Revision as of 06:13, 21 December 2007 editAbd (talk | contribs)14,259 edits trim back article, cut the math. it's a start.← Previous edit | Latest revision as of 21:20, 11 November 2008 edit undoSgtSchumann (talk | contribs)324 edits Made redirect, as discussed on Talk. | ||
(26 intermediate revisions by 10 users not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
#REDIRECT ] | |||
{{Mergeto|Plurality voting system|date=December 2007}} | |||
{{Unreferenced|date=July 2006}} | |||
'''Simple majority voting''' is a common form of voting where, given two options, the option receiving a simple majority of votes wins, a well-known example of democratic procedure. It is informally used in small groups to make all kinds of practical decisions, by counting hands in a group or judging the loudness of the cheers in a crowd. However, ] states that any ] rule that satisfies certain conditions, will turn out to be the simple majority rule. | |||
==May's Theorem== | |||
Manipulability by voters is as such unobservable, but doesn’t constitute a problem with simple majority voting, since in a two option case, it is impossible to manipulate the result by voting strategically. May states that, since group choice must depend only upon individual preferences concerning the alternatives in a set, a pattern of group choice may be built up if we know the group preference for each pair of alternatives. However, manipulability in a more options case is not as simple as it sounds. | |||
'''''Definition''''' | |||
Simple majority voting is an example of a social choice rule: the winning choice is the one whose number of votes is greater than half of the voters who are not indifferent between the two choices. This is in contrast with ], where the winner is the option which gets more than half of all votes, including abstentions. | |||
==Properties== | |||
Simple majority voting satisfies the ]: it assigns an unambiguous value to every logically possible list of individual preferences. In other words, whatever every individual chooses, the procedure always yields a result. This trait is sometimes referred to as decisiveness. | |||
Secondly, simple majority voting satisfies ]: it assigns the same value to two lists that are permutations of one another. This means that when two people change their votes in such a way that the number of voters for each option remains the same, than the result remains the same. The procedure does not care about which voter votes for an option, only about how many voters vote for that option. If the result changed, that would mean that one of those two votes overrides all the other votes, which comes down to a dictatorship. | |||
Simple majority voting also satisfies ]: if everyone reverses their vote, the result is reversed, a tie remains a tie. | |||
As fourth and last property, simple majority voting satisfies ]. If one of the two options has more or equally many votes as the other option and one voter changes his mind in favor of that first option, then the result will also change in favor of that option: a tie becomes a win and a win stays a win. | |||
==See also:== | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
] |
Latest revision as of 21:20, 11 November 2008
Redirect to: