and regrating the same, more than upon any reasonable or just ground or cause, to the great damage and impoverishing of the King's subjects."<ref>25 Hen. 8, c. 2.</ref></blockquote> {{blockquote|it is very hard and difficult to put certain prices to any such things&nbsp;... prices of such victuals be many times enhanced and raised by the Greedy Covetousness and Appetites of the Owners of such Victuals, by occasion of ingrossing and regrating the same, more than upon any reasonable or just ground or cause, to the great damage and impoverishing of the King's subjects.<ref>25 Hen. 8, c. 2.</ref>}}


Around this time organisations representing various tradesmen and handicraftspeople, known as ]s had been developing, and enjoyed many concessions and exemptions from the laws against monopolies. The privileges conferred were not abolished until the Municipal Corporations Act 1835. Around this time organizations representing various tradesmen and handicrafts people, known as ]s had been developing, and enjoyed many concessions and exemptions from the laws against monopolies. The privileges conferred were not abolished until the Municipal Corporations Act 1835.


===Early competition law in Europe===
===Renaissance developments===
] in the 17th century thought that general restraints on trade were unreasonable.]]
{{seealso|Renaissance}}
The English common law of ] is the direct predecessor to modern competition law later developed in the US.<ref>"...&nbsp;the modern common law of England passed directly into the legislation and thereafter into the judge-made law of the United States." Wilberforce (1966) p. 7</ref> It is based on the prohibition of agreements that ran counter to public policy, unless the ] of an agreement could be shown. It effectively prohibited agreements designed to restrain another's trade. The 1414 ''Dyer's'' is the first known restrictive trade agreement to be examined under English common law. A dyer had given a bond not to exercise his trade in the same town as the plaintiff for six months but the plaintiff had promised nothing in return. On hearing the plaintiff's attempt to enforce this restraint, Hull J exclaimed, "per Dieu, if the plaintiff were here, he should go to prison until he had paid a fine to the King". The court denied the collection of a bond for the dyer's breach of agreement because the agreement was held to be a restriction on trade.<ref>(1414) 2 Hen. 5, 5 Pl. 26</ref> English courts subsequently decided a range of cases which gradually developed competition related case law, which eventually were transformed into ].<ref name="Papadopoulos 2010 7">{{Cite book| last = Papadopoulos| first = Anestis S| title = The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy| publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2010| page = 7| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law| isbn = 978-0-521-19646-8| access-date = 22 October 2020| archive-date = 12 April 2024| archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20240412052931/https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law#v=snippet&q=eu%20competition%20law&f=false| url-status = live}}</ref>
]]]
Europe around the 15th century was changing fast. The ] had just been opened up, overseas trade and plunder was pouring wealth through the international economy and attitudes among businessmen were shifting. In 1561 a system of Industrial Monopoly Licences, similar to modern ]s had been introduced into England.<ref>The idea is said to have originated in Venice in 1500</ref> But by the reign of Queen Elizabeth I, the system was reputedly much abused and used merely to preserve privileges, encouraging nothing new in the way of innovation or manufacture.<ref>according to ], 4 Holdsworth, 3rd ed., Chap. 4 p. 346</ref> When a protest was made in the ] and a Bill was introduced, the Queen convinced the protesters to challenge the case in the courts. This was the catalyst for the ] or ''Darcy v. Allin''.<ref>(1602) 11 Co. Rep. 84b</ref> The plaintiff, an officer of the Queen's household, had been granted the sole right of making playing cards and claimed damages for the defendant's infringement of this right. The court found the grant void and that three characteristics of monopoly were (1) price increases (2) quality decrease (3) the tendency to reduce artificers to idleness and begarry. This put a temporary end to complaints about monopoly, till ] began to grant them again. In 1623 Parliament passed the ], which for the most part excluded patent rights from its prohibitions, as well as guilds. From ], through the civil war and to ], monopolies continued, especially useful for raising revenue.<ref>e.g. one John Manley paid £10,000 p.a. from 1654 to the Crown for a tender on the "postage of letters both inland and foreign"</ref> Then in 1684, in ''East India Company v. Sandys''<ref>(1685) 10 St. Tr. 371</ref> it was decided that exclusive rights to trade only outside the realm were legitimate, on the grounds that only large and powerful concerns could trade in the conditions prevailing overseas. In 1710 to deal with high coal prices caused by a Newcastle Coal Monopoly the New Law was passed.<ref>9 Anne, c. 30</ref> Its provisions stated that "all and every contract or contracts, Covenants and Agreements, whether the same be in writing or not in writing... are hereby declared to be illegal." By the time Adam Smith wrote the '']'' in 1776<ref>Adam Smith, An Enquiry into the Wealth of Nations'' (1776)</ref>, not so much the government but private traders were the greater threat to the public and free competition. Smith was somewhat cynical of the possibility for change.


].]]
<blockquote>"To expect indeed that freedom of trade should ever be entirely restored in Great Britain is as absurd as to expect that ] or ] should ever be established in it. Not only the prejudices of the public, but what is more unconquerable, the private interests of many individuals irresistibly oppose it. The Member of Parliament who supports any proposal for strengthening this Monopoly is seen to acquire not only the reputation for understanding trade, but great popularity and influence with an order of men whose members and wealth render them of great importance."</blockquote>
Europe around the 16th century was changing quickly. The ] had just been opened up, overseas trade and plunder was pouring wealth through the international economy and attitudes among businessmen were shifting. In 1561 a system of Industrial Monopoly Licenses, similar to modern ]s had been introduced into England. But by the reign of ], the system was reputedly much abused and used merely to preserve privileges, encouraging nothing new in the way of innovation or manufacture.<ref>according to ], 4 Holdsworth, 3rd ed., Chap. 4 p. 346</ref> In response English courts developed case law on restrictive business practices. The statute followed the unanimous decision in ''Darcy v. Allein'' 1602, also known as the ],<ref>(1602) 11 Co. Rep. 84b</ref> of the ] to declare void the sole right that Queen Elizabeth I had granted to Darcy to import playing cards into England.<ref name="Papadopoulos 2010 7"/> Darcy, an officer of the Queen's household, claimed damages for the defendant's infringement of this right. The court found the grant void and that three characteristics of ] were (1) price increases, (2) quality decrease, (3) the tendency to reduce artificers to idleness and beggary. This put an end to granted monopolies until ] began to grant them again. In 1623 Parliament passed the ], which for the most part excluded ] rights from its prohibitions, as well as guilds. From ], through the civil war and to ], monopolies continued, especially useful for raising revenue.<ref>For example one John Manley paid p.a. from 1654 to the Crown for a tender on the "postage of letters both inland and foreign" Wilberforce (1966) p. 18</ref> Then in 1684, in ''East India Company v. Sandys'' it was decided that exclusive rights to trade only outside the realm were legitimate, on the grounds that only large and powerful concerns could trade in the conditions prevailing overseas.<ref>(1685) 10 St. Tr. 371</ref>


The development of early competition law in England and Europe progressed with the diffusion of writings such as '']'' by ], who first established the concept of the '']''. At the same time ] replaced the individual ], or group of artisans, with paid labourers and machine-based production. Commercial success became increasingly dependent on maximizing production while minimizing cost. Therefore, the size of a company became increasingly important, and a number of European countries responded by enacting laws to regulate large companies that restricted trade. Following the ] in 1789 the law of 14–17 June 1791 declared agreements by members of the same trade that fixed the price of an industry or labour as void, unconstitutional, and hostile to liberty. Similarly, the Austrian Penal Code of 1852 established that "agreements ... to raise the price of a commodity ... to the disadvantage of the public should be punished as misdemeanours". Austria passed a law in 1870 abolishing the penalties, though such agreements remained void. However, in Germany laws clearly validated agreements between firms to raise prices. Throughout the 18th and 19th centuries, ideas that dominant private companies or legal monopolies could excessively restrict trade were further developed in Europe. However, as in the late 19th century, a depression spread through Europe, known as the ], ideas of competition lost favour, and it was felt that companies had to co-operate by forming ] to withstand huge pressures on prices and profits.<ref>{{Cite book| last = Papadopoulos| first = Anestis S| title = The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy| publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2010| pages = 8–9| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law| isbn = 978-0-521-19646-8| access-date = 22 October 2020| archive-date = 12 April 2024| archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20240412052931/https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law#v=snippet&q=eu%20competition%20law&f=false| url-status = live}}</ref>
===Restraint of trade===
{{main|Restraint of trade}}
] in the 17th century thought that general restraints on trade were unreasonable]]
The English law of restraint of trade is the direct predecessor to modern competition law.<ref>"the modern common law of England passed directly into the legislation and thereafter into the judge-made law of the United States." Wilberforce (1966) 7</ref> Its current use is small, given modern and economically oriented statutes in most common law countries. Its approach was based on the two concepts of prohibiting agreements that ran counter to public policy, unless the ] of an agreement could be shown. A restraint of trade is simply some kind of agreed provision that is designed to restrain another's trade. For example, in ''Nordenfelt v. Maxim, Nordenfelt Gun Co.''<ref>''Nordenfelt v. Maxim, Nordenfelt Gun Co.'' AC 535</ref> a Swedish arm inventor promised on sale of his business to an American gun maker that he "would not make guns or ammunition anywhere in the world, and would not compete with Maxim in any way."


==Modern competition law==
To be consider whether or not there is a restraint of trade in the first place, both parties must have provided valuable ] for their agreement. In ''Dyer's'' case<ref>(1414) 2 Hen. 5, 5 Pl. 26</ref> a dyer had given a bond not to exercise his trade in the same town as the plaintiff for six months but the plaintiff had promised nothing in return. On hearing the plaintiff's attempt to enforce this restraint, Hull J exclaimed,
While the development of competition law stalled in Europe during the late 19th century, in 1889 ] enacted what is considered the first competition statute of modern times. The ''Act for the Prevention and Suppression of Combinations formed in restraint of Trade'' was passed one year before the United States enacted the most famous legal statute on competition law, the ] of 1890. It was named after ] who argued that the Act "does not announce a new principle of law, but applies old and well recognised principles of common law".<ref name="bare_url">{{Cite book| last = Papadopoulos| first = Anestis S| title = The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy| publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2010| pages = 9–10| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law| isbn = 978-0-521-19646-8| access-date = 22 October 2020| archive-date = 12 April 2024| archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20240412052931/https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law#v=snippet&q=eu%20competition%20law&f=false| url-status = live}}</ref>


===United States antitrust===
<blockquote>"per Dieu, if the plaintiff were here, he should go to prison until he had paid a fine to the King."</blockquote>
{{Main|United States antitrust law}}
], 1886]]
The ] of 1890 attempted to outlaw the restriction of competition by large companies, who co-operated with rivals to fix outputs, prices and market shares, initially through ''pools'' and later through ''trusts''. Trusts first appeared in the US railroads, where the capital requirement of railroad construction precluded competitive services in then scarcely settled territories. This trust allowed railroads to discriminate on rates imposed and services provided to consumers and businesses and to destroy potential competitors. Different trusts could be dominant in different industries. The ] trust in the 1880s controlled several markets, including the market in ], ] and ].<ref name="bare_url" /> Vast numbers of citizens became sufficiently aware and publicly concerned about how the trusts negatively impacted them that the Act became a priority for both major parties. A primary concern of this act is that competitive markets themselves should provide the primary regulation of prices, outputs, interests and profits. Instead, the Act outlawed anticompetitive practices, codifying the common law restraint of trade doctrine.<ref>{{Cite book| last = Papadopoulos| first = Anestis S| title = The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy| publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2010| page = 11| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law| isbn = 978-0-521-19646-8| access-date = 22 October 2020| archive-date = 12 April 2024| archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20240412052931/https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law#v=snippet&q=eu%20competition%20law&f=false| url-status = live}}</ref> Rudolph Peritz has argued that competition law in the United States has evolved around two sometimes conflicting concepts of competition: first that of individual liberty, free of government intervention, and second a fair competitive environment free of excessive ]. Since the enactment of the Sherman Act enforcement of competition law has been based on various economic theories adopted by Government.<ref>{{Cite book| last = Papadopoulos| first = Anestis S| title = The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy| publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2010| page = 12| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law| isbn = 978-0-521-19646-8| access-date = 22 October 2020| archive-date = 12 April 2024| archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20240412052931/https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law#v=snippet&q=eu%20competition%20law&f=false| url-status = live}}</ref>


Section 1 of the Sherman Act declared illegal "every contract, in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations." Section 2 prohibits ], or attempts and conspiracies to monopolize. Following the enactment in 1890 US court applies these principles to business and markets. Courts applied the Act without consistent economic analysis until 1914, when it was complemented by the ] which specifically prohibited exclusive dealing agreements, particularly tying agreements and interlocking directorates, and mergers achieved by purchasing stock. From 1915 onwards the '']'' analysis was frequently applied by courts to competition cases. However, the period was characterized by the lack of competition law enforcement. From 1936 to 1972 courts' application of antitrust law was dominated by the '']'' paradigm of the Harvard School. From 1973 to 1991, the enforcement of antitrust law was based on efficiency explanations as the Chicago School became dominant, and through legal writings such as Judge ]'s book '']''. Since 1992 ] has frequently been used in antitrust cases.<ref>{{Cite book| last = Papadopoulos| first = Anestis S| title = The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy| publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2010| pages = 11–12| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law| isbn = 978-0-521-19646-8| access-date = 22 October 2020| archive-date = 12 April 2024| archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20240412052931/https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law#v=snippet&q=eu%20competition%20law&f=false| url-status = live}}</ref>
The common law has evolved to reflect changing business conditions. So in the early seventeenth century case of ''Rogers v. Parry''<ref>''Rogers v. Parry'' (1613) 2 Bulstr. 136</ref> it was held that a joiner who promised not to trade from his house for 21 years could have this bond enforced against him since the time and place was certain. It was also held that a man cannot bind himself to not use his trade generally by ]. This was followed in ''Broad v. Jolyffe''<ref>''Broad v. Jolyffe'' (1620) Cro. Jac. 596</ref> and ''Mitchell v. Reynolds''<ref>''Mitchell v. Reynolds'' (1711) 1 P.Wms. 181</ref> where ] asked, "What does it signify to a tradesman in London what another does in Newcastle?" In times of such slow communications, commerce around the country it seemed axiomatic that a general restraint served no legitimate purpose for one's business and ought to be void. But already in 1880 in ''Roussillon v. Roussillon''<ref>''Roussillon v. Roussillon'' (1880) 14 Ch. D. 351</ref> ] stated that a restraint unlimited in space need not be void, since the real question was whether it went further than necessary for the promisee's protection. So in the ''Nordenfelt''<ref>''Nordenfelt v. Maxim, Nordenfelt Gun Co.'' AC 535</ref> case Lord McNaughton rule that while one could validly promise to "not make guns or ammunition anywhere in the world" it was and unreasonable restraint to "not compete with Maxim in any way." This approach in England was confirmed by the House of Lords in ''Mason v. The Provident Supply and Clothing Co.''<ref>''Mason v. The Provident Supply and Clothing Co.'' AC 724</ref>


], mergers and acquisitions came into additional scrutiny from U.S. regulators. Under the act, parties must make a pre-merger notification to the U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission prior to the completion of a transaction. As of February 2, 2021, the FTC reduced the Hart-Scott-Rodino reporting threshold to $92 million in combined assets for the transaction.<ref>{{Cite web|title=FTC Announces Reduced Hart-Scott-Rodino Act Thresholds For 2021|url=https://www.seyfarth.com/news-insights/ftc-announces-reduced-hart-scott-rodino-act-thresholds-for-2021.html|access-date=2021-04-12|website=Seyfarth Shaw - FTC Announces Reduced Hart-Scott-Rodino Act Thresholds For 2021|language=en|archive-date=12 April 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210412031404/https://www.seyfarth.com/news-insights/ftc-announces-reduced-hart-scott-rodino-act-thresholds-for-2021.html|url-status=live}}</ref>
==Competition law today==
Modern competition law begins with the United States legislation of the ] of 1890 and the ] of 1914. While other, particularly European, countries also had some form of regulation on monopolies and cartels, the US codification of the common law position on restraint of trade had a widespread effect on subsequent competition law development. Both after the ] and after the fall of the ] competition law has gone through phases of renewed attention and legislative updates around the world.


===United States antitrust=== ===European Union law===
{{main|United States antitrust law}} {{Main|European Union competition law}}
Competition law gained new recognition in Europe in the inter-war years, with Germany enacting its first anti-cartel law in 1923 and Sweden and Norway adopting similar laws in 1925 and 1926 respectively. However, with the ] of 1929 competition law disappeared from Europe and was revived following the ] when the United Kingdom and Germany, following pressure from the United States, became the first European countries to adopt fully fledged competition laws. At a regional level ] has its origins in the ] (ECSC) agreement between France, ], ], the ], ] and Germany in 1951 following the Second World War. The agreement aimed to prevent Germany from re-establishing dominance in the production of ] and ] as it was felt that this dominance had contributed to the outbreak of the war. Article 65 of the agreement banned cartels and article 66 made provisions for concentrations, or mergers, and the abuse of a dominant position by companies.<ref>{{Cite book| last = Papadopoulos| first = Anestis S| title = The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy | publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2010| pages =12–13 | url = https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law| isbn = 978-0-521-19646-8}}</ref> This was the first time that competition law principles were included in a ] regional agreement and established the trans-European model of competition law. In 1957 competition rules were included in the ], also known as the EC Treaty, which established the ] (EEC). The Treaty of Rome established the enactment of competition law as one of the main aims of the EEC through the "institution of a system ensuring that competition in the common market is not distorted". The two central provisions on EU competition law on companies were established in article 85, which prohibited anti-competitive agreements, subject to some exemptions, and article 86 prohibiting the abuse of dominant position. The treaty also established principles on competition law for member states, with article 90 covering public undertakings, and article 92 making provisions on state aid. Regulations on mergers were not included as member states could not establish consensus on the issue at the time.<ref>{{Cite book| last = Papadopoulos| first = Anestis S| title = The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy | publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2010| page =14 | url = https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law| isbn = 978-0-521-19646-8}}</ref>
] was one of the greatest companies to be broken up under United States antitrust laws]]
The American term ] arose not because the US statutes had anything to do with ordinary ], but because the enormous American corporations used to set up trusts to hide their business interests. Big trusts became synonymous with big monopolies and the government stepped in to prevent the threat to the ] order. The ] and ]s represented a break with past law on competition, because they were enacted in by far the largest and most powerful economy of the time, across the United States as a whole. Interpretation of the Acts took on a life of its own, and it was these interpretative methods that became replicated by countries around the world. That said, U.S. antitrust is directly linked to the English common law on restraint of trade. Firstly, ], a principal draftsman of the ] said in a debate, "We have affirmed the old doctrine of the common law in regard to all inter-state and inter-national commercial transactions and have clothed the United States courts with authority to enforce that doctrine by injunction." Secondly, in the ''Standard Oil'' case<ref>''Standard Oil of New Jersey v. United States'' (1911) 221 U.S. 1</ref> ] explicitly linked the Sherman Act with the common law and sixteenth century English statutes on engrossing.<ref>e.g. Under ] in 1552, 5 & 6 Edw. 6, c. 14]]</ref> Thirdly, the Act's wording clearly reflects the common law. The first two sections read as follows,


Today, the ] prohibits anti-competitive agreements in Article 101(1), including ]. According to Article 101(2) any such agreements are automatically void. Article 101(3) establishes exemptions, if the collusion is for distributional or technological innovation, gives consumers a "fair share" of the benefit and does not include unreasonable restraints that risk eliminating competition anywhere (or compliant with the ] of ]). Article 102 prohibits the abuse of ],<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Vandenborre|first1=Ingrid|last2=Goetz|first2=Thorsten|last3=Dionnet|first3=Stephane|title=EU Nonmerger Antitrust Enforcement Gets Stricter|url=https://www.transactionadvisors.com/insights/eu-nonmerger-antitrust-enforcement-gets-stricter|journal=Transaction Advisors|issn=2329-9134|access-date=29 April 2015|archive-date=23 June 2017|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170623092339/https://www.transactionadvisors.com/insights/eu-nonmerger-antitrust-enforcement-gets-stricter|url-status=dead}}</ref> such as price discrimination and exclusive dealing. ] governs mergers between firms.<ref>{{CELEX|32004R0139|text=Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of 20 January 2004 on the control of concentrations between undertakings (the EC Merger Regulation)}}</ref> The general test is whether a concentration (i.e. merger or acquisition) with a community dimension (i.e. affects a number of EU member states) might significantly impede ]. Articles 106 and 107 provide that member state's right to deliver public services may not be obstructed, but that otherwise public enterprises must adhere to the same competition principles as companies. Article 107 lays down a general rule that the state may not aid or subsidize private parties in distortion of free competition and provides exemptions for ], regional development objectives and in the event of a ].{{Citation needed|date=September 2011}}
<blockquote>"Section 1. Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal. Every person who shall make any contract or engage in any combination or conspiracy hereby declared to be illegal shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine....</blockquote>


Leading ] cases on competition law include '']'' and '']''.
<blockquote>Section 2. Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine...."</blockquote>


===India===
The Sherman Act was deficient in a number of respects, its broadbrush approach being one of them. ] President ]'s federal government sued 45 companies, and ] used it against 75. Furthermore, the Sherman Act was used to sue trade unions, whose members, working employees, attempted to ] for better pay and conditions in their contractual terms - a far cry from the wealth extorted from the economy by monopolists. The following ] administration of President ] brought in the ] to remedy these defects. Firstly, specific categories of abusive conduct were laid down, such as ](section 2), exclusive dealings (section 3) and mergers which substantially lessen competition (section 7). Secondly, section 6 exempted trade unions from the law's operation. These laws are now codified under ] of the ].
{{Main|The Competition Act, 2002|Competition Commission of India}}


India responded positively by opening up its economy by removing controls during the ]. In quest of increasing the efficiency of the nation's economy, the ] acknowledged the ] ] ] era. As a result, Indian market faces competition from within and outside the country.<ref name="Competition">Warrier VS, Conflict between Competition Law and Intellectual Property Rights {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200910141719/http://lex-warrier.in/2010/09/competition-law-and-ipr/ |date=10 September 2020 }} The Lex-Warrier: Online Law Journal, {{ISSN|2319-8338}}</ref> This led to the need of a strong legislation to dispense justice in commercial matters and ] was passed. The history of competition law in India dates back to the 1960s when the first competition law, namely the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act (MRTP) was enacted in 1969. But after the economic reforms in 1991, this legislation was found to be obsolete in many aspects and as a result, a new competition law in the form of ] was enacted in 2003. The ], is the quasi judicial body established for enforcing provisions of the Competition Act.<ref name="CCI formation">{{cite web|title=CCI formation|url=http://www.cci.gov.in/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=18|publisher=CCI|access-date=4 January 2013|archive-date=14 April 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210414102723/http://www.cci.gov.in/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=18|url-status=live}}</ref>
===Post war consensus===
{{seealso|Competition regulator}}
], established following ], was the first ] wide competition authority]]
It was after the ] that countries began to follow the United States' lead in competition policy. In 1923 Canada introduced the ] and in 1926 France reinforced its basic competition provisions from the 1810 Code Napoleon. After the ], the Allies, led by the ], introduced tight regulation of cartels and monopolies in occupied ] and ]. In Germany, despite the existence of laws against unfair competition passed in 1909 (''Gesetz gegen den unlauteren Wettbewerb'' or ''UWB'') it was widely believed that the predominance of large cartels of German industry had made it easier for the ] to assume total economic control, simply by bribing or blackmailing the heads of a small number of industrial magnates. Similarly in Japan, where business was organised along family and nepotistic ties, the ] were easy for the despotic government to manipulate into the war effort. Following, unconditional surrender tighter controls, replicating American policy were introduced.


===China===
Further developments however were considerably overshadowed by the move towards ] and industry wide planning in many countries. Making the economy and industry democratically accountable through direct government action became a priority. ] industry, ], ], ], ], ] and many other sectors were targeted for their special qualities of being ]. ] countries were slow in enacting statutory competition law provisions. The United Kingdom introduced the (considerably less stringent) Restrictive Practices Act in 1956. Australia introduced its current ] in 1974. Recently however there has been a wave of updates, especially in Europe to harmonise legislation with contemporary competition law thinking.
{{Main|Anti Monopoly Law of China}}


The ] came into effect in 2008. For years, it was enforced by three different branches of government, but since 2018 its enforcement has been the responsibility of the ]. The '']'' reported that the law had generated 11 billion RMB of penalties between 2008 and 2018.<ref>{{cite news |title=China's updated Anti-monopoly Law criticised for not doing enough |url=https://www.scmp.com/economy/china-economy/article/3045224/chinas-updated-anti-monopoly-law-aimed-further-protecting |access-date=27 October 2022 |work=South China Morning Post |date=9 January 2020 |language=en |archive-date=27 October 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221027204034/https://www.scmp.com/economy/china-economy/article/3045224/chinas-updated-anti-monopoly-law-aimed-further-protecting |url-status=live }}</ref>
===European Union law===
{{main|European Community competition law}}
] which covers EU competition laws]]
In 1957 six Western European countries signed the ] (TEC or Treaty of Rome), which over the last fifty years has grown into a ] of nearly half a billion citizens. The European Community is the name for the economic and social pillar of ], under which competition law falls. Healthy competition is seen as an essential element in the creation of a common market free from restraints on trade. The first provision is Article 81 TEC, which deals with cartels and restrictive vertical agreements. Prohibited are...


===International expansion===
<blockquote>"(1) ...all agreements between undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices which may affect trade between Member States and which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition within the common market..."</blockquote>
By 2008, 111 countries had enacted competition laws, which is more than 50 percent of countries with a population exceeding 80,000 people. 81 of the 111 countries had adopted their competition laws in the past 20 years, signaling the spread of competition law following the collapse of the ] and the expansion of the ].<ref>{{Cite book| last = Papadopoulos| first = Anestis S| title = The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy | publisher = Cambridge University Press| year = 2010| page =15 | url = https://books.google.com/books?id=BpCqNMPNxeoC&q=eu+competition+law| isbn = 978-0-521-19646-8}}</ref> Currently ] of many states closely co-operate, on everyday basis, with foreign counterparts in their enforcement efforts, also in such key area as information / evidence sharing.<ref>Marek Martyniszyn, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240412053623/https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2436467 |date=12 April 2024 }}, 19(1) International Journal of Evidence and Proof 11 (2015)</ref>


In many of Asia's developing countries, including India, Competition law is considered a tool to stimulate economic growth. In ] and ], the competition law prevents certain forms of ]. In addition, competition law has promoted fairness in China and Indonesia as well as international integration in Vietnam.<ref name="papers.ssrn.com"/> ]'s Competition Ordinance came into force in the year 2015.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.compcomm.hk/en/legislation_guidance/legislation/legislation/comp_ordinance_cap619.html|title=Competition Commission – The Competition Ordinance (Cap 619)|website=www.compcomm.hk|access-date=27 June 2017|archive-date=12 June 2017|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170612151723/http://www.compcomm.hk/en/legislation_guidance/legislation/legislation/comp_ordinance_cap619.html|url-status=live}}</ref>
Article 81(1) then gives examples of "hard core" restrictive practices such as price fixing or market sharing and 81(2) confirms that any agreements are automatically void. However, just like the ], Article 81(3) creates exemptions, if the collusion is for distributional or technological innovation, gives consumers a "fair share" of the benefit and does not include unreasonable restraints (or disproportionate, in ECJ terminology) that risk eliminating competition anywhere. Article 82 TEC deals with monopolies, or more precisely firms who have a dominant market share and abuse that position. Unlike ], EC law has never been used to punish the existence of dominant firms, but merely imposes a special responsibility to conduct oneself appropriately. Specific categories of abuse listed in Article 82 include price discrimination and exclusive dealing, much the same as sections 2 and 3 of the U.S. Clayton Act. Also under Article 82, the European Council was empowered to enact a ] to control mergers between firms, currently the latest known by the abbreviation of ECMR "Reg. 139/2004". The general test is whether a concentration (i.e. merger or acquisition) with a community dimension (i.e. affects a number of EU member states) might significantly impede effective competition. Again, the similarity to the ]'s substantial lessening of competition. Finally, Articles 86 and 87 TEC regulate the state's role in the market. Article 86(2) states clearly that nothing in the rules cannot be used to obstruct a member state's right to deliver public services, but that otherwise public enterprises must play by the same rules on collusion and abuse of dominance as everyone else. Article 87, similar to Article 81, lays down a general rule that the state may not aid or subsidise private parties in distortion of free competition, but then grants exceptions for things like charities, natural disasters or regional development.


=== ASEAN member states ===
===International enforcement===
As part of the creation of the ASEAN Economic Community, the member states of the ] (ASEAN) pledged to enact competition laws and policies by the end of 2015.<ref>{{Cite news|url=http://asean.org/asean-economic-community/sectoral-bodies-under-the-purview-of-aem/competition-policy/overview/|title=Overview|work=ASEAN {{!}} ONE VISION ONE IDENTITY ONE COMMUNITY|access-date=2018-02-28|language=en-US|archive-date=28 February 2018|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180228114819/http://asean.org/asean-economic-community/sectoral-bodies-under-the-purview-of-aem/competition-policy/overview/|url-status=live}}</ref> Today, all ten member states have general competition legislation in place. While there remains differences between regimes (for example, over merger control notification rules, or leniency policies for whistle-blowers),<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.conventuslaw.com/report/competition-law-in-asean-where-are-we-now-and/|title=Competition Law in ASEAN: Where Are We Now, And Where Are We Headed?|website=Conventus Law|date=19 June 2016|language=en|access-date=2018-02-28|archive-date=28 February 2018|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180228223951/http://www.conventuslaw.com/report/competition-law-in-asean-where-are-we-now-and/|url-status=live}}</ref> and it is unlikely that there will be a supranational competition authority for ASEAN (akin to the European Union),<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.eucentre.sg/?p=11358|title=EU Competition Law: A Roadmap for ASEAN?|website=EU Centre in Singapore|language=en-US|access-date=2018-02-28|archive-date=28 February 2018|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180228223315/http://www.eucentre.sg/?p=11358|url-status=live}}</ref> there is a clear trend towards increase in infringement investigations or decisions on cartel enforcement.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.expertguides.com/articles/a-new-era-for-competition-law-in-the-asean-region/arezehbk|title=A new era for competition law in the ASEAN region|website=Expert Guides|language=en-gb|access-date=2018-02-28|archive-date=28 February 2018|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180228223354/https://www.expertguides.com/articles/a-new-era-for-competition-law-in-the-asean-region/arezehbk|url-status=live}}</ref>
{{seealso|World Trade Organization|International Competition Network}}
] members have been recently discussing how future global competition law could look]]
Competition law has already been substantially internationalised along the lines of the US model by nation states themselves, however the involvement of international organisations has been growing. Increasingly active at all international conferences are the ] (UNCTAD) and the ] (OECD), which is prone to making neo-liberal recommendations about the total application of competition law for public and private industries.<ref>see, Tony Prosser, ''The Limits of Competition Law'' (2005) ch.1</ref> Chapter 5 of the post war ] contained an Antitrust code<ref>see a speech by Wood, ''The Internationalisation of Antitrust Law: Options for the Future'' 3 February 1995, at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/future.txt</ref> but this was never incorporated into the WTO's forerunner, the ] 1947. ] Director and Professor Richard Whish wrote sceptically that it "seems unlikely at the current stage of its development that the WTO will metamorphose into a global competition authority."<ref>Whish (2003) 448</ref> Despite that, at the ongoing ] of trade talks for the ], discussion includes the prospect of competition law enforcement moving up to a global level. While it is incapable of enforcement itself, the newly established ]<ref>see, http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/</ref> (ICN) is a way for national authorities to coordinate their own enforcement activities.


==Enforcement==
==Competition law theory==
{{See also|World Trade Organization|International Competition Network}}
===Traditional perspective===
] members, in green and blue, whether competition law should form part of the agreements.]]
The traditional perspective on competition was that certain agreements could be an unreasonable restraint on the ] of tradespeople to carry on their livelihoods. Restraints were judged as good or bad by courts on an ''ad hoc'' basis as new cases appeared and in the light of changing business circumstances. Hence the courts found specific categories of agreement, specific clauses, to fall foul of their doctrine on economic fairness, and they did not contrive an overarching conception of market power. Earlier theorists like Adam Smith rejected any monopoly power and the very existence of, not just large corporations, but ]s at all. However by the latter half of the nineteenth century it had become clear that large firms had become a fact of the market economy, and the old model of many small producers was fictitious.
Competition law is enforced at the national level through competition authorities, as well as private enforcement. The ] explained:<ref>''Hawaii v. Standard Oil Co. of California'', {{ussc|405|251|1972}}, 262.</ref>


{{blockquote|Every violation of the antitrust laws is a blow to the free-enterprise system envisaged by Congress. This system depends on strong competition for its health and vigor, and strong competition depends, in turn, on compliance with antitrust legislation. In enacting these laws, Congress had many means at its disposal to penalize violators. It could have, for example, required violators to compensate federal, state, and local governments for the estimated damage to their respective economies caused by the violations. But, this remedy was not selected. Instead, Congress chose to permit all persons to sue to recover three times their actual damages every time they were injured in their business or property by an antitrust violation.}}
===Neo-classical synthesis===
{{seealso|Neo-classical economics}}
] won the Nobel prize for economics in 1970 for his merging of maths and political economy]]
Most contemporary textbooks present the economic theory behind competition law as a relatively homogenous entity and that there is only one kind of economics.<ref>e.g. Whish (2003) Ch. 1 ''Competition Policy and Economics''; Jones (2004) Ch. 1.2.A ''Economic efficiency''; Gavil (2002) Ch. 1.B ''Identifying the core questions of antitrust law''</ref> Economic theory in legal discourse usually reflects the predominant orthodoxy of economic thought, known in the field as the "neo-classical synthesis". While the second world war was being fought, economist ] wrote his ] on how old mathematical economics models could be reconciled with the newer ] arguments of ]. Whilst Keynsian economists advocated an interventionist role for the state, the new classical economists sought to reassert free market justifications based on Samuelson's twin assumptions of individuals behaving as ] of their self interest and the tendency of prices towards a ].<ref>for just one prominent example of the considerable scepticism on neo-classical economic assumptions, see, from 1998 Nobel laureate ], "Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioural Foundations of Economic Theory," ''Philosophy and Public Affairs'', 6 (1976-7) pp.317-44</ref>


In the ], the so-called "Modernisation Regulation",<ref>], {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230518003606/https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/284432/oft442.pdf |date=18 May 2023 }}, p. 4, published December 2004, accessed 27 November 2023</ref> Regulation 1/2003,<ref>{{CELEX|32003R0001|text=Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 of 16 December 2002 on the implementation of the rules on competition laid down in Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty}}</ref> established that the ] was no longer the only body capable of public enforcement of ]. This was done to facilitate quicker resolution of competition-related inquiries. In 2005 the Commission issued a ] on ''Damages actions for the breach of the EC antitrust rules'',<ref>{{CELEX|52005DC0672|text=Green Paper - Damages actions for breach of the EC antitrust rules {SEC(2005) 1732} }}</ref> which suggested ways of making private damages claims against cartels easier.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/05/489&format=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en|title=European Commission – PRESS RELEASES – Press release – European Commission Green Paper on damages actions for breach of EC Treaty antitrust rules – frequently asked questions|website=europa.eu|access-date=27 June 2017|archive-date=1 May 2012|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120501142829/http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/05/489&format=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en|url-status=live}}</ref>
According to the neo-classical view, production and distribution of goods and services in competitive free markets maximises ]. By this term economists mean something very specific, that competitive free markets deliver ], ] and dynamic efficiency. Allocative efficiency is also known as ] after the Italian economist ] and means that resources in an economy over the ] will go precisely to those who are ] and ] to pay for them. Because rational producers will keep producing and selling, and buyers will keep buying up to the last ] of possible output - or alternatively rational producers will be reduce their output to the margin at which buyers will buy the same amount as produced - there is no waste, the greatest number wants of the greatest number of people become satisfied and ] is perfected because resources can no longer be reallocated to make anyone better off without making someone else worse off; society has achieved allocative efficiency.<ref>for the opposite view see again, ] "The Moral Standing of the Market," in ''Ethics and Economics'', ed. Ellen Frankel Paul, Fred D. Miller, Jr and Jeffrey Paul, Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 1985, pp. 1-19; Amartya Sen, ''On Ethics and Economics'' Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 1987</ref> Productive efficiency simply means that society is making as much as it can. Free markets are meant to reward those who ], and therefore those who will put society's resources towards the ].<ref>for one of the opposite views, see ], '']'' (1967)</ref> Dynamic efficiency refers to the idea that business which constantly competes must research, create and innovate to keep its share of consumers. This traces to Austrian-American political scientist ]'s notion that a "perennial gale of creative destruction" is ever sweeping through ] economies, driving enterprise at the market's mercy.<ref>], ''The Process of Creative Destruction'' (1942)</ref>


Some EU Member States enforce their competition laws with criminal sanctions. As analysed by ], these types of sanctions engender a number of significant theoretical, legal and practical challenges.<ref>Peter Whelan, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151116072212/http://ukcatalogue.oup.com/product/9780199670062.do |date=16 November 2015 }}, Oxford University Press, 2014</ref>
Contrasting with the allocatively, productively and dynamically efficient market model are the monopolists and cartels. Their abuse of ] is capable of limiting output, lining businessmen's pockets at consumers' expense and manufacturing a ] of ]. Why firms can get market power in the first place is not answered easily by neo-classicals. Anomalous causes, each with their own special economist term, are suggested. These include the existence of ], ] of the market, the ], and so on. Markets may ] to be efficient for a variety of reasons, so the exception of competition law's intervention to the rule of '']'' is justified. Orthodox economists fully acknowledge that ] is seldom observed and rarely real, and so aim for what is called "]".<ref>Whish (2003) 14</ref><ref>Clark, "Towards a Concept of Workable Competition" (1940) 30 Am Ec Rev p.241-256</ref> This follows the theory that if one cannot achieve the ideal, then go for the second best option<ref>c.f. Lipsey and Lancaster, "The General Theory of Second Best" (1956-7) 24 Rev Ec Stud 11-32</ref> by using the law to tame market operation where it can.


Antitrust administration and legislation can be seen as a balance between:
===Chicago School===
* guidelines which are clear and specific to the courts, regulators and business but leave little room for discretion that prevents the application of laws from resulting in unintended consequences.
{{seealso|Chicago School (economics)}}
* guidelines which are broad, hence allowing administrators to sway between improving economic outcomes versus succumbing to political policies to redistribute wealth.<ref>{{cite journal| url = http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/UNSWLawJl/2003/15.html| title = COMPETITION LAW IN A SMALL OPEN ECONOMY| volume = 15| author = McEwin, R Ian| journal = University of New South Wales Law Journal| page = 246| year = 2003| access-date = 9 October 2009| archive-date = 25 February 2021| archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20210225153355/http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/UNSWLawJl/2003/15.html| url-status = live}}</ref>
] argues that competition law is fundamentally flawed]]
A group of economists and lawyers, who are largely associated with the ] and a teacher named ], in advocating a minimalist application of competition law. Starting with President ]'s administration in the early 1980s under ] US competition authorities and the ] have adopted their ideas,<ref>see for instance, ''Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc.'', ''Broadcast Music Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc.'', ''NCAA v. Board of Regents of Univ. of Oklahoma'', ''Spectrum Sports Inc. v. McQuillan'', ''State Oil Co. v. Khan'', ''Verizon v. Trinko'', and ''Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc.''</ref> which take the neo-classical concept many steps further. ]'s definition of "]", which he asserts has become "perhaps the most common, is – efficiency."<ref>], ''Economic Analysis of Law''(1998) p.30 5th Ed. Aspen Business and Law</ref> He and a number of other influential economists and lawyers, such as ], ] and ], form the conservative reaction to competition policy. Richard Posner's views are comprehensively laid out in his texts on ''Antitrust law''<ref>Posner, ''Antitrust Law'' (2001) 2nd ed., ISBN 9780226675763</ref> and ''Economic Analysis of Law''<ref>Posner, ''Economic Analysis of Law'' (2007) 7th ed., ISBN 9780735563544</ref> He used to work in the Department of Justice's antitrust division. His views are pro-big business and highly scathing of what he calls "populist" measures to fiddle antitrust towards the protection of smaller business.<ref>Posner (2001) p.24-25</ref> Milton Friedman, taking after his tutor ], used to be the most famous proponent of strict antitrust regulation for big businesses, and reintroducing antitrust laws for ]. More recently he has changed his mind, and is in favour of abolishing them for big business,<ref>Milton Friedman, </ref> keeping them merely to control trade unions.


Chapter 5 of the post-war ] contained an Antitrust code<ref>see a speech by Wood, ''The Internationalisation of Antitrust Law: Options for the Future'' 3 February 1995, at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/future.txt {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20050210184645/http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/future.txt |date=10 February 2005 }}</ref> but this was never incorporated into the WTO's forerunner, the ] 1947. ] Director and Richard Whish wrote sceptically that it "seems unlikely at the current stage of its development that the WTO will metamorphose into a global competition authority".<ref>Whish (2003) p. 448</ref> Despite that, at the ongoing ] of trade talks for the ], discussion includes the prospect of competition law enforcement moving up to a global level. While it is incapable of enforcement itself, the newly established ]<ref>see, http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/ {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210420080723/https://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/ |date=20 April 2021 }}</ref> (ICN) is a way for national authorities to coordinate their own enforcement activities.
] was highly critical of court decisions on United States antitrust law in a series of law review articles and his book ''The Antitrust Paradox''.<ref>Bork, Robert H. ''The Antitrust Paradox'' (1978) New York Free Press ISBN 0465003699</ref> Bork argued that both the original intention of antitrust laws and economic efficiency was pursuit ''only'' of consumer welfare, the protection of competition rather than competitors.<ref>Bork (1978) p.405</ref> Furthermore, only a few acts should be prohibited, namely cartels that fix prices and divide markets, mergers that create monopolies, and dominant firms pricing predatorily, while allowing such practices as vertical agreements and price discrimination on the grounds that it did not harm consumers.<ref>Bork (1978) p.406</ref> Running through the different critiques of US antitrust policy is the common theme that government interference in the operation of free markets does more harm than good.<ref>], ''The Limits of Antitrust'', 63 U. Tex. L. Rev. 1 (1984).</ref> In fact monopolies, they say, are created by government intervention that ]s or attempts to ]. More government intervention in the way of antitrust laws will only further distort markets, for instance by reducing incentives for entrepreneurs to take risks with new projects and contracts.<ref>see e.g. Alan Greenspan, '''' (1998)</ref> The proposed solutions range from its complete abolition to grounding competition law solidly in economic theory of their own persuasion. "The only cure for bad theory," writes Bork, "is better theory".<ref> Bork (1978) p.405</ref> The deep splits existing in economic theory was even fought out in the ] on one occasion, with Professor Philip Areeda, who favours more aggressive antitrust policy, pitted against Robert Bork's preference for non intervention.<ref>''Brooke Group v. Williamson'' (1993)</ref>


==Theory==
===Contemporary issues===
{{Main|Competition law theory}}
In Europe questions of reform have circulated around whether to introduce US style treble damages as added deterrent against competition law violaters. The recent Modernisation Regulation 1/2003 has meant that the ] no longer has a monopoly on enforcement, and that private parties may bring suits in national courts. Hence there has been debate over the legitimacy of private damages actions in traditions which shy from imposing punitive measures in civil actions. Globally, there is still the issue of whether enforcement can take on a dimension that transcends the nation states and individual trading blocks. With ever increasing global economic integration, the potential for cartels and market sharing grows all the time. Nevertheless, considerable scepticism remains about the effectiveness of competition law in achieving economic progress and its interference with the provision of public services. France's president ] called recently for the reference in the praemble to the ] to the goal of "free and undistorted competition" to be removed.<ref>''Removal of competition clause causes dismay'', Tobias Buck and Bertrand Benoit, ] p.6 June 23rd 2007</ref> Though competition law itself would have remained unchanged, the other goals of the praemble which include "full employment" and "social progress" have the perception of greater specificity and as being ends in themselves, while "free competition" is merely a means.


===Classical perspective===
==Competition law practice==
{{See also|Classical economics}}
===Collusion and cartels===
{{main|Collusion|Cartel}}
] philosopher ] was an early enemy of cartels]]
Despite theoretical disagreement on a wide range of issues, most economists and lawyers do agree that hard core cartels should be illegal. Back in 1776, Adam Smith wrote in his book on the '']'',


Under the doctrine of ], antitrust is seen as unnecessary as competition is viewed as a long-term dynamic process where firms compete against each other for market ]. In some markets, a firm may successfully dominate, but it is because of superior skill or innovativeness. However, according to laissez-faire theorists, when it tries to raise prices to take advantage of its monopoly position it creates profitable opportunities for others to compete. A process of ] begins which erodes the monopoly. Therefore, government should not try to break up monopoly but should allow the market to work.<ref>Campbell R. McConnell, Stanley L. Brue. Economics: Principles, Problems, and Policies. McGraw-Hill Professional, 2005. pp. 601–02</ref>
<blockquote>"People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices."</blockquote>


] believed the ] doctrine was justified to preserve ] and ].]]
There has long been consensus that traders' attempts to ] ought to be met with severe financial, sometimes criminal penalties, just as ] and ] produce ought to be. Under EC law cartels are caught by Article 81 ], whereas under US law the ] prohibitions of section 1. To compare, the target of competition law under the Sherman Act ] is every "contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy", which essentially targets anybody who has some dealing or contact with someone else. This encouraged employers to target ] action before reform under the ] ]. In the mean time, Art. 81 EC makes clear who the targets of competition law are in two stages with the term agreement "undertaking". This is used to describe almost anyone "engaged in an economic activity",<ref>''Hoefner v Macroton GmbH'' </ref> but excludes both employees, who are by their "very nature the opposite of the independent exercise of an economic or commercial activity",<ref>per AG Jacobs, ''Albany International BV'' </ref> and public services based on "solidarity" for a "social purpose".<ref>''FENIN v. Commission'' </ref> Undertakings must then have formed an agreement, developed a "concerted practice", or, within an association, taken a decision. Like US antitrust, this just means all the same thing;<ref>per AG Reischl, ''Van Landweyck'' there is no need to distinguish an agreement from a concerted practice, because they are merely convenient labels</ref> any kind of dealing or contact, or a "meeting of the minds" between parties. Covered therefore is a whole range from a strong handshaken written or verbal agreement to a supplier sending invoices with directions not to export to its retailer who gives "tacit acquiescence" to the conduct.<ref>''Sandoz Prodotti Farmaceutica SpA v. Commission'' </ref>
The classical perspective on competition was that certain agreements and business practice could be an unreasonable restraint on the ] of tradespeople to carry on their livelihoods. Restraints were judged as permissible or not by courts as new cases appeared and in the light of changing business circumstances. Hence the courts found specific categories of agreement, specific clauses, to fall foul of their doctrine on economic fairness, and they did not contrive an overarching conception of market power. Earlier theorists like Adam Smith rejected any monopoly power on this basis.


{{blockquote|A monopoly granted either to an individual or to a trading company has the same effect as a secret in trade or manufactures. The monopolists, by keeping the market constantly under-stocked, by never fully supplying the effectual demand, sell their commodities much above the natural price, and raise their emoluments, whether they consist in wages or profit, greatly above their natural rate.<ref>Smith (1776) Book I, Chapter 7, para 26</ref>}}
Less of a consensus exists in the field of ]s. These are agreements not between firms at the same level of production, but firms at different levels in the ], for instance a supermarket and a bread producer. Many question whether there can be any effect on the market when restrictive agreements are concluded vertically.

In '']'' (1776) ] also pointed out the cartel problem, but did not advocate specific legal measures to combat them.

{{blockquote|People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices. It is impossible indeed to prevent such meetings, by any law which either could be executed, or would be consistent with liberty and justice. But though the law cannot hinder people of the same trade from sometimes assembling together, it ought to do nothing to facilitate such assemblies; much less to render them necessary.<ref name="Book I, Chapter 10">Smith (1776) Book I, Chapter 10, para 82</ref>}}

By the latter half of the 19th century, it had become clear that large firms had become a fact of the market economy. ]'s approach was laid down in his treatise '']'' (1859).

{{blockquote|Again, trade is a social act. Whoever undertakes to sell any description of goods to the public, does what affects the interest of other persons, and of society in general; and thus his conduct, in principle, comes within the jurisdiction of society... both the cheapness and the good quality of commodities are most effectually provided for by leaving the producers and sellers perfectly free, under the sole check of equal freedom to the buyers for supplying themselves elsewhere. This is the so-called doctrine of Free Trade, which rests on grounds different from, though equally solid with, the principle of individual liberty asserted in this Essay. Restrictions on trade, or on production for purposes of trade, are indeed restraints; and all restraint, qua restraint, is an evil...<ref>Mill (1859) Chapter V, para 4</ref>}}

===Neo-classical synthesis===
{{See also|Neoclassical synthesis}}
], author of the 20th century's most successful economics text, combined mathematical models and ] macroeconomic intervention. He advocated the general success of the market but backed the American government's antitrust policies.]]
After Mill, there was a shift in economic theory, which emphasized a more precise and theoretical model of competition. A simple neo-classical model of free markets holds that production and distribution of goods and services in competitive free markets maximizes ]. This model assumes that new firms can freely enter markets and compete with existing firms, or to use legal language, there are no ]. By this term economists mean something very specific, that competitive free markets deliver ], ] and dynamic efficiency. Allocative efficiency is also known as ] after the Italian economist ] and means that resources in an economy over the ] will go precisely to those who are ] and ] to pay for them. Because rational producers will keep producing and selling, and buyers will keep buying up to the last ] of possible output – or alternatively rational producers will be reduce their output to the margin at which buyers will buy the same amount as produced – there is no waste, the greatest number wants of the greatest number of people become satisfied and ] is perfected because resources can no longer be reallocated to make anyone better off without making someone else worse off; society has achieved allocative efficiency. Productive efficiency simply means that society is making as much as it can. Free markets are meant to reward those who ], and therefore those who will put society's resources towards the ].<ref>for one of the opposite views, see ], '']'' (1967)</ref> Dynamic efficiency refers to the idea that business which constantly competes must research, create and innovate to keep its share of consumers. This traces to Austrian-American political scientist ]'s notion that a "perennial gale of creative destruction" is ever sweeping through ] economies, driving enterprise at the market's mercy.<ref>], ''The Process of Creative Destruction'' (1942)</ref> This led Schumpeter to argue that monopolies did not need to be broken up (as with ]) because the next gale of economic innovation would do the same.

Contrasting with the allocatively, productively and dynamically efficient market model are monopolies, oligopolies, and cartels. When only one or a few firms exist in the market, and there is no credible threat of the entry of competing firms, prices rise above the competitive level, to either a monopolistic or oligopolistic equilibrium price. Production is also decreased, further decreasing ] by creating a ]. Sources of this market power are said{{By whom|date=October 2009}} to include the existence of ], ] of the market, and the ]. Markets may ] to be efficient for a variety of reasons, so the exception of competition law's intervention to the rule of '']'' is justified if ] can be avoided. Orthodox economists fully acknowledge that ] is seldom observed in the real world, and so aim for what is called "]".<ref>Whish (2003), p. 14.</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last=Clark |first=John M. |year=1940 |title=Towards a Concept of Workable Competition |journal=] |volume=30 |issue=2 |pages=241–56 |jstor=1807048 }}</ref> This follows the theory that if one cannot achieve the ideal, then go for the second best option<ref>c.f. {{cite journal |last1=Lipsey |first1=R. G. |last2=Lancaster |first2=Kelvin |year=1956 |title=The General Theory of Second Best |journal=Review of Economic Studies |volume=24 |issue=1 |pages=11–32 |doi=10.2307/2296233 |jstor=2296233 }}</ref> by using the law to tame market operation where it can.

===Chicago school===
]]]
{{See also|Chicago school of economics|Neoclassical economics}}
A group of economists and lawyers, who are largely associated with the ], advocate an approach to competition law guided by the proposition that some actions that were originally considered to be anticompetitive could actually promote competition.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Hovenkamp |first=Herbert |year=1985 |title=Antitrust Policy after Chicago |journal=Michigan Law Review |volume=84 |issue=2 |pages=213–84 |doi=10.2307/1289065 |publisher=The Michigan Law Review Association |jstor=1289065 |s2cid=153691408 |url=https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/context/faculty_scholarship/article/2926/viewcontent/SSRN_id1396788.pdf |access-date=12 December 2023 |archive-date=12 April 2024 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240412053444/https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/context/faculty_scholarship/article/2926/viewcontent/SSRN_id1396788.pdf |url-status=live }}</ref> The ] has used the Chicago school approach in several recent cases.<ref>'']'', {{ussc|433|36|1977}}; '']'', {{ussc|441|1|1979}}; '']'', {{ussc|468|85|1984}}; '']'', {{ussc|506|447|1993}}; '']'', {{ussc|522|3|1997}}; '']'', {{ussc|540|398|2004}}; '']'', 551 U.S. ___ (2007).</ref> One view of the Chicago school approach to antitrust is found in United States Circuit Court of Appeals Judge ]'s books ''Antitrust Law''<ref>{{cite book |last=Posner |first=R. |url=https://archive.org/details/antitrustlawecon00posn |title=Antitrust Law |publisher=University of Chicago Press |year=2001 |isbn=978-0-226-67576-3 |edition=2nd |location=Chicago |url-access=registration}}</ref> and ''Economic Analysis of Law''.<ref>{{cite book |last=Posner |first=R. |url=https://archive.org/details/economicanalysis00posn |title=Economic Analysis of Law |publisher=Wolters Kluwer Law & Business |year=2007 |isbn=978-0-7355-6354-4 |edition=7th |location=Austin, TX |url-access=registration}}</ref>

] was highly critical of court decisions on United States antitrust law in a series of law review articles and his book '']''.<ref>{{cite book |title=The Antitrust Paradox |last=Bork |first=Robert H. |year=1978 |publisher=Free Press |location=New York |isbn=978-0-465-00369-3 |url=https://archive.org/details/antitrustparadox00bork }}</ref> Bork argued that both the original intention of antitrust laws and economic efficiency was the pursuit ''only'' of consumer welfare, the protection of competition rather than competitors.<ref name="Bork1978p405">Bork (1978), p. 405.</ref> Furthermore, only a few acts should be prohibited, namely cartels that fix prices and divide markets, mergers that create monopolies, and dominant firms pricing predatorily, while allowing such practices as vertical agreements and price discrimination on the grounds that it did not harm consumers.<ref>Bork (1978), p. 406.</ref> Running through the different critiques of US antitrust policy is the common theme that government interference in the operation of free markets does more harm than good.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Easterbrook |first=Frank |author-link=Frank Easterbrook |year=1984 |title=The Limits of Antitrust |journal=Texas Law Review |volume=63 |page=1 |issn=0040-4411 }}</ref> "The only cure for bad theory," writes Bork, "is better theory."<ref name="Bork1978p405" /> ] professor ], who favours more aggressive antitrust policy, in at least one Supreme Court case challenged Robert Bork's preference for non-intervention.<ref>'']'', {{ussc|509|209|1993}}.</ref>

==Practice==

===Collusion and cartels===
{{Main|Collusion|Cartel}}
] philosopher ] was an early enemy of cartels.]]


===Dominance and monopoly=== ===Dominance and monopoly===
{{main|Dominance (economics)|Monopoly}} {{Main|Dominance (economics)|Monopoly}}
] to efficiency that monopolies cause]] ] to efficiency that monopolies cause]]
When firms hold large market shares, up to one hundred percent, consumers are probably at risk of paying higher prices and getting lower quality products than if the market were competitive. This is the general presumption, however ] is argued by the ] to be the true test. For instance the existence of a very high market share does not necessarily mean uncompetitiveness since the threat of new entrants to the market, or corporate takeovers may restrain undesirable conduct. Hence simply being big is not unlawful, although abusing one's dominant position, for instance through exclusionary practices, is. When firms hold large market shares, consumers risk paying higher prices and getting lower quality products than compared to competitive markets. However, the existence of a very high market share does not always mean consumers are paying excessive prices since the threat of new entrants to the market can restrain a high-market-share firm's price increases. Competition law does not make merely having a monopoly illegal, but rather abusing the power that a monopoly may confer, for instance through exclusionary practices. Market dominance is connected with decreased innovation and increased political connectedness.<ref>{{cite journal | url=http://www.nber.org/papers/w25136.pdf | doi=10.3982/ECTA18338 | title=Connecting to Power: Political Connections, Innovation, and Firm Dynamics | date=2023 | last1=Akcigit | first1=Ufuk | last2=Baslandze | first2=Salomé | last3=Lotti | first3=Francesca | journal=Econometrica | volume=91 | issue=2 | pages=529–564 | archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200508070019/https://www.nber.org/papers/w25136.pdf | archive-date=2020-05-08 | url-status=live }}</ref>

First, it is necessary to determine whether a firm is dominant, or whether it behaves "to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors, customers and ultimately of its consumer".<ref>C-27/76 ''United Brands Continental BV v. Commission'' ECR 207</ref> Under EU law, very large market shares raise a presumption that a firm is dominant,<ref>C-85/76 ''Hoffmann-La Roche & Co AG v. Commission'' ECR 461</ref> which may be rebuttable.<ref>''AKZO'' </ref> If a firm has a dominant position, then there is "a special responsibility not to allow its conduct to impair competition on the common market".<ref>''Michelin'' </ref> Similarly as with collusive conduct, market shares are determined with reference to the particular market in which the firm and product in question is sold. Then although the lists are seldom closed,<ref>''Continental Can'' </ref> certain categories of abusive conduct are usually prohibited under the country's legislation. For instance, limiting production at a shipping port by refusing to raise expenditure and update technology could be abusive.<ref>Art. 82 (b) ''Porto di Genova'' </ref> Tying one product into the sale of another can be considered abuse too, being restrictive of ] and depriving competitors of outlets. This was the alleged case in '']''<ref>{{CELEX|62004TO0201(02)|text=Order of the President of the Court of First Instance of 22 December 2004. Microsoft Corp. v Commission of the European Communities. Proceedings for interim relief - Article 82 EC. Case T-201/04 R}}, {{ECLI|ECLI:EU:T:2004:372}}</ref> leading to an eventual fine of million for including its ] with the ] platform. A refusal to supply a facility which is essential for all businesses attempting to compete to use can constitute an abuse. One example was in a case involving a medical company named '']''.<ref>'']'' </ref> When it set up its own rival in the ] drugs market, Commercial Solvents were forced to continue supplying a company named Zoja with the raw materials for the drug. Zoja was the only market competitor, so without the court forcing supply, all competition would have been eliminated.


Forms of abuse relating directly to pricing include price exploitation. It is difficult to prove at what point a dominant firm's prices become "exploitative" and this category of abuse is rarely found. In one case however, a French funeral service was found to have demanded exploitative prices, and this was justified on the basis that prices of funeral services outside the region could be compared.<ref>{{CELEX|61987CJ0030|text=Judgment of the Court (Sixth Chamber) of 4 May 1988. Corinne Bodson v SA Pompes funèbres des régions libérées. Reference for a preliminary ruling: Cour de cassation - France. Competition - Funeral services - Exclusive special rights. Case 30/87.}}, {{ECLI|ECLI:EU:C:1988:225}}</ref> A more tricky issue is ]. This is the practice of dropping prices of a product so much that one's smaller competitors cannot cover their costs and fall out of business. The Chicago school considers predatory pricing to be unlikely.<ref>see, e.g. Posner (1998) p. 332; "While it is possible to imagine cases in which predatory pricing would be a rational stragy, it should be apparent by now why confirmed cases of it are rare."</ref> However, in ''France Telecom SA v. Commission''<ref>Case T-340/03 ''France Telecom SA v. Commission''</ref> a broadband internet company was forced to pay $13.9 million for dropping its prices below its own production costs. It had "no interest in applying such prices except that of eliminating competitors"<ref>''AKZO'' para 71</ref> and was being cross-subsidized to capture the lion's share of a booming market. One last category of pricing abuse is ].<ref>in the EU under Article 82(2)c)</ref> An example of this could be a company offering rebates to industrial customers who export their sugar, but not to customers who are selling their goods in the same market.<ref>''Irish Sugar'' </ref>
First it is necessary to determine whether a firm is dominant, or whether it behaves "to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors, customers and ultimately of its consumer."<ref>C-27/76 ''United Brands Continental BV v. Commission'' ECR 207</ref> Under EU law, very large market shares raise a presumption that a firm is dominant,<ref>C-85/76 ''Hoffmann-La Roche & Co AG v. Commission'' ECR 461</ref> which may be rebuttable.<ref>''AKZO'' </ref> If a firm has a dominant position, because it has beyond a 39.7% market share<ref>this was the lowest yet market share of a "dominant" firm, in BA/Virgin 2004</ref> then there is "a special responsibility not to allow its conduct to impair competition on the common market"<ref>''Michelin'' </ref> Same as with collusive conduct, market shares are determined with reference to the particular market in which the firm and product in question is sold. Then although the lists are seldom closed,<ref>''Continental Can'' </ref> certain categories of abusive conduct are usually prohibited under the country's legislation. For instance, limiting production at a shipping port by refusing to raise expenditure and update technology could be abusive.<ref>Art. 82 (b) ''Porto di Genova'' </ref> Tying one product into the sale of another can be considered abuse too, being restrictive of consumer choice and depriving competitors of outlets. This was the alleged case in ''Microsoft v. Commission''<ref> ''Microsoft v. Commission'' Order, 22 December 2004</ref> leading to an eventual fine of €497 million for including its ] with the ] platform. A refusal to supply a facility which is essential for all businesses attempting to compete to use can constitute an abuse. One example was in a case involving a medical company named ''Commercial Solvents''.<ref>''Commercial Solvents'' </ref> When it set up its own rival in the ] drugs market, Commercial Solvents were forced to continue supplying a company named Zoja with the raw materials for the drug. Zoja was the only market competitor, so without the court forcing supply, all competition would have been eliminated.


====Example====
Forms of abuse relating directly to pricing include price exploitation. It is difficult to prove at what point a dominant firm's prices become "exploitative" and this category of abuse is rarely found. In one case however, a French funeral service was found to have demanded exploitative prices, and this was justified on the basis that prices of funeral services outside the region could be compared.<ref> ''Corinne Bodson v. SA Pompes funèbres des régions libérées'' ECR 2479</ref> A more tricky issue is ]. This is the practice of dropping prices of a product so much that in order one's smaller competitors cannot cover their costs and fall out of business. The ] holds predatory pricing to be impossible, because if it were then banks would lend money to finance it. However in ''France Telecom SA v. Commission''<ref>Case T-340/03 ''France Telecom SA v. Commission''</ref> a broadband internet company was forced to pay €10.35 for dropping its prices below its own production costs. It had "no interest in applying such prices except that of eliminating competitors"<ref>''AKZO'' para 71</ref> and was being crossed subsidised to capture the lion's share of a booming market. One last category of pricing abuse is ].<ref>in the EU under Article 82(2)c)</ref> An example of this could be offering rebates to industrial customers who export sugar that your company sells, but not to Irish customers, selling in the same market as you are in.<ref>''Irish Sugar'' 1999</ref>
According to The World Bank's "Republic of Armenia Accumulation, Competition, and Connectivity Global Competition" report which was published in 2013, the Global Competitiveness Index suggests that Armenia ranks lowest among ECA (Europe and Central Asia) countries in the effectiveness of anti-monopoly policy and the intensity of competition. This low ranking somehow explains the low employment and low incomes in Armenia.<ref>{{cite book |last1=The World Bank |title=Republic of Armenia Accumulation, Competition, and Connectivity Global Competition |publisher=The World Bank |url=http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/367551468207280159/pdf/811370revision0Box0379837B00PUBLIC0.pdf |access-date=7 May 2019 |archive-date=7 May 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190507095519/http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/367551468207280159/pdf/811370revision0Box0379837B00PUBLIC0.pdf |url-status=live }}</ref>


===Mergers and acquisitions=== ===Mergers and acquisitions===
{{main|Mergers and acquisitions}} {{Main|Mergers and acquisitions}}
], valued at $165,747,000,000 was between ] and ] in 2000]] <!-- Commented out because image was deleted: ], valued at $165,747,000,000 was between ] and ] in 2000]] -->
A merger or acquisition involves, from a competition law perspective, the concentration of economic power in the hands of fewer than before.<ref>Under EC law, a concentration is where a "change of control on a lasting basis results from (a) the merger of two or more previously independent undertakings... (b) the acquisition... if direct or indirect control of the whole or parts of one or more other undertakings." Art. 3(1), Regulation 139/2004, the ]</ref> This usually means that one firm buys out the ]s of another. The reasons for oversight of economic concentrations by the state are the same as the reasons to restrict firms who abuse a position of dominance, only that regulation of mergers and acquisitions attempts to deal with the problem before it arises, ''ex ante'' prevention of creating dominant firms.<ref>In the case of ''Gencor Ltd v. Commission'' ECR II-753 the EU ] wrote merger control is there "to avoid the etablishment of market structures which may create or strengthen a dominant position and not need to control directly possible abuses of dominant positions"</ref> In the United States merger regulation began under the Clayton Act, and in the European Union, under the Merger Regulation 139/2004 (known as the "ECMR"<ref>The authority for the Commission to pass this regulation is found under Art. 83 TEC</ref>). Competition law requires that firms proposing to merge gain authorisation from the relevant government authority, or simply go ahead but face the prospect of ] should the concentration later be found to lessen competition. The theory behind mergers is that transaction costs can be reduced compared to operating on an open market through bilateral contracts.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Coase |first=Ronald H.|authorlink=Ronald H. Coase |year=1937|month=November |title=The Nature of the Firm |journal=Economica |volume=4 |issue=16| pages=386–405| url=http://www.cerna.ensmp.fr/Enseignement/CoursEcoIndus/SupportsdeCours/COASE.pdf |accessdate=2007-02-10}}</ref> Concentrations can increase ] and scope. However often firms take advantage of their increase in market power, their increased market share and decreased number of competitors, which can have a knock on effect on the deal that consumers get. Merger control is about predicting what the market might be like, not knowing and making a judgment. Hence the central provision under EU law asks whether a concentration ''would'' if it went ahead "significantly impede effective competition... in particular as a result of the creation or strengthening off a dominant position..."<ref>Art. 2(3) Reg. 129/2005</ref> and the corresponding provision under US antitrust states similarly, A merger or acquisition involves, from a competition law perspective, the concentration of economic power in the hands of fewer than before.<ref>Under EC law, a concentration is where a "change of control on a lasting basis results from (a) the merger of two or more previously independent undertakings... (b) the acquisition... if direct or indirect control of the whole or parts of one or more other undertakings". Art. 3(1), Regulation 139/2004, the ]</ref> This usually means that one firm buys out the ] of another. The reasons for oversight of economic concentrations by the state are the same as the reasons to restrict firms who abuse a position of dominance, only that regulation of mergers and acquisitions attempts to deal with the problem before it arises, ''ex ante'' prevention of market dominance.<ref>In the case of ''Gencor Ltd v. Commission'' ECR II-753 the EU ] wrote merger control is there "to avoid the establishment of market structures which may create or strengthen a dominant position and not need to control directly possible abuses of dominant positions"</ref> In the United States merger regulation began under the Clayton Act, and in the European Union, under the Merger Regulation 139/2004 (known as the "ECMR").<ref>The authority for the Commission to pass this regulation is found under Art. 83 TEC</ref> Competition law requires that firms proposing to merge gain authorization from the relevant government authority. The theory behind mergers is that transaction costs can be reduced compared to operating on an open market through bilateral contracts.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Coase |first=Ronald H.|author-link=Ronald H. Coase |date=November 1937 |title=The Nature of the Firm |journal=Economica |volume=4 |issue=16|pages=386–405 |url=http://www.cerna.ensmp.fr/Enseignement/CoursEcoIndus/SupportsdeCours/COASE.pdf |access-date=2007-02-10 |doi=10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x |archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20070113063048/http://www.cerna.ensmp.fr/Enseignement/CoursEcoIndus/SupportsdeCours/COASE.pdf <!-- Bot retrieved archive --> |archive-date = 13 January 2007}}</ref> Concentrations can increase ] and scope. However often firms take advantage of their increase in market power, their increased market share and decreased number of competitors, which can adversely affect the deal that consumers get. Merger control is about predicting what the market might be like, not knowing and making a judgment. Hence the central provision under EU law asks whether a concentration ''would'', if it went ahead, "significantly impede effective competition... in particular as a result of the creation or strengthening off a dominant position..."<ref>Art. 2(3) Reg. 129/2005</ref> and the corresponding provision under US antitrust states similarly,


<blockquote>"No person shall acquire, directly or indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share capital... of the assets of one or more persons engaged in commerce or in any activity affecting commerce, where... the effect of such acquisition, of such stocks or assets, or of the use of such stock by the voting or granting of proxies or otherwise, may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly.<ref>Clayton Act Section 7, codified at {{usc|15|18}}</ref></blockquote> {{blockquote|No person shall acquire, directly or indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share capital... of the assets of one or more persons engaged in commerce or in any activity affecting commerce, where... the effect of such acquisition, of such stocks or assets, or of the use of such stock by the voting or granting of proxies or otherwise, may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly.<ref>Clayton Act Section 7, codified at {{usc|15|18}}</ref>}}


What amounts to a substantial lessening of, or significant impediment to competition is usually answered through empirical study. The market shares of the merging companies can be assessed and added, although this kind of analysis only gives rise to presumptions, not conclusions.<ref>see, for instance para 17, ''Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers'' (2004/C 31/03)</ref> Something called the ] is used to calculate the "density" of the market, or what concentration exists. Aside from the maths, it is important to consider the product in question and the rate of technical innovation in the market.<ref>C-68/94 ''France v. Commission'' ECR I-1375, para. 219</ref> A further problem of collective dominance, or ] through "economic links"<ref>''Italian Flat Glass'' ECR ii-1403</ref> can arise, whereby the new market becomes more conducive to ]. It is relevant how transparent a market is, because a more concentrated structure could mean firms can coordinate their behaviour more easily, whether firms can deploy deterrants and whether firms are safe from a reaction by their competitors and consumers.<ref>T-342/99 ''Airtours plc v. Commission'' ECR II-2585, para 62</ref> The entry of new firms to the market, and any barriers that they might encounter should be considered.<ref>''Mannesmann, Vallourec and Ilva'' CMLR 529, OJ L102 21 April 1994</ref> If firms are shown to be creating an uncompetitive concentration, in the US they can still argue that they create efficiencies enough to outweigh any detriment, and similar reference to "technical and economic progress" is mentioned in Art. 2 of the ECMR.<ref>see the argument put forth in Hovenkamp H (1999) ''Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law of Competition and Its Practice'', 2nd Ed, West Group, St. Paul, Minnesota. Unlike the authorities however, the courts take a dim view of the efficiencies defence.</ref> Another defence might be that a firm which is being taken over is about to fail or go insolvent, and taking it over leaves a no less competitive state than what would happen anyway.<ref>''Kali und Salz AG v. Commission'' ECR 499</ref> Mergers vertically in the market are rarely of concern, although in ''AOL/Time Warner''<ref>''Time Warner/AOL'' 4 CMLR 454, OJ L268</ref> the ] required that a joint venture with a competitor ] be ceased beforehand. The EU authorities have also focussed lately on the effect of ]s, where companies acquire a large portfolio of related products, though without necessarily dominant shares in any individual market.<ref>e.g. ''Guinness/Grand Metropolitan 5 CMLR 760, OJ L288; Many in the US are scathing of this approach, see W. J. Kolasky, ‘Conglomerate Mergers and Range Effects: It’s a long way from Chicago to Brussels’ 9 Nov. 2001, Address before George Mason University Symposium Washington, DC.</ref> What amounts to a substantial lessening of, or significant impediment to competition is usually answered through empirical study. The market shares of the merging companies can be assessed and added, although this kind of analysis only gives rise to presumptions, not conclusions.<ref>see, for instance para 17, ''Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers'' (2004/C 31/03)</ref> The ] is used to calculate the "density" of the market, or what concentration exists. Aside from the maths, it is important to consider the product in question and the rate of technical innovation in the market.<ref>C-68/94 ''France v. Commission'' ECR I-1375, para. 219</ref> A further problem of collective dominance, or ] through "economic links"<ref>''Italian Flat Glass'' ECR ii-1403</ref> can arise, whereby the new market becomes more conducive to ]. It is relevant how transparent a market is, because a more concentrated structure could mean firms can coordinate their behavior more easily, whether firms can deploy deterrents and whether firms are safe from a reaction by their competitors and consumers.<ref>T-342/99 ''Airtours plc v. Commission'' ECR II-2585, para 62</ref> The entry of new firms to the market, and any barriers that they might encounter should be considered.<ref>''Mannesmann, Vallourec and Ilva'' CMLR 529, OJ L102 21 April 1994</ref> If firms are shown to be creating an uncompetitive concentration, in the US they can still argue that they create efficiencies enough to outweigh any detriment, and similar reference to "technical and economic progress" is mentioned in Art. 2 of the ECMR.<ref>see the argument put forth in Hovenkamp H (1999) ''Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law of Competition and Its Practice'', 2nd Ed, West Group, St. Paul, Minnesota. Unlike the authorities however, the courts take a dim view of the efficiencies defense.</ref> Another defense might be that a firm which is being taken over is about to fail or go insolvent, and taking it over leaves a no less competitive state than what would happen anyway.<ref>''Kali und Salz AG v. Commission'' ECR 499</ref> Mergers vertically in the market are rarely of concern, although in ''AOL/Time Warner''<ref>''Time Warner/AOL'' 4 CMLR 454, OJ L268</ref> the ] required that a joint venture with a competitor ] be ceased beforehand. The EU authorities have also focused lately on the effect of ]s, where companies acquire a large portfolio of related products, though without necessarily dominant shares in any individual market.<ref>e.g. ''Guinness/Grand Metropolitan'' 5 CMLR 760, OJ L288; Many in the US disapprove of this approach, see W. J. Kolasky, ''Conglomerate Mergers and Range Effects: It's a long way from Chicago to Brussels'' 9 November 2001, Address before George Mason University Symposium Washington, DC.</ref>


===Intellectual property, innovation and competition===
===Public sector regulation===
Competition law has become increasingly intertwined with ], such as ], ]s, ]s, ]s and in some jurisdictions ]s.<ref>{{cite report |url=http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/hearings/ip/222655.pdf |title=Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual Property Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition |date=April 2007 |publisher=U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission |access-date=9 October 2009 |archive-date=30 May 2009 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090530112144/http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/hearings/ip/222655.pdf |url-status=live }}</ref> It is believed that promotion of ] through enforcement of intellectual property rights may promote as well as limit competitiveness. The question rests on whether it is legal to acquire monopoly through accumulation of intellectual property rights. In which case, the judgment needs to decide between giving preference to intellectual property rights or to competitiveness:
{{main|Public services|Regulated market}}
* Should antitrust laws accord special treatment to intellectual property.
] is the U.K.'s rail industry watchdog]]
* Should intellectual rights be revoked or not granted when antitrust laws are violated.
Public sector industries, or industries which are by their nature providing a public service, are involved in competition law in many ways similar to private companies. Under EC law, Articles 86 and 87 create exceptions for the assured achievement of public sector service provision. Many industries, such as railways, telecommunications, electricity, gas, water and media have their own independent sector regulators. These government agencies are charged with ensuring that private providers carry out certain public service duties in line of ] goals. For instance, an electricity company may not be allowed to disconnect someone's supply merely because they have not paid their bills up to date, because that could leave a person in the dark and cold just because they are poor. Instead the electricity company would have to give the person a number of warnings and offer assistance until government welfare support kicks in.<ref>this is the general position in the UK.</ref>

Concerns also arise over anti-competitive effects and consequences due to:
* Intellectual properties that are collaboratively designed with consequence of violating antitrust laws (intentionally or otherwise).
* The further effects on competition when such properties are accepted into industry standards.
* Cross-licensing of intellectual property.
* Bundling of intellectual property rights to long-term business transactions or agreements to extend the market exclusiveness of intellectual property rights beyond their statutory duration.
* ], if they remain a secret, having an eternal length of life.

Some scholars suggest that a prize instead of patent would solve the problem of deadweight loss, when innovators got their reward from the prize, provided by the government or non-profit organization, rather than directly selling to the market, see ]. However, innovators may accept the prize only when it is at least as much as how much they earn from patent, which is a question difficult to determine.<ref>Suzanne Scotchmer: "Innovation and Incentives" the MIT press, 2004 (Chapter 2).</ref>


==See also== ==See also==
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
*]
*] * ]
* ]
* '']'' (book)
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
{{div col end}}


==Notes== ==Notes==
{{reflist|2}} {{Reflist}}


==References== ==References==
* ] (1978) ''The Antitrust Paradox'', New York Free Press ISBN 0465003699 * ] (1978) '']'', New York Free Press {{ISBN|0-465-00369-9}}
* _____ (1993). ''The Antitrust Paradox'' (second edition). New York: Free Press. {{ISBN|0-02-904456-1}}.
* ] (1999) ''The Business Community's Suicidal Impulse''
* ] (1999) , ''Cato Policy Report'', 21(2), pp.&nbsp;6–7 (scroll down & press '''+''').
* ] (1967) ''The New Industrial State'' * ] (1967) ''The New Industrial State''
* {{cite book |last1=Harrington |first1=Joseph E. |date=2008 |chapter=antitrust enforcement |editor-first1= Steven N. |editor-last1=Durlauf |editor-first2=Lawrence E. |editor-last2=Blume |title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics |edition= 2nd |url=http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_A000223&edition=current&q=antitrust&topicid=&result_number=1 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161221112306/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_A000223&edition=current&q=antitrust&topicid=&result_number=1 |archive-date= Dec 21, 2016 }}
* ] (2001) ''Antitrust Law'', 2nd ed., ISBN 9780226675763
* ] (1859) '']''
* ] (2007) ''Economic Analysis of Law'' 7th ed., ISBN 9780735563544
* ] (2001) ''Antitrust Law'', 2nd ed., {{ISBN|978-0-226-67576-3}}
* _____ (2007) ''Economic Analysis of Law'' 7th ed., {{ISBN|978-0-7355-6354-4}}
* Prosser, Tony (2005) ''The Limits of Competition Law'', ch.1 * Prosser, Tony (2005) ''The Limits of Competition Law'', ch.1
* {{citation|doi=10.1016/B0-08-043076-7/02299-3|chapter=Antitrust Policy|title=International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences|pages=553–560|year=2001|last1=Rubinfeld|first1=D.L.|isbn=9780080430768}}
* ] (1942) ''The Process of Creative Destruction'' * ] (1942) ''The Process of Creative Destruction''
* ] (1776) '']'' online
* ] (1976-7) "Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioural Foundations of Economic Theory," Philosophy and Public Affairs, 6 pp.317-44
* ], Alan Campbell and Neil Elles (1966) ''The Law of Restrictive Practices and Monopolies'', 2nd edition, London: Sweet and Maxwell {{LCCN|66070116}}
* ] (1985) "The Moral Standing of the Market," in Ethics and Economics, ed. Ellen Frankel Paul, Fred D. Miller, Jr and Jeffrey Paul, Oxford, Basil Blackwell, pp. 1-19;
* ] (1987) ''On Ethics and Economics'', Oxford, Basil Blackwell
* ] (1776) ''An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
* ] (1966) ''The Law of Restrictive Practices and Monopolies'', Sweet and Maxwell
* Whish, Richard (2003) ''Competition Law'', 5th Ed. Lexis Nexis Butterworths * Whish, Richard (2003) ''Competition Law'', 5th Ed. Lexis Nexis Butterworths
* https://anali.rs/the-klobuchar-bill-is-something-rotten-in-the-us-antitrust-legislative-reform/


==External links== ==Further reading==
* ''Competition Policy International'', {{ISSN|1554-6853}}, available at https://web.archive.org/web/20071127034131/http://www.globalcompetitionpolicy.org/
* Elhauge, Einer, Geradin, Damien (2007) ''Global Competition Law and Economics'', {{ISBN|1-84113-465-1}}
* Faull, Jonathan, Nikpay, Ali (eds) (2007) "Faull & Nikpay : The EC Law of Competition", {{ISBN|978-0-19-926929-7}}
* Georg Erber, Georg, Kooths, Stefan, '"Windows Vista: Securing Itself against Competition?'", in: ''DIW Weekly Report'', 2/2007, Vol.3, 7–14.
* Hylton, Keith N., et al., "".


== External links ==
*
*


{{Law}} {{Law}}
{{Competition law by country}}
{{Authority control}}


] ]
] ]
]
]
]
]

]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]

Latest revision as of 00:32, 18 December 2024

Law maintaining market competition "Antitrust" and "Anti-Monopoly Law" redirect here. For the film, see Antitrust (film). For the law specific to China, see Anti Monopoly Law of China.

Competition law
Basic concepts
Anti-competitive practices
Enforcement authorities and organizations

Competition law is the field of law that promotes or seeks to maintain market competition by regulating anti-competitive conduct by companies. Competition law is implemented through public and private enforcement. It is also known as antitrust law (or just antitrust), anti-monopoly law, and trade practices law; the act of pushing for antitrust measures or attacking monopolistic companies (known as trusts) is commonly known as trust busting.

The history of competition law reaches back to the Roman Empire. The business practices of market traders, guilds and governments have always been subject to scrutiny, and sometimes severe sanctions. Since the 20th century, competition law has become global. The two largest and most influential systems of competition regulation are United States antitrust law and European Union competition law. National and regional competition authorities across the world have formed international support and enforcement networks.

Modern competition law has historically evolved on a national level to promote and maintain fair competition in markets principally within the territorial boundaries of nation-states. National competition law usually does not cover activity beyond territorial borders unless it has significant effects at nation-state level. Countries may allow for extraterritorial jurisdiction in competition cases based on so-called "effects doctrine". The protection of international competition is governed by international competition agreements. In 1945, during the negotiations preceding the adoption of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) in 1947, limited international competition obligations were proposed within the Charter for an International Trade Organisation. These obligations were not included in GATT, but in 1994, with the conclusion of the Uruguay Round of GATT multilateral negotiations, the World Trade Organization (WTO) was created. The Agreement Establishing the WTO included a range of limited provisions on various cross-border competition issues on a sector specific basis. Competition law has failed to prevent monopolization of economic activity. "The global economy is dominated by a handful of powerful transnational corporations (TNCs). ... Only 737 top holders accumulate 80% of the control over the value of all ... network control is much more unequally distributed than wealth. In particular, the top ranked actors hold a control ten times bigger than what could be expected based on their wealth. ... Recent works have shown that when a financial network is very densely connected it is prone to systemic risk. Indeed, while in good times the network is seemingly robust, in bad times firms go into distress simultaneously. This knife-edge property was witnessed during the recent (2009) financial turmoil "

Starting Point

Competition law, or antitrust law, has three main elements:

  • prohibiting agreements or practices that restrict free trading and competition between business. This includes in particular the repression of free trade caused by cartels.
  • banning abusive behavior by a firm dominating a market, or anti-competitive practices that tend to lead to such a dominant position. Practices controlled in this way may include predatory pricing, tying, price gouging, and refusal to deal.
  • supervising the mergers and acquisitions of large corporations, including some joint ventures. Transactions that are considered to threaten the competitive process can be prohibited altogether, or approved subject to "remedies" such as an obligation to divest part of the merged business or to offer licenses or access to facilities to enable other businesses to continue competing.

Substance and practice of competition law varies from jurisdiction to jurisdiction. Protecting the interests of consumers (consumer welfare) and ensuring that entrepreneurs have an opportunity to compete in the market economy are often treated as important objectives. Competition law is closely connected with law on deregulation of access to markets, state aids and subsidies, the privatization of state owned assets and the establishment of independent sector regulators, among other market-oriented supply-side policies. In recent decades, competition law has been viewed as a way to provide better public services. Robert Bork argued that competition laws can produce adverse effects when they reduce competition by protecting inefficient competitors and when costs of legal intervention are greater than benefits for the consumers.

History

Main article: History of competition law

Roman legislation

An early example was enacted during the Roman Republic around 50 BC. To protect the grain trade, heavy fines were imposed on anyone directly, deliberately, and insidiously stopping supply ships. Under Diocletian in 301 A.D., an edict imposed the death penalty for anyone violating a tariff system, for example by buying up, concealing, or contriving the scarcity of everyday goods. More legislation came under the constitution of Zeno of 483 A.D., which can be traced into Florentine municipal laws of 1322 and 1325. This provided for confiscation of property and banishment for any trade combination or joint action of monopolies private or granted by the Emperor. Zeno rescinded all previously granted exclusive rights. Justinian I subsequently introduced legislation to pay officials to manage state monopolies.

Middle Ages

Legislation in England to control monopolies and restrictive practices was in force well before the Norman Conquest. The Domesday Book recorded that "foresteel" (i.e. forestalling, the practice of buying up goods before they reach market and then inflating the prices) was one of three forfeitures that King Edward the Confessor could carry out through England. But concern for fair prices also led to attempts to directly regulate the market. Under Henry III an act was passed in 1266 to fix bread and ale prices in correspondence with grain prices laid down by the assizes. Penalties for breach included amercements, pillory and tumbrel. A 14th-century statute labelled forestallers as "oppressors of the poor and the community at large and enemies of the whole country". Under King Edward III the Statute of Labourers of 1349 fixed wages of artificers and workmen and decreed that foodstuffs should be sold at reasonable prices. On top of existing penalties, the statute stated that overcharging merchants must pay the injured party double the sum he received, an idea that has been replicated in punitive treble damages under US antitrust law. Also under Edward III, the following statutory provision outlawed trade combination.

... we have ordained and established, that no merchant or other shall make Confederacy, Conspiracy, Coin, Imagination, or Murmur, or Evil Device in any point that may turn to the Impeachment, Disturbance, Defeating or Decay of the said Staples, or of anything that to them pertaineth, or may pertain.

In continental Europe, competition principles developed in lex mercatoria. Examples of legislation enshrining competition principles include the constitutiones juris metallici by Wenceslaus II of Bohemia between 1283 and 1305, condemning combination of ore traders increasing prices; the Municipal Statutes of Florence in 1322 and 1325 followed Zeno's legislation against state monopolies; and under Emperor Charles V in the Holy Roman Empire a law was passed "to prevent losses resulting from monopolies and improper contracts which many merchants and artisans made in the Netherlands". In 1553, Henry VIII of England reintroduced tariffs for foodstuffs, designed to stabilize prices, in the face of fluctuations in supply from overseas. So the legislation read here that whereas,

it is very hard and difficult to put certain prices to any such things ... prices of such victuals be many times enhanced and raised by the Greedy Covetousness and Appetites of the Owners of such Victuals, by occasion of ingrossing and regrating the same, more than upon any reasonable or just ground or cause, to the great damage and impoverishing of the King's subjects.

Around this time organizations representing various tradesmen and handicrafts people, known as guilds had been developing, and enjoyed many concessions and exemptions from the laws against monopolies. The privileges conferred were not abolished until the Municipal Corporations Act 1835.

Early competition law in Europe

Judge Coke in the 17th century thought that general restraints on trade were unreasonable.

The English common law of restraint of trade is the direct predecessor to modern competition law later developed in the US. It is based on the prohibition of agreements that ran counter to public policy, unless the reasonableness of an agreement could be shown. It effectively prohibited agreements designed to restrain another's trade. The 1414 Dyer's is the first known restrictive trade agreement to be examined under English common law. A dyer had given a bond not to exercise his trade in the same town as the plaintiff for six months but the plaintiff had promised nothing in return. On hearing the plaintiff's attempt to enforce this restraint, Hull J exclaimed, "per Dieu, if the plaintiff were here, he should go to prison until he had paid a fine to the King". The court denied the collection of a bond for the dyer's breach of agreement because the agreement was held to be a restriction on trade. English courts subsequently decided a range of cases which gradually developed competition related case law, which eventually were transformed into statute law.

Elizabeth I assured monopolies would not be abused in the early era of globalization.

Europe around the 16th century was changing quickly. The new world had just been opened up, overseas trade and plunder was pouring wealth through the international economy and attitudes among businessmen were shifting. In 1561 a system of Industrial Monopoly Licenses, similar to modern patents had been introduced into England. But by the reign of Queen Elizabeth I, the system was reputedly much abused and used merely to preserve privileges, encouraging nothing new in the way of innovation or manufacture. In response English courts developed case law on restrictive business practices. The statute followed the unanimous decision in Darcy v. Allein 1602, also known as the Case of Monopolies, of the King's Bench to declare void the sole right that Queen Elizabeth I had granted to Darcy to import playing cards into England. Darcy, an officer of the Queen's household, claimed damages for the defendant's infringement of this right. The court found the grant void and that three characteristics of monopoly were (1) price increases, (2) quality decrease, (3) the tendency to reduce artificers to idleness and beggary. This put an end to granted monopolies until King James I began to grant them again. In 1623 Parliament passed the Statute of Monopolies, which for the most part excluded patent rights from its prohibitions, as well as guilds. From King Charles I, through the civil war and to King Charles II, monopolies continued, especially useful for raising revenue. Then in 1684, in East India Company v. Sandys it was decided that exclusive rights to trade only outside the realm were legitimate, on the grounds that only large and powerful concerns could trade in the conditions prevailing overseas.

The development of early competition law in England and Europe progressed with the diffusion of writings such as The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith, who first established the concept of the market economy. At the same time industrialisation replaced the individual artisan, or group of artisans, with paid labourers and machine-based production. Commercial success became increasingly dependent on maximizing production while minimizing cost. Therefore, the size of a company became increasingly important, and a number of European countries responded by enacting laws to regulate large companies that restricted trade. Following the French Revolution in 1789 the law of 14–17 June 1791 declared agreements by members of the same trade that fixed the price of an industry or labour as void, unconstitutional, and hostile to liberty. Similarly, the Austrian Penal Code of 1852 established that "agreements ... to raise the price of a commodity ... to the disadvantage of the public should be punished as misdemeanours". Austria passed a law in 1870 abolishing the penalties, though such agreements remained void. However, in Germany laws clearly validated agreements between firms to raise prices. Throughout the 18th and 19th centuries, ideas that dominant private companies or legal monopolies could excessively restrict trade were further developed in Europe. However, as in the late 19th century, a depression spread through Europe, known as the Panic of 1873, ideas of competition lost favour, and it was felt that companies had to co-operate by forming cartels to withstand huge pressures on prices and profits.

Modern competition law

While the development of competition law stalled in Europe during the late 19th century, in 1889 Canada enacted what is considered the first competition statute of modern times. The Act for the Prevention and Suppression of Combinations formed in restraint of Trade was passed one year before the United States enacted the most famous legal statute on competition law, the Sherman Act of 1890. It was named after Senator John Sherman who argued that the Act "does not announce a new principle of law, but applies old and well recognised principles of common law".

United States antitrust

Main article: United States antitrust law
Senatorial Round House by Thomas Nast, 1886

The Sherman Act of 1890 attempted to outlaw the restriction of competition by large companies, who co-operated with rivals to fix outputs, prices and market shares, initially through pools and later through trusts. Trusts first appeared in the US railroads, where the capital requirement of railroad construction precluded competitive services in then scarcely settled territories. This trust allowed railroads to discriminate on rates imposed and services provided to consumers and businesses and to destroy potential competitors. Different trusts could be dominant in different industries. The Standard Oil Company trust in the 1880s controlled several markets, including the market in fuel oil, lead and whiskey. Vast numbers of citizens became sufficiently aware and publicly concerned about how the trusts negatively impacted them that the Act became a priority for both major parties. A primary concern of this act is that competitive markets themselves should provide the primary regulation of prices, outputs, interests and profits. Instead, the Act outlawed anticompetitive practices, codifying the common law restraint of trade doctrine. Rudolph Peritz has argued that competition law in the United States has evolved around two sometimes conflicting concepts of competition: first that of individual liberty, free of government intervention, and second a fair competitive environment free of excessive economic power. Since the enactment of the Sherman Act enforcement of competition law has been based on various economic theories adopted by Government.

Section 1 of the Sherman Act declared illegal "every contract, in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations." Section 2 prohibits monopolies, or attempts and conspiracies to monopolize. Following the enactment in 1890 US court applies these principles to business and markets. Courts applied the Act without consistent economic analysis until 1914, when it was complemented by the Clayton Act which specifically prohibited exclusive dealing agreements, particularly tying agreements and interlocking directorates, and mergers achieved by purchasing stock. From 1915 onwards the rule of reason analysis was frequently applied by courts to competition cases. However, the period was characterized by the lack of competition law enforcement. From 1936 to 1972 courts' application of antitrust law was dominated by the structure-conduct-performance paradigm of the Harvard School. From 1973 to 1991, the enforcement of antitrust law was based on efficiency explanations as the Chicago School became dominant, and through legal writings such as Judge Robert Bork's book The Antitrust Paradox. Since 1992 game theory has frequently been used in antitrust cases.

With the Hart–Scott–Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976, mergers and acquisitions came into additional scrutiny from U.S. regulators. Under the act, parties must make a pre-merger notification to the U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission prior to the completion of a transaction. As of February 2, 2021, the FTC reduced the Hart-Scott-Rodino reporting threshold to $92 million in combined assets for the transaction.

European Union law

Main article: European Union competition law

Competition law gained new recognition in Europe in the inter-war years, with Germany enacting its first anti-cartel law in 1923 and Sweden and Norway adopting similar laws in 1925 and 1926 respectively. However, with the Great Depression of 1929 competition law disappeared from Europe and was revived following the Second World War when the United Kingdom and Germany, following pressure from the United States, became the first European countries to adopt fully fledged competition laws. At a regional level EU competition law has its origins in the European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC) agreement between France, Italy, Belgium, the Netherlands, Luxembourg and Germany in 1951 following the Second World War. The agreement aimed to prevent Germany from re-establishing dominance in the production of coal and steel as it was felt that this dominance had contributed to the outbreak of the war. Article 65 of the agreement banned cartels and article 66 made provisions for concentrations, or mergers, and the abuse of a dominant position by companies. This was the first time that competition law principles were included in a plurilateral regional agreement and established the trans-European model of competition law. In 1957 competition rules were included in the Treaty of Rome, also known as the EC Treaty, which established the European Economic Community (EEC). The Treaty of Rome established the enactment of competition law as one of the main aims of the EEC through the "institution of a system ensuring that competition in the common market is not distorted". The two central provisions on EU competition law on companies were established in article 85, which prohibited anti-competitive agreements, subject to some exemptions, and article 86 prohibiting the abuse of dominant position. The treaty also established principles on competition law for member states, with article 90 covering public undertakings, and article 92 making provisions on state aid. Regulations on mergers were not included as member states could not establish consensus on the issue at the time.

Today, the Treaty of Lisbon prohibits anti-competitive agreements in Article 101(1), including price fixing. According to Article 101(2) any such agreements are automatically void. Article 101(3) establishes exemptions, if the collusion is for distributional or technological innovation, gives consumers a "fair share" of the benefit and does not include unreasonable restraints that risk eliminating competition anywhere (or compliant with the general principle of European Union law of proportionality). Article 102 prohibits the abuse of dominant position, such as price discrimination and exclusive dealing. Regulation 139/2004/EC governs mergers between firms. The general test is whether a concentration (i.e. merger or acquisition) with a community dimension (i.e. affects a number of EU member states) might significantly impede effective competition. Articles 106 and 107 provide that member state's right to deliver public services may not be obstructed, but that otherwise public enterprises must adhere to the same competition principles as companies. Article 107 lays down a general rule that the state may not aid or subsidize private parties in distortion of free competition and provides exemptions for charities, regional development objectives and in the event of a natural disaster.

Leading ECJ cases on competition law include Consten & Grundig v Commission and United Brands v Commission.

India

Main articles: The Competition Act, 2002 and Competition Commission of India

India responded positively by opening up its economy by removing controls during the Economic liberalisation. In quest of increasing the efficiency of the nation's economy, the Government of India acknowledged the Liberalization Privatization Globalization era. As a result, Indian market faces competition from within and outside the country. This led to the need of a strong legislation to dispense justice in commercial matters and the Competition Act, 2002 was passed. The history of competition law in India dates back to the 1960s when the first competition law, namely the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act (MRTP) was enacted in 1969. But after the economic reforms in 1991, this legislation was found to be obsolete in many aspects and as a result, a new competition law in the form of the Competition Act, 2002 was enacted in 2003. The Competition Commission of India, is the quasi judicial body established for enforcing provisions of the Competition Act.

China

Main article: Anti Monopoly Law of China

The Anti Monopoly Law of China came into effect in 2008. For years, it was enforced by three different branches of government, but since 2018 its enforcement has been the responsibility of the State Administration for Market Regulation. The People's Daily reported that the law had generated 11 billion RMB of penalties between 2008 and 2018.

International expansion

By 2008, 111 countries had enacted competition laws, which is more than 50 percent of countries with a population exceeding 80,000 people. 81 of the 111 countries had adopted their competition laws in the past 20 years, signaling the spread of competition law following the collapse of the Soviet Union and the expansion of the European Union. Currently competition authorities of many states closely co-operate, on everyday basis, with foreign counterparts in their enforcement efforts, also in such key area as information / evidence sharing.

In many of Asia's developing countries, including India, Competition law is considered a tool to stimulate economic growth. In Korea and Japan, the competition law prevents certain forms of conglomerates. In addition, competition law has promoted fairness in China and Indonesia as well as international integration in Vietnam. Hong Kong's Competition Ordinance came into force in the year 2015.

ASEAN member states

As part of the creation of the ASEAN Economic Community, the member states of the Association of South-East Asian Nations (ASEAN) pledged to enact competition laws and policies by the end of 2015. Today, all ten member states have general competition legislation in place. While there remains differences between regimes (for example, over merger control notification rules, or leniency policies for whistle-blowers), and it is unlikely that there will be a supranational competition authority for ASEAN (akin to the European Union), there is a clear trend towards increase in infringement investigations or decisions on cartel enforcement.

Enforcement

See also: World Trade Organization and International Competition Network
There is considerable controversy among WTO members, in green and blue, whether competition law should form part of the agreements.

Competition law is enforced at the national level through competition authorities, as well as private enforcement. The United States Supreme Court explained:

Every violation of the antitrust laws is a blow to the free-enterprise system envisaged by Congress. This system depends on strong competition for its health and vigor, and strong competition depends, in turn, on compliance with antitrust legislation. In enacting these laws, Congress had many means at its disposal to penalize violators. It could have, for example, required violators to compensate federal, state, and local governments for the estimated damage to their respective economies caused by the violations. But, this remedy was not selected. Instead, Congress chose to permit all persons to sue to recover three times their actual damages every time they were injured in their business or property by an antitrust violation.

In the European Union, the so-called "Modernisation Regulation", Regulation 1/2003, established that the European Commission was no longer the only body capable of public enforcement of European Union competition law. This was done to facilitate quicker resolution of competition-related inquiries. In 2005 the Commission issued a Green Paper on Damages actions for the breach of the EC antitrust rules, which suggested ways of making private damages claims against cartels easier.

Some EU Member States enforce their competition laws with criminal sanctions. As analysed by Whelan, these types of sanctions engender a number of significant theoretical, legal and practical challenges.

Antitrust administration and legislation can be seen as a balance between:

  • guidelines which are clear and specific to the courts, regulators and business but leave little room for discretion that prevents the application of laws from resulting in unintended consequences.
  • guidelines which are broad, hence allowing administrators to sway between improving economic outcomes versus succumbing to political policies to redistribute wealth.

Chapter 5 of the post-war Havana Charter contained an Antitrust code but this was never incorporated into the WTO's forerunner, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1947. Office of Fair Trading Director and Richard Whish wrote sceptically that it "seems unlikely at the current stage of its development that the WTO will metamorphose into a global competition authority". Despite that, at the ongoing Doha round of trade talks for the World Trade Organization, discussion includes the prospect of competition law enforcement moving up to a global level. While it is incapable of enforcement itself, the newly established International Competition Network (ICN) is a way for national authorities to coordinate their own enforcement activities.

Theory

Main article: Competition law theory

Classical perspective

See also: Classical economics

Under the doctrine of laissez-faire, antitrust is seen as unnecessary as competition is viewed as a long-term dynamic process where firms compete against each other for market dominance. In some markets, a firm may successfully dominate, but it is because of superior skill or innovativeness. However, according to laissez-faire theorists, when it tries to raise prices to take advantage of its monopoly position it creates profitable opportunities for others to compete. A process of creative destruction begins which erodes the monopoly. Therefore, government should not try to break up monopoly but should allow the market to work.

John Stuart Mill believed the restraint of trade doctrine was justified to preserve liberty and competition.

The classical perspective on competition was that certain agreements and business practice could be an unreasonable restraint on the individual liberty of tradespeople to carry on their livelihoods. Restraints were judged as permissible or not by courts as new cases appeared and in the light of changing business circumstances. Hence the courts found specific categories of agreement, specific clauses, to fall foul of their doctrine on economic fairness, and they did not contrive an overarching conception of market power. Earlier theorists like Adam Smith rejected any monopoly power on this basis.

A monopoly granted either to an individual or to a trading company has the same effect as a secret in trade or manufactures. The monopolists, by keeping the market constantly under-stocked, by never fully supplying the effectual demand, sell their commodities much above the natural price, and raise their emoluments, whether they consist in wages or profit, greatly above their natural rate.

In The Wealth of Nations (1776) Adam Smith also pointed out the cartel problem, but did not advocate specific legal measures to combat them.

People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices. It is impossible indeed to prevent such meetings, by any law which either could be executed, or would be consistent with liberty and justice. But though the law cannot hinder people of the same trade from sometimes assembling together, it ought to do nothing to facilitate such assemblies; much less to render them necessary.

By the latter half of the 19th century, it had become clear that large firms had become a fact of the market economy. John Stuart Mill's approach was laid down in his treatise On Liberty (1859).

Again, trade is a social act. Whoever undertakes to sell any description of goods to the public, does what affects the interest of other persons, and of society in general; and thus his conduct, in principle, comes within the jurisdiction of society... both the cheapness and the good quality of commodities are most effectually provided for by leaving the producers and sellers perfectly free, under the sole check of equal freedom to the buyers for supplying themselves elsewhere. This is the so-called doctrine of Free Trade, which rests on grounds different from, though equally solid with, the principle of individual liberty asserted in this Essay. Restrictions on trade, or on production for purposes of trade, are indeed restraints; and all restraint, qua restraint, is an evil...

Neo-classical synthesis

See also: Neoclassical synthesis
Paul Samuelson, author of the 20th century's most successful economics text, combined mathematical models and Keynesian macroeconomic intervention. He advocated the general success of the market but backed the American government's antitrust policies.

After Mill, there was a shift in economic theory, which emphasized a more precise and theoretical model of competition. A simple neo-classical model of free markets holds that production and distribution of goods and services in competitive free markets maximizes social welfare. This model assumes that new firms can freely enter markets and compete with existing firms, or to use legal language, there are no barriers to entry. By this term economists mean something very specific, that competitive free markets deliver allocative, productive and dynamic efficiency. Allocative efficiency is also known as Pareto efficiency after the Italian economist Vilfredo Pareto and means that resources in an economy over the long run will go precisely to those who are willing and able to pay for them. Because rational producers will keep producing and selling, and buyers will keep buying up to the last marginal unit of possible output – or alternatively rational producers will be reduce their output to the margin at which buyers will buy the same amount as produced – there is no waste, the greatest number wants of the greatest number of people become satisfied and utility is perfected because resources can no longer be reallocated to make anyone better off without making someone else worse off; society has achieved allocative efficiency. Productive efficiency simply means that society is making as much as it can. Free markets are meant to reward those who work hard, and therefore those who will put society's resources towards the frontier of its possible production. Dynamic efficiency refers to the idea that business which constantly competes must research, create and innovate to keep its share of consumers. This traces to Austrian-American political scientist Joseph Schumpeter's notion that a "perennial gale of creative destruction" is ever sweeping through capitalist economies, driving enterprise at the market's mercy. This led Schumpeter to argue that monopolies did not need to be broken up (as with Standard Oil) because the next gale of economic innovation would do the same.

Contrasting with the allocatively, productively and dynamically efficient market model are monopolies, oligopolies, and cartels. When only one or a few firms exist in the market, and there is no credible threat of the entry of competing firms, prices rise above the competitive level, to either a monopolistic or oligopolistic equilibrium price. Production is also decreased, further decreasing social welfare by creating a deadweight loss. Sources of this market power are said to include the existence of externalities, barriers to entry of the market, and the free rider problem. Markets may fail to be efficient for a variety of reasons, so the exception of competition law's intervention to the rule of laissez faire is justified if government failure can be avoided. Orthodox economists fully acknowledge that perfect competition is seldom observed in the real world, and so aim for what is called "workable competition". This follows the theory that if one cannot achieve the ideal, then go for the second best option by using the law to tame market operation where it can.

Chicago school

Robert Bork
See also: Chicago school of economics and Neoclassical economics

A group of economists and lawyers, who are largely associated with the University of Chicago, advocate an approach to competition law guided by the proposition that some actions that were originally considered to be anticompetitive could actually promote competition. The U.S. Supreme Court has used the Chicago school approach in several recent cases. One view of the Chicago school approach to antitrust is found in United States Circuit Court of Appeals Judge Richard Posner's books Antitrust Law and Economic Analysis of Law.

Robert Bork was highly critical of court decisions on United States antitrust law in a series of law review articles and his book The Antitrust Paradox. Bork argued that both the original intention of antitrust laws and economic efficiency was the pursuit only of consumer welfare, the protection of competition rather than competitors. Furthermore, only a few acts should be prohibited, namely cartels that fix prices and divide markets, mergers that create monopolies, and dominant firms pricing predatorily, while allowing such practices as vertical agreements and price discrimination on the grounds that it did not harm consumers. Running through the different critiques of US antitrust policy is the common theme that government interference in the operation of free markets does more harm than good. "The only cure for bad theory," writes Bork, "is better theory." Harvard Law School professor Philip Areeda, who favours more aggressive antitrust policy, in at least one Supreme Court case challenged Robert Bork's preference for non-intervention.

Practice

Collusion and cartels

Main articles: Collusion and Cartel
Scottish Enlightenment philosopher Adam Smith was an early enemy of cartels.

Dominance and monopoly

Main articles: Dominance (economics) and Monopoly
The economist's depiction of deadweight loss to efficiency that monopolies cause

When firms hold large market shares, consumers risk paying higher prices and getting lower quality products than compared to competitive markets. However, the existence of a very high market share does not always mean consumers are paying excessive prices since the threat of new entrants to the market can restrain a high-market-share firm's price increases. Competition law does not make merely having a monopoly illegal, but rather abusing the power that a monopoly may confer, for instance through exclusionary practices. Market dominance is connected with decreased innovation and increased political connectedness.

First, it is necessary to determine whether a firm is dominant, or whether it behaves "to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors, customers and ultimately of its consumer". Under EU law, very large market shares raise a presumption that a firm is dominant, which may be rebuttable. If a firm has a dominant position, then there is "a special responsibility not to allow its conduct to impair competition on the common market". Similarly as with collusive conduct, market shares are determined with reference to the particular market in which the firm and product in question is sold. Then although the lists are seldom closed, certain categories of abusive conduct are usually prohibited under the country's legislation. For instance, limiting production at a shipping port by refusing to raise expenditure and update technology could be abusive. Tying one product into the sale of another can be considered abuse too, being restrictive of consumer choice and depriving competitors of outlets. This was the alleged case in Microsoft v. Commission leading to an eventual fine of million for including its Windows Media Player with the Microsoft Windows platform. A refusal to supply a facility which is essential for all businesses attempting to compete to use can constitute an abuse. One example was in a case involving a medical company named Commercial Solvents. When it set up its own rival in the tuberculosis drugs market, Commercial Solvents were forced to continue supplying a company named Zoja with the raw materials for the drug. Zoja was the only market competitor, so without the court forcing supply, all competition would have been eliminated.

Forms of abuse relating directly to pricing include price exploitation. It is difficult to prove at what point a dominant firm's prices become "exploitative" and this category of abuse is rarely found. In one case however, a French funeral service was found to have demanded exploitative prices, and this was justified on the basis that prices of funeral services outside the region could be compared. A more tricky issue is predatory pricing. This is the practice of dropping prices of a product so much that one's smaller competitors cannot cover their costs and fall out of business. The Chicago school considers predatory pricing to be unlikely. However, in France Telecom SA v. Commission a broadband internet company was forced to pay $13.9 million for dropping its prices below its own production costs. It had "no interest in applying such prices except that of eliminating competitors" and was being cross-subsidized to capture the lion's share of a booming market. One last category of pricing abuse is price discrimination. An example of this could be a company offering rebates to industrial customers who export their sugar, but not to customers who are selling their goods in the same market.

Example

According to The World Bank's "Republic of Armenia Accumulation, Competition, and Connectivity Global Competition" report which was published in 2013, the Global Competitiveness Index suggests that Armenia ranks lowest among ECA (Europe and Central Asia) countries in the effectiveness of anti-monopoly policy and the intensity of competition. This low ranking somehow explains the low employment and low incomes in Armenia.

Mergers and acquisitions

Main article: Mergers and acquisitions

A merger or acquisition involves, from a competition law perspective, the concentration of economic power in the hands of fewer than before. This usually means that one firm buys out the shares of another. The reasons for oversight of economic concentrations by the state are the same as the reasons to restrict firms who abuse a position of dominance, only that regulation of mergers and acquisitions attempts to deal with the problem before it arises, ex ante prevention of market dominance. In the United States merger regulation began under the Clayton Act, and in the European Union, under the Merger Regulation 139/2004 (known as the "ECMR"). Competition law requires that firms proposing to merge gain authorization from the relevant government authority. The theory behind mergers is that transaction costs can be reduced compared to operating on an open market through bilateral contracts. Concentrations can increase economies of scale and scope. However often firms take advantage of their increase in market power, their increased market share and decreased number of competitors, which can adversely affect the deal that consumers get. Merger control is about predicting what the market might be like, not knowing and making a judgment. Hence the central provision under EU law asks whether a concentration would, if it went ahead, "significantly impede effective competition... in particular as a result of the creation or strengthening off a dominant position..." and the corresponding provision under US antitrust states similarly,

No person shall acquire, directly or indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share capital... of the assets of one or more persons engaged in commerce or in any activity affecting commerce, where... the effect of such acquisition, of such stocks or assets, or of the use of such stock by the voting or granting of proxies or otherwise, may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly.

What amounts to a substantial lessening of, or significant impediment to competition is usually answered through empirical study. The market shares of the merging companies can be assessed and added, although this kind of analysis only gives rise to presumptions, not conclusions. The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index is used to calculate the "density" of the market, or what concentration exists. Aside from the maths, it is important to consider the product in question and the rate of technical innovation in the market. A further problem of collective dominance, or oligopoly through "economic links" can arise, whereby the new market becomes more conducive to collusion. It is relevant how transparent a market is, because a more concentrated structure could mean firms can coordinate their behavior more easily, whether firms can deploy deterrents and whether firms are safe from a reaction by their competitors and consumers. The entry of new firms to the market, and any barriers that they might encounter should be considered. If firms are shown to be creating an uncompetitive concentration, in the US they can still argue that they create efficiencies enough to outweigh any detriment, and similar reference to "technical and economic progress" is mentioned in Art. 2 of the ECMR. Another defense might be that a firm which is being taken over is about to fail or go insolvent, and taking it over leaves a no less competitive state than what would happen anyway. Mergers vertically in the market are rarely of concern, although in AOL/Time Warner the European Commission required that a joint venture with a competitor Bertelsmann be ceased beforehand. The EU authorities have also focused lately on the effect of conglomerate mergers, where companies acquire a large portfolio of related products, though without necessarily dominant shares in any individual market.

Intellectual property, innovation and competition

Competition law has become increasingly intertwined with intellectual property, such as copyright, trademarks, patents, industrial design rights and in some jurisdictions trade secrets. It is believed that promotion of innovation through enforcement of intellectual property rights may promote as well as limit competitiveness. The question rests on whether it is legal to acquire monopoly through accumulation of intellectual property rights. In which case, the judgment needs to decide between giving preference to intellectual property rights or to competitiveness:

  • Should antitrust laws accord special treatment to intellectual property.
  • Should intellectual rights be revoked or not granted when antitrust laws are violated.

Concerns also arise over anti-competitive effects and consequences due to:

  • Intellectual properties that are collaboratively designed with consequence of violating antitrust laws (intentionally or otherwise).
  • The further effects on competition when such properties are accepted into industry standards.
  • Cross-licensing of intellectual property.
  • Bundling of intellectual property rights to long-term business transactions or agreements to extend the market exclusiveness of intellectual property rights beyond their statutory duration.
  • Trade secrets, if they remain a secret, having an eternal length of life.

Some scholars suggest that a prize instead of patent would solve the problem of deadweight loss, when innovators got their reward from the prize, provided by the government or non-profit organization, rather than directly selling to the market, see Millennium Prize Problems. However, innovators may accept the prize only when it is at least as much as how much they earn from patent, which is a question difficult to determine.

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Li, Rita Yi Man; Li, Yi Lut (1 June 2013). "The Role of Competition Law(Act): An Asian Perspective". SSRN 2281756.
  2. ^ Taylor, Martyn D. (2006). International competition law: a new dimension for the WTO?. Cambridge University Press. p. 1. ISBN 978-0-521-86389-6. Archived from the original on 14 December 2022. Retrieved 22 March 2023.
  3. Cartel Damage Claims (CDC). "Cartel Damage Claims (CDC)". www.carteldamageclaims.com/. Archived from the original on 12 April 2024. Retrieved 23 June 2014.
  4. "Antitrust: Overview – Competition – European Commission". ec.europa.eu. Archived from the original on 5 February 2020. Retrieved 27 June 2017.
  5. "Trust Busting - Ohio History Central". ohiohistorycentral.org. Archived from the original on 21 February 2023. Retrieved 21 February 2023.
  6. Topping, Simon; Tweedale, Patrick. "UAE Competition Law: New Regulations and Potential Effect on M&A Transactions". Transaction Advisors. ISSN 2329-9134. Archived from the original on 23 June 2017. Retrieved 25 September 2015.
  7. JG Castel, 'The Extraterritorial Effects of Antitrust Laws' (1983) 179 Recueil des Cours 9
  8. Taylor, Martyn D. (2006). International competition law: a new dimension for the WTO?. Cambridge University Press. p. 2. ISBN 978-0-521-86389-6. Archived from the original on 14 December 2022. Retrieved 22 March 2023.
  9. Vitali, Stefania; Glattfelder, James B.; Battiston, Stefano (2011). "The Network of Global Corporate Control". PLOS ONE. 6 (10): e25995. arXiv:1107.5728. Bibcode:2011PLoSO...625995V. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0025995. PMC 3202517. PMID 22046252.
  10. see, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development's Regulation and Sectors Archived 6 October 2021 at the Wayback Machine page.
  11. Bork (1993), p. 56
  12. This is Julius Caesar's time according to Babled in De La Cure Annone chez le Romains.
  13. ^ Wilberforce (1966) p. 20
  14. Wilberforce (1966) p. 22
  15. ^ Wilberforce (1966) p. 21
  16. Pollock and Maitland, History of English Law Vol. II, 453
  17. 51 & 52 Hen. 3, Stat. 1
  18. 51 & 52 Hen. 3, Stat. 6
  19. Wilberforce (1966) p. 23
  20. 23 Edw. 3.
  21. 27 Edw. 3, Stat. 2, c. 25
  22. 25 Hen. 8, c. 2.
  23. "... the modern common law of England passed directly into the legislation and thereafter into the judge-made law of the United States." Wilberforce (1966) p. 7
  24. (1414) 2 Hen. 5, 5 Pl. 26
  25. ^ Papadopoulos, Anestis S (2010). The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy. Cambridge University Press. p. 7. ISBN 978-0-521-19646-8. Archived from the original on 12 April 2024. Retrieved 22 October 2020.
  26. according to William Searle Holdsworth, 4 Holdsworth, 3rd ed., Chap. 4 p. 346
  27. (1602) 11 Co. Rep. 84b
  28. For example one John Manley paid p.a. from 1654 to the Crown for a tender on the "postage of letters both inland and foreign" Wilberforce (1966) p. 18
  29. (1685) 10 St. Tr. 371
  30. Papadopoulos, Anestis S (2010). The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy. Cambridge University Press. pp. 8–9. ISBN 978-0-521-19646-8. Archived from the original on 12 April 2024. Retrieved 22 October 2020.
  31. ^ Papadopoulos, Anestis S (2010). The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy. Cambridge University Press. pp. 9–10. ISBN 978-0-521-19646-8. Archived from the original on 12 April 2024. Retrieved 22 October 2020.
  32. Papadopoulos, Anestis S (2010). The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy. Cambridge University Press. p. 11. ISBN 978-0-521-19646-8. Archived from the original on 12 April 2024. Retrieved 22 October 2020.
  33. Papadopoulos, Anestis S (2010). The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy. Cambridge University Press. p. 12. ISBN 978-0-521-19646-8. Archived from the original on 12 April 2024. Retrieved 22 October 2020.
  34. Papadopoulos, Anestis S (2010). The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy. Cambridge University Press. pp. 11–12. ISBN 978-0-521-19646-8. Archived from the original on 12 April 2024. Retrieved 22 October 2020.
  35. "FTC Announces Reduced Hart-Scott-Rodino Act Thresholds For 2021". Seyfarth Shaw - FTC Announces Reduced Hart-Scott-Rodino Act Thresholds For 2021. Archived from the original on 12 April 2021. Retrieved 12 April 2021.
  36. Papadopoulos, Anestis S (2010). The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy. Cambridge University Press. pp. 12–13. ISBN 978-0-521-19646-8.
  37. Papadopoulos, Anestis S (2010). The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy. Cambridge University Press. p. 14. ISBN 978-0-521-19646-8.
  38. Vandenborre, Ingrid; Goetz, Thorsten; Dionnet, Stephane. "EU Nonmerger Antitrust Enforcement Gets Stricter". Transaction Advisors. ISSN 2329-9134. Archived from the original on 23 June 2017. Retrieved 29 April 2015.
  39. Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of 20 January 2004 on the control of concentrations between undertakings (the EC Merger Regulation)
  40. Warrier VS, Conflict between Competition Law and Intellectual Property Rights Citation: 2010 (1) LW 2 Archived 10 September 2020 at the Wayback Machine The Lex-Warrier: Online Law Journal, ISSN 2319-8338
  41. "CCI formation". CCI. Archived from the original on 14 April 2021. Retrieved 4 January 2013.
  42. "China's updated Anti-monopoly Law criticised for not doing enough". South China Morning Post. 9 January 2020. Archived from the original on 27 October 2022. Retrieved 27 October 2022.
  43. Papadopoulos, Anestis S (2010). The International Dimension of EU Competition Law and Policy. Cambridge University Press. p. 15. ISBN 978-0-521-19646-8.
  44. Marek Martyniszyn, Inter-Agency Evidence Sharing in Competition Law Enforcement Archived 12 April 2024 at the Wayback Machine, 19(1) International Journal of Evidence and Proof 11 (2015)
  45. "Competition Commission – The Competition Ordinance (Cap 619)". www.compcomm.hk. Archived from the original on 12 June 2017. Retrieved 27 June 2017.
  46. "Overview". ASEAN | ONE VISION ONE IDENTITY ONE COMMUNITY. Archived from the original on 28 February 2018. Retrieved 28 February 2018.
  47. "Competition Law in ASEAN: Where Are We Now, And Where Are We Headed?". Conventus Law. 19 June 2016. Archived from the original on 28 February 2018. Retrieved 28 February 2018.
  48. "EU Competition Law: A Roadmap for ASEAN?". EU Centre in Singapore. Archived from the original on 28 February 2018. Retrieved 28 February 2018.
  49. "A new era for competition law in the ASEAN region". Expert Guides. Archived from the original on 28 February 2018. Retrieved 28 February 2018.
  50. Hawaii v. Standard Oil Co. of California, 405 U.S. 251 (1972), 262.
  51. Office of Fair Trading, Modernisation: Understanding competition law Archived 18 May 2023 at the Wayback Machine, p. 4, published December 2004, accessed 27 November 2023
  52. Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 of 16 December 2002 on the implementation of the rules on competition laid down in Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty
  53. Green Paper - Damages actions for breach of the EC antitrust rules {SEC(2005) 1732}
  54. "European Commission – PRESS RELEASES – Press release – European Commission Green Paper on damages actions for breach of EC Treaty antitrust rules – frequently asked questions". europa.eu. Archived from the original on 1 May 2012. Retrieved 27 June 2017.
  55. Peter Whelan, The Criminalization of European Cartel Enforcement: Theoretical, Legal and Practical Challenges Archived 16 November 2015 at the Wayback Machine, Oxford University Press, 2014
  56. McEwin, R Ian (2003). "COMPETITION LAW IN A SMALL OPEN ECONOMY". University of New South Wales Law Journal. 15: 246. Archived from the original on 25 February 2021. Retrieved 9 October 2009.
  57. see a speech by Wood, The Internationalisation of Antitrust Law: Options for the Future 3 February 1995, at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/future.txt Archived 10 February 2005 at the Wayback Machine
  58. Whish (2003) p. 448
  59. see, http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/ Archived 20 April 2021 at the Wayback Machine
  60. Campbell R. McConnell, Stanley L. Brue. Economics: Principles, Problems, and Policies. McGraw-Hill Professional, 2005. pp. 601–02
  61. Smith (1776) Book I, Chapter 7, para 26
  62. Smith (1776) Book I, Chapter 10, para 82
  63. Mill (1859) Chapter V, para 4
  64. for one of the opposite views, see Kenneth Galbraith, The New Industrial State (1967)
  65. Joseph Schumpeter, The Process of Creative Destruction (1942)
  66. Whish (2003), p. 14.
  67. Clark, John M. (1940). "Towards a Concept of Workable Competition". American Economic Review. 30 (2): 241–56. JSTOR 1807048.
  68. c.f. Lipsey, R. G.; Lancaster, Kelvin (1956). "The General Theory of Second Best". Review of Economic Studies. 24 (1): 11–32. doi:10.2307/2296233. JSTOR 2296233.
  69. Hovenkamp, Herbert (1985). "Antitrust Policy after Chicago" (PDF). Michigan Law Review. 84 (2). The Michigan Law Review Association: 213–84. doi:10.2307/1289065. JSTOR 1289065. S2CID 153691408. Archived (PDF) from the original on 12 April 2024. Retrieved 12 December 2023.
  70. Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977); Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979); National Collegiate Athletic Assn. v. Board of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85 (1984); Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447 (1993); State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3 (1997); Verizon v. Trinko, 540 U.S. 398 (2004); Leegin Creative Leather Products Inc. v. PSKS Inc., 551 U.S. ___ (2007).
  71. Posner, R. (2001). Antitrust Law (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0-226-67576-3.
  72. Posner, R. (2007). Economic Analysis of Law (7th ed.). Austin, TX: Wolters Kluwer Law & Business. ISBN 978-0-7355-6354-4.
  73. Bork, Robert H. (1978). The Antitrust Paradox. New York: Free Press. ISBN 978-0-465-00369-3.
  74. ^ Bork (1978), p. 405.
  75. Bork (1978), p. 406.
  76. Easterbrook, Frank (1984). "The Limits of Antitrust". Texas Law Review. 63: 1. ISSN 0040-4411.
  77. Brooke Group v. Williamson, 509 U.S. 209 (1993).
  78. Akcigit, Ufuk; Baslandze, Salomé; Lotti, Francesca (2023). "Connecting to Power: Political Connections, Innovation, and Firm Dynamics" (PDF). Econometrica. 91 (2): 529–564. doi:10.3982/ECTA18338. Archived (PDF) from the original on 8 May 2020.
  79. C-27/76 United Brands Continental BV v. Commission ECR 207
  80. C-85/76 Hoffmann-La Roche & Co AG v. Commission ECR 461
  81. AKZO
  82. Michelin
  83. Continental Can
  84. Art. 82 (b) Porto di Genova
  85. Order of the President of the Court of First Instance of 22 December 2004. Microsoft Corp. v Commission of the European Communities. Proceedings for interim relief - Article 82 EC. Case T-201/04 R, ECLI:EU:T:2004:372
  86. Commercial Solvents
  87. Judgment of the Court (Sixth Chamber) of 4 May 1988. Corinne Bodson v SA Pompes funèbres des régions libérées. Reference for a preliminary ruling: Cour de cassation - France. Competition - Funeral services - Exclusive special rights. Case 30/87., ECLI:EU:C:1988:225
  88. see, e.g. Posner (1998) p. 332; "While it is possible to imagine cases in which predatory pricing would be a rational stragy, it should be apparent by now why confirmed cases of it are rare."
  89. Case T-340/03 France Telecom SA v. Commission
  90. AKZO para 71
  91. in the EU under Article 82(2)c)
  92. Irish Sugar
  93. The World Bank. Republic of Armenia Accumulation, Competition, and Connectivity Global Competition (PDF). The World Bank. Archived (PDF) from the original on 7 May 2019. Retrieved 7 May 2019.
  94. Under EC law, a concentration is where a "change of control on a lasting basis results from (a) the merger of two or more previously independent undertakings... (b) the acquisition... if direct or indirect control of the whole or parts of one or more other undertakings". Art. 3(1), Regulation 139/2004, the European Community Merger Regulation
  95. In the case of Gencor Ltd v. Commission ECR II-753 the EU Court of First Instance wrote merger control is there "to avoid the establishment of market structures which may create or strengthen a dominant position and not need to control directly possible abuses of dominant positions"
  96. The authority for the Commission to pass this regulation is found under Art. 83 TEC
  97. Coase, Ronald H. (November 1937). "The Nature of the Firm" (PDF). Economica. 4 (16): 386–405. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x. Archived from the original (PDF) on 13 January 2007. Retrieved 10 February 2007.
  98. Art. 2(3) Reg. 129/2005
  99. Clayton Act Section 7, codified at 15 U.S.C. § 18
  100. see, for instance para 17, Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers (2004/C 31/03)
  101. C-68/94 France v. Commission ECR I-1375, para. 219
  102. Italian Flat Glass ECR ii-1403
  103. T-342/99 Airtours plc v. Commission ECR II-2585, para 62
  104. Mannesmann, Vallourec and Ilva CMLR 529, OJ L102 21 April 1994
  105. see the argument put forth in Hovenkamp H (1999) Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law of Competition and Its Practice, 2nd Ed, West Group, St. Paul, Minnesota. Unlike the authorities however, the courts take a dim view of the efficiencies defense.
  106. Kali und Salz AG v. Commission ECR 499
  107. Time Warner/AOL 4 CMLR 454, OJ L268
  108. e.g. Guinness/Grand Metropolitan 5 CMLR 760, OJ L288; Many in the US disapprove of this approach, see W. J. Kolasky, Conglomerate Mergers and Range Effects: It's a long way from Chicago to Brussels 9 November 2001, Address before George Mason University Symposium Washington, DC.
  109. Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual Property Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition (PDF) (Report). U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission. April 2007. Archived (PDF) from the original on 30 May 2009. Retrieved 9 October 2009.
  110. Suzanne Scotchmer: "Innovation and Incentives" the MIT press, 2004 (Chapter 2).

References

Further reading

External links

Law
Core subjects
Disciplines
Sources of law
Law making
Legal systems
Legal theory
Jurisprudence
Legal institutions
History
Competition law by country
Americas
Asia
Europe
Oceania
Categories: