Misplaced Pages

History of banking: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 20:21, 19 December 2009 editCs-wolves (talk | contribs)Autopatrolled, Extended confirmed users, Pending changes reviewers, Rollbackers222,143 editsNo edit summary← Previous edit Latest revision as of 01:23, 28 November 2024 edit undoClueBot NG (talk | contribs)Bots, Pending changes reviewers, Rollbackers6,438,500 editsm Reverting possible vandalism by 167.108.76.225 to version by Citation bot. Report False Positive? Thanks, ClueBot NG. (4360731) (Bot)Tag: Rollback 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Detailed history of the formation of the bank}}
{{Cleanup|article|date=December 2008}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=February 2021}}
{{Banking}}
The '''history of banking''' began with the first prototype ]s, that is, the merchants of the world, who gave grain ]s to farmers and traders who carried goods between cities. This was around 2000 BCE in ], ] and ]. Later, in ] and during the ], lenders based in temples gave loans, while accepting ] and performing the ]. Archaeology from this period in ] and ] also show evidences of ].{{Citation needed|date=June 2024}}


Many scholars trace the historical roots of the modern ] system to medieval and Renaissance ], particularly the affluent cities of ], ] and ]. The ] and ] families dominated banking in 14th century Florence, establishing branches in many other parts of ].<ref name="Hoggson, N. F. 1926">] (1926) ''Banking Through the Ages'', New York, Dodd, Mead & Company.</ref> The most famous Italian bank was the ], established by ] in 1397.<ref name="autogenerated1995">Goldthwaite, R. A. ''Banks, Places and Entrepreneurs in Renaissance Florence,'' (1995)</ref> The ] is ], headquartered in ], Italy, which has been operating continuously since 1472.<ref>{{cite news|url=http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/a034542e-5771-11de-8c47-00144feabdc0.html |title=Modern dilemma for world's oldest bank |last=Boland |first=Vincent |date=12 June 2009 |work=]|access-date=23 February 2010}}</ref> Until the end of 2002, the oldest bank still in operation was the ] headquartered in ], Italy, which had been operating since 1463.
==Earliest banks==
The first ]s were probably the religious ]s of the ancient world, and were probably established sometime during the third millennium B.C. Banks probably predated the invention of money. Deposits initially consisted of grain and later other goods including cattle, agricultural implements, and eventually precious metals such as ], in the form of easy-to-carry compressed plates. Temples and palaces were the safest places to store gold as they were constantly attended and well built. As sacred places, temples presented an extra deterrent to would-be thieves. There are extant records of ]s from the 18th century BC in ] that were made by temple priests/monks to merchants. By the time of ], banking was well enough developed to justify the promulgation of laws governing banking operations.<ref>The word "bank" reflects the origins of banking in temples. According to the famous passage from the New Testament, when Christ drove the money changers out of the temple in Jerusalem, he overturned their tables. Matthew 21.12. In Greece, bankers were known as ''trapezitai'', a name derived from the tables where they sat. Similarly, the English word ''bank'' comes from the Italian ''banca'', for bench or counter.</ref>] holds further evidence of banking. Greek temples, as well as private and civic entities, conducted financial transactions such as loans, deposits, currency exchange, and validation of coinage<ref>]: ''Athenian Economy and Society: A Banking Perspective'' (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1992) ISBN 0-691-03609-8</ref>. There is evidence too of credit, whereby in return for a payment from a client, a moneylender in one Greek port would write a credit note for the client who could "cash" the note in another city, saving the client the danger of carting coinage with him on his journey. Pythius, who operated as a merchant banker throughout Asia Minor at the beginning of the 5th century B.C., is the first individual banker of whom we have records. Many of the early bankers in Greek city-states were “metics” or foreign residents. Around 371 B.C., ], a slave, became the wealthiest and most famous Greek banker, gaining his freedom and Athenian citizenship in the process.The fourth century B.C. saw increased use of credit-based banking in the Mediterranean world. In Egypt, from early times, grain had been used as a form of money in addition to precious metals, and state granaries functioned as banks. When Egypt fell under the rule of a Greek dynasty, the Ptolemies (332-30 B.C.), the numerous scattered government granaries were transformed into a network of grain banks, centralized in Alexandria where the main accounts from all the state granary banks were recorded. This banking network functioned as a trade credit system in which payments were effected by transfer from one account to another without money passing.In the late third century B.C., the barren Aegean island of Delos, known for its magnificent harbor and famous temple of Apollo, became a prominent banking center. As in Egypt, cash transactions were replaced by real credit receipts and payments were made based on simple instructions with accounts kept for each client. With the defeat of its main rivals, Carthage and Corinth, by the Romans, the importance of Delos increased. Consequently it was natural that the bank of Delos should become the model most closely imitated by the banks of Rome.] in ''Passionary of Christ and Antichrist''.<ref>The references cited in the Passionary for this woodcut: {{bibleverse|1|John|2:14-16|9}}, {{bibleverse||Matthew|10:8|9}}, and </ref>]]] perfected the administrative aspect of banking and saw greater regulation of financial institutions and financial practices. Charging ] on loans and paying interest on deposits became more highly developed and competitive. The development of Roman banks was limited, however, by the Roman preference for cash transactions. During the reign of the Roman emperor Gallienus (260-268 AD), there was a temporary breakdown of the Roman banking system after the banks rejected the flakes of copper produced by his mints. With the ascent of ], banking became subject to additional restrictions, as the charging of interest was seen as immoral. After the fall of Rome, banking was abandoned in western Europe and did not revive until the time of the crusades.


Development of banking spread from northern Italy throughout the ], and in the 15th and 16th century to northern Europe. This was followed by a number of important innovations that took place in ] during the ] in the 17th century, and in London since the 18th century. During the 20th century, developments in telecommunications and computing caused major changes to banks' operations and let banks dramatically increase in size and geographic spread. The ] led to many ]s, including some of the world's largest banks, and provoked much debate about ].
===Religious restrictions on interest===
Most early religious systems in the ancient ], and the secular codes arising from them, did not forbid ]. These societies regarded inanimate matter as alive, like plants, animals and people, and capable of reproducing itself. Hence if you lent 'food money', or monetary tokens of any kind, it was legitimate to charge interest.<ref>Johnson cites Fritz E. Heichelcheim: ''An Ancient Economic History'', 2 vols. (trans. Leiden 1965), i.104-566</ref> Food money in the shape of olives, dates, seeds or animals was lent out as early as c. 5000 BC, if not earlier. Among the ]ns, ], ] and ], interest was legal and often fixed by the state. But the Jews took a different view of the matter.<ref>]: ''A History of the Jews'' (New York: HarperCollins Publishers, 1987) ISBN 0-06-091533-1. pp.172-173</ref></blockquote>The ] and later sections of the ] criticize interest-taking, but interpretations of the Biblical prohibition vary. One common understanding is that Jews are forbidden to charge interest upon loans made to other Jews, but allowed to charge interest on transactions with non-Jews, or Gentiles. However, the Hebrew Bible itself gives numerous examples where this provision was evaded.


==Ancient authority==
==During Late Antiquity and Middle Ages==
{{See also|Cheque}}
]s were ostracized from most professions by local rulers, the Church and the ]s and so were pushed into marginal occupations considered socially inferior, such as ] and ] collecting and moneylending, while the provision of financial services was increasingly demanded by the expansion of ]an trade and commerce.


{{further|Economic history of the world|History of economics}}
Medieval trade fairs, such as the one in ], contributed to the growth of banking in a curious way: moneychangers issued documents redeemable at other fairs, in exchange for hard currency. These documents could be cashed at another fair in a different country or at a future fair in the same location. If redeemable at a future date, they would often be ]ed by an amount comparable to a rate of interest. Eventually, these documents evolved into ], which could be redeemed at any office of the issuing banker. These bills made it possible to transfer large sums of money without the complications of hauling large chests of gold and hiring armed guards to protect the gold from thieves.


The shift from a reliance on ] of foods to ], starting sometime after 12,000&nbsp;BCE, resulted in increased stability of economic relations. Such changes in socio-economic conditions began approximately 10,000 years ago in the ], about 9,500 years ago in northern China, about 5,500 years ago in Mexico, and approximately 4,500 years ago in the eastern parts of the United States.<ref name="Marks">{{cite book | url =https://books.google.com/books?id=07pEoprLQs8C&q=History+of+agriculture+Fertile+Crescent&pg=PT18|author=R Marks was Richard and Billie Deihl Professor of History at Whittier College during 2000|title=The Origins of the Modern World: Fate and Fortune in the Rise of the West|publisher=Rowman & Littlefield, 7 December 2006| access-date = 1 June 2012|isbn=9781461700005|date=7 December 2006}}</ref><ref name="Cameron">{{cite book | url =https://books.google.com/books?id=aEHX63g1XsYC|author=Rondo E. Cameron|title=A Concise Economic History of the World: From Paleolithic Times to the Present|publisher=Oxford University Press, 11 March 1993| access-date = 1 June 2012|isbn=9780195074451|year=1993}}</ref><ref>Ian Hodder – Cambridge University Press, 30 August 2010 Retrieved 25 June 2012</ref>
Beginning around 1100s, the need to transfer large sums of money to finance the ] stimulated the re-emergence of banking in western Europe. In 1156, in ], occurred the earliest known foreign exchange contract. Two brothers borrowed 115 Genoese pounds and agreed to reimburse the bank's agents in Constantinople the sum of 460 bezants one month after their arrival in that city. In the following century the use of such contracts grew rapidly, particularly since profits from time differences were seen as not infringing canon laws against usury. In 1162, King Henry the II levied a tax to support the crusades -- the first of a series of taxes levied by Henry over the years with the same objective. The ] and ] acted as Henry's bankers in the Holy Land. The Templars' wide flung, large land holdings across Europe also emerged in the 1100-1300 time frame as the beginning of Europe-wide banking, as their practice was to take in local currency, for which a demand note would be given that would be good at any of their castles across Europe, allowing movement of money without the usual risk of robbery while traveling.


===Monetary===
By 1200 there was a large and growing volume of long-distance and international trade in a number of agricultural commodities and manufactured goods in western Europe; some of the goods traded during that period included wool, finished cloth, wine, salt, wax and tallow, leather and leather goods, and weapons and armour. Individual trading concerns and combines often specialized in one or more of these, as did individual producers; because a large amount of capital was required to establish, e.g., a cloth manufacturing business, only the largest firms could diversify. As a result, businesses and clusters of businesses tended to market fairly narrow product lines. Big firms like the Medici bank could and did specialize; the Medici’s manufacturing division had a number of manufacturing facilities producing many different types of cloth. Perhaps the best example of product policy comes from the Cistercian monastic order, where individual monasteries and granges tended to specialize in particular agricultural products or types of industrial production, usually with an eye to meeting particular local or regional market needs.


Ancient types of money known as grain-money and food cattle-money were used from around 9000&nbsp;BCE as two of the earliest commodities used for purposes of ].
Ironically, the Papal bankers were the most successful of the Western world, though often goods taken in pawn were substituted for interest in the institution termed the ]. When ] (born Jacques d'Euse (1249 - 1334) was crowned in ] in 1316, he set up residency in ]. Civil war in Florence between the rival Guelph and Ghibelline factions resulted in victory for a group of Guelph merchant families in the city. They took over papal banking monopolies from rivals in nearby Siena and became tax collectors for the Pope throughout Europe. In 1306, Philip IV expelled Jews from France. In 1307 Philip had the ] arrested and had gotten hold of their wealth, which had become to serve as the unofficial treasury of France. In 1311 he expelled Italian bankers and collected their outstanding credit. In 1327, Avignon had 43 branches of Italian banking houses. In 1347, Edward III of England defaulted on loans. Later there was the bankruptcy of the Peruzzi (1374) and Bardi (1353). The accompanying growth of Italian banking in ] was the start of the ] moneychangers in Europe, who moved from city to city along the busy pilgrim routes important for trade. Key cities in this period were ], the birthplace of Pope John XXII, and ]. Perhaps it was because of these origins that the term ''Lombard'' is synonymous with ''Cahorsin'' in medieval Europe, and means 'pawnbroker'. Banca ] SPA (MPS) Italy, is the oldest surviving bank in the world.


]n ] as a raw material for ] was being distributed from as early as about 12,500&nbsp;BCE, and ] of it was occurring during the 9th millennium BCE (Cauvin; Chataigner 1989). ] was one of the four main sites for sourcing the material deposits of obsidian within the Mediterranean; trade using obsidian was replaced during the 3rd millennium BCE by trade of ] and ].
] ''Stultifera Navis'' (]); ] attributed to ]]]
After 1400, political forces turned against the methods of the Italian free enterprise bankers. In 1401, King Martin I of Aragon expelled them. In 1403, Henry IV of England prohibited them from taking profits in any way in his kingdom. In 1409, Flanders imprisoned and then expelled Genoese bankers. In 1410, all Italian merchants were expelled from Paris. In 1401, the Bank of Barcelona was founded. In 1407, the ] was founded in Genoa. This bank dominated business in the Mediterranean. In 1403 charging interest on loans was ruled legal in Florence despite the traditional Christian prohibition of usury. Italian banks such as the Lombards, who had agents in the main economic centres of Europe, had been making charges for loans. The lawyer and theologian Lorenzo di Antonio Ridolfi won a case which legalised interest payments by the Florentine government. In 1413, Giovanni di Bicci de’Medici appointed banker to the pope. In 1440, Gutenberg invents the modern printing press although Europe already knew of the use of paper money in China. The printing press design was subsequently modified, by Leonardo da Vinci among others, for use in minting coins nearly two centuries before printed banknotes were produced in the West.


===Record-keeping===
By the 1390s silver was short all over Europe, except in Venice. The silver mines at ] had begun to decline in the 1370s, and finally closed down after being sacked by King Sigismund in 1422. By 1450 almost all of the mints of northwest Europe had closed down for lack of silver. The last money-changer in the major French port of Dieppe went out of business in 1446. In 1455 the Turks overran the Serbian silver mines, and in 1460 captured the last Bosnian mine. The last Venetian silver grosso was minted in 1462. Several Venetian banks failed, and so did the Strozzi bank of Florence, the second largest in the city. Even the smallest of small change became scarce.


]
==Western banking history==
Modern Western economic and financial history is usually traced back to the coffee houses of London.{{Fact|date=November 2008}} The London ] was established in 1565. At that time moneychangers were already called bankers, though the term "]" usually referred to their offices, and did not carry the meaning it does today. There was also a hierarchical order among professionals; at the top were the bankers who did business with heads of state, next were the city exchanges, and at the bottom were the ]s or "]"'s. Some European cities today have a Lombard street where the pawn shop was located.


{{further|History of accounting#Ancient history|History of accounting}}
After the ] trade moved to ]. In 1609 the '']'' (Amsterdam Exchange Bank) was founded which made Amsterdam the financial centre of the world until the ].


Objects used for record keeping, "]" and ''tokens'', have been recovered from within ], dated to a period beginning 8000&nbsp;BCE and ending 1500&nbsp;BCE, as records of the ] of agricultural produce. Commencing in the late fourth millennia ] symbols were in use by members of temples and palaces to record stocks of produce. Types of records accounting for trade exchanges of payments were first being made about 3200&nbsp;BCE. The '']'', written on a clay tablet around 1700&nbsp;BCE, describes the regulation of banking activity within the civilization (Armstrong); although still rudimentary, banking was well enough developed to justify laws governing banking operations.<ref group="nb">The word "bank" reflects the origins of banking in temples. According to the famous passage from the ], when Christ drove the money changers out of the temple in Jerusalem, he overturned their tables. Matthew 21.12. In Greece, bankers were known as ''trapezitai'', a name derived from the tables where they sat. Similarly, the English word ''bank'' comes from the Italian ''banca'', for bench or counter.</ref> Later during the ] (after 646&nbsp;BCE),<ref>MA Dandamaev – BRILL, 1989 Retrieved 15 July 2012</ref> further evidence is found of banking practices in the Mesopotamia region.<ref name="Mario Liverani">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=0d1JAgAAQBAJ&q=open+bulla+for+record-keeping.&pg=PA76|author=Mario Liverani|title=The Ancient Near East: History, Society and Economy|publisher=Routledge, 4 December 2013| access-date=12 February 2015|isbn=978-1134750849|date=4 December 2013}} (p. 76 – "record-keeping & bulla"</ref><ref name="Andrew Robinson">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=BX2uIFhUNWMC&q=History+of+banks&pg=PA1|author=A Robinson|title=Writing and Script: A Very Short Introduction|publisher=Oxford University Press, 1 October 2009| access-date=8 June 2012|isbn=978-0199567782|author-link=W. Andrew Robinson|date=5 April 2010}}</ref><ref name="Nissen et al">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=YBAzXV4YtQ8C&q=Clay+accounts+fourth+millennium+B.C.+BULLA+ACCOUNTS&pg=PA125|author1=H J Nissen |author2=P Damerow |author3=R K Englund |publisher=University of Chicago Press, 1993|title=Archaic bookkeeping| access-date=8 June 2012|isbn=0226586596|year=1993 }}</ref><ref name="Mario Liverani, Zainab Bahrani, Marc Van de Mieroop"/><ref name="Kuhrt">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=V_sfMzRPTgoC&q=Uruk+3200+accounts&pg=PA23|author=A Kuhrt |title=The Ancient Near East, C. 3000–330 BC, Volume 1|publisher=Routledge, 1995| access-date=16 June 2012|isbn=0415167639|year = 1995}}</ref><ref name="Beatrice Teissier">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=qu7WeaZA3VUC&q=Uruk&pg=PA3|author=B Teissier |title=Ancient Near Eastern Cylinder Seals from the Marcopoli Collection|publisher=University of California Press, 1984| access-date=16 June 2012|isbn=0520049276|date = 1 January 1984}}</ref><ref name="H Williams">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=BX2uIFhUNWMC&q=History+of+banks&pg=PA1|author=H Williams|title=Building Type Basics for Banks and Financial Institutions|publisher=John Wiley & Sons, 5 April 2010| access-date=8 June 2012|isbn=978-0470278628|date=5 April 2010}}</ref><ref>D Schmandt-Besserat – University of Texas Press, 1992 {{ISBN|0292707835}} Retrieved 8 June 2012</ref>
Banking offices were usually located near centers of trade, and in the late 17th century, the largest centers for commerce were the ports of ], ], and ]. Individuals could participate in the lucrative East India trade by purchasing bills of credit from these banks, but the price they received for commodities was dependent on the ships returning (which often didn't happen on time) and on the cargo they carried (which often wasn't according to plan). The commodities market was very volatile for this reason, and also because of the many wars that led to cargo seizures and loss of ships.


===Capitalism=== ===Structural===
Around the time of ] (]) there was a massive growth in the banking industry. Within the new system of ownership and investment, the state's role as an economic factor changed substantially.


By the 5th millennium BCE, the settlements of ], such as ], were formed around a central temple. In the fifth millennium, people began to build and live in the civilization of cities, providing a structure for the construction of institutions and establishments. ] and ] were two early ] settlements.<ref name="Mario Liverani, Zainab Bahrani, Marc Van de Mieroop">{{cite book |author=M Liverani |author-link=Mario Liverani|translator1=Z Bahrani |translator1-link=Zainab Bahrani |translator2=M Van de Mieroop |title=Uruk: the first city|publisher=Equinox, 2006}}</ref><ref name="Moorey, P R S"/><ref>P Watson – Hachette UK, 12 January 2012 -Retrieved 9 June 2012</ref><ref name="Brian M. Fagan">{{cite book |author=Brian M. Fagan |title=World prehistory: a brief introduction|publisher=Prentice Hall, 2002 }}</ref><ref>Ur, Jason A. 2007 Early Mesopotamian urbanism: a new view from the North. Antiquity 81(313): 585–600. – Retrieved 1 July 2012</ref>
==Global banking==
{{Original research|date=April 2009}}
{{Unreferenced|date=May 2007}}
In the 1970s, a number of smaller crashes tied to the policies put in place following the depression, resulted in deregulation and privatization of government-owned enterprises in the 1980s, indicating that governments of industrial countries around the world found private-sector solutions to problems of economic growth and development preferable to state-operated, semi-socialist programs. This spurred a trend that was already prevalent in the business sector, large companies becoming global and dealing with customers, suppliers, manufacturing, and information centres all over the world.


==Earliest forms of banking==
Global banking and capital market services proliferated during the 1980s and 1990s as a result of a great increase in demand from companies, governments, and financial institutions, but also because financial market conditions were buoyant and, on the whole, bullish. Interest rates in the United States declined from about 15% for two-year U.S. Treasury notes to about 5% during the 20-year period, and financial assets grew then at a rate approximately twice the rate of the world economy.
Such growth rate would have been lower, in the last twenty years, were it not for the profound effects of the internationalization of financial markets especially U.S. Foreign investments, particularly from Japan, who not only provided the funds to corporations in the U.S., but also helped finance the federal government; thus, transforming the U.S. stock market by far into the largest in the world.


{{See also|Banker (ancient)}}
Nevertheless, in recent years, the dominance of U.S. financial markets has been disappearing and there has been an increasing interest in foreign stocks. The extraordinary growth of foreign financial markets results from both large increases in the pool of savings in foreign countries, such as Japan, and, especially, the deregulation of foreign financial markets, which has enabled them to expand their activities. Thus, American corporations and banks have started seeking investment opportunities abroad, prompting the development in the U.S. of mutual funds specializing in trading in foreign stock markets.


===Asia===
Such growing internationalization and opportunity in financial services has entirely changed the competitive landscape, as now many banks have demonstrated a preference for the “universal banking” model so prevalent in Europe. Universal banks are free to engage in all forms of financial services, make investments in client companies, and function as much as possible as a “one-stop” supplier of both retail and wholesale financial services.


====Mesopotamia and Persia====
Many such possible alignments could be accomplished only by large acquisitions, and there were many of them. By the end of 2000, a year in which a record level of financial services transactions with a market value of $10.5 trillion occurred, the top ten banks commanded a market share of more than 80% and the top five, 55%. Of the top ten banks ranked by market share, seven were large universal-type banks (three American and four European), and the remaining three were large U.S. investment banks who between them accounted for a 33% market share.


{{Further|Mesopotamia#Economy and agriculture}}
This growth and opportunity also led to an unexpected outcome: entrance into the market of other financial intermediaries: nonbanks. Large corporate players were beginning to find their way into the financial service community, offering competition to established banks. The main services offered included insurances, pension, mutual, money market and hedge funds, loans and credits and securities. Indeed, by the end of 2001 the market capitalisation of the world’s 15 largest financial services providers included four nonbanks.


Banking as an archaic activity (or quasi-banking<ref>M. Chahin – Routledge, 2001 {{ISBN|0700714529}}</ref><ref>ME Stevens Baker Academic, 2006 {{ISBN|0801047773}}</ref>) is thought to have begun as early as the latter part of the 4th millennium BCE,<ref>N Luhmann – Transaction Publishers, 2005 {{ISBN|0202307646}} (p. 181)</ref> to the 3rd millennia BCE.<ref>{{cite book |url=http://projects.exeter.ac.uk/RDavies/arian/amser/chrono1.html |author1=Davies, R |author2=Davies, G |title=A History of Money from Ancient Times to the Present Day |publisher=Cardiff: University of Wales Press, 1996}}</ref><ref> universalis.fr Accessed 15 September 2018</ref>
In recent years, the process of financial innovation has advanced enormously increasing the importance and profitability of nonbank finance. Such profitability priorly restricted to the nonbanking industry, has prompted the ] (OCC) to encourage banks to explore other financial instruments, diversifying banks' business as well as improving banking economic health. Hence, as the distinct financial instruments are being explored and adopted by both the banking and nonbanking industries, the distinction between different financial institutions is gradually vanishing.


] recorded interest-bearing loans.]]
==Major events in banking history==
Prior to the reign of ] (2335–2280&nbsp;BCE<ref>Chahin, M. – James Clarke & Co., 1996 {{ISBN|0718829506}} Retrieved 8 June 2012</ref>) the occurrence of trade was limited to the internal boundaries of each city-state of ] and the temple located at the centre of economic activity therein; trade at the time for citizens external to the city was forbidden.<ref name="Moorey, P R S">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=P_Ixuott4doC&q=ancient+agriculture+mesopotamia&pg=PA1|author=Moorey, P R S|title=Ancient Mesopotamia :Materials and Industries The Archaeological Evidence|publisher=Eisenbrauns, 1 November 1999 | access-date=8 June 2012|isbn=1575060426|year=1999}}</ref><ref>Beaudreau, B C – iUniverse, 13 September 2004 {{ISBN|0595778445}} Retrieved 8 June 2012</ref><ref>secondary references – + + + </ref>
* Florentine banking &mdash; The ]s and ]s among others.
* ]- earliest Euro wide /Mideast banking 1100-1300.
* ]s &mdash; Introduction of paper money.
* ] - First ] company, the ] founded.
* ] - The ] and ]'s ], which caused a European financial crisis and forced many bankers out of business.
* ] - The ] was found by the ].
* ] - ] founds Euro wide banking.
* ]-] In the wake of the ], 9,000 banks close, wiping out a third of the money supply in the United States.<ref>http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2008/may/12/panic-control</ref>
* ] - ] collapses. It was the largest bank failure in history.


In ] of 2000&nbsp;BCE, people depositing gold were required to pay amounts as much as one sixtieth of the total deposited. Both the palaces and temple are known to have provided lending and issuing from the wealth they held—the palaces to a lesser extent. Such loans typically involved issuing seed-grain, with re-payment from the harvest. These basic social agreements were documented in clay tablets,
===Oldest private banks===
with an agreement on interest ]. The habit of depositing and storing of wealth in temples continued at least until 209 BCE, as evidenced by ] having ransacked or pillaged the temple of Aine in ] (]) of gold and silver.<ref>GW Bromiley – Wm. B. Eerdmans Publishing, 13 February 1995 Retrieved 14 July 2012 {{ISBN|0802837816}}</ref><ref>the British Museum - Retrieved 9 April 2012</ref><ref name="Orsingher">{{cite book |url=https://docs.google.com/viewer?a=v&q=cache:Rno4htiTfYIJ:www.unc.edu/~salemi/Econ006/Orsingher.pdf+&hl=en&gl=uk&pid=bl&srcid=ADGEEShMa_MmpKTwUX5ZX61fzKYS8Bp6vzsVZfaYiNvyVJf2VifxcbOQKMZOFRZOn4aFy6mUULvk0ojvDjOZKDNQLCC5MAuL--Ag7J_dOxtDrHXy3lXO_aDvsOF-V6nrry1xvQ3buwwa&sig=AHIEtbRYONza475fGri19-f0S6mK6HqCJQ |author=Orsingher, R Translated by D.S.Ault|title=Banks of the World |publisher=Walker and Company New York| access-date=9 April 2012}}</ref><ref>G G Aperghis – Cambridge University Press, 23 December 2004 {{ISBN|0521837073}} Retrieved 10 June 2012</ref><ref>A Holm -translated by F. Clarke- Macmillan & Co 1898 – {{ISBN|1440041237}} Retrieved 10 June 2012</ref><ref>] – Harper & Brothers, 1855 – Retrieved 10 June 2012</ref><ref>] – Walton & Maberly, 1857 – Retrieved 10 June 2012</ref><ref>''Encyclopædia Britannica'' shows is "... Hamadān, Iran ..." – Retrieved 10 June 2012</ref>
* ] 1472 - present, the oldest surviving bank in the world. Founded in 1472 by the Magistrate of the city state of Siena, Italy.
* ] founded 1473 - now part of ] of Italy
* ] founded 1672
* ], which was founded by John Freame and Thomas Gould in 1690<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.aboutbarclays.com/content/detail.asp?NewsAreaID=138|title=Barclays - Our Beginnings|accessdate=2007-09-21}}
</ref> and renamed to ] by Freame's son-in-law, James Barclay, in 1736
* ] 1700 - present
* ] 1741 - present, the oldest Swiss bank, founded in 1741 in St. Gallen, third largest private bank in Switzerland
* ], founded in ]


More information comes from ] commissioned by ], king of Babylon {{circa|1792}}–1750&nbsp;BCE. Law 100 stipulated that ] of a ] by a ] to a ] was to be on a ] with a ] specified in ] ]s.<ref name="Sommer 1903 p. 75">{{cite journal|translator-last=Sommer|translator-first=Otto|author=Hammurabi|author-link=Hammurabi|title=Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon|year=1903|journal=Records of the Past|place=]|publisher=]|volume=2|issue=3|page=|access-date=June 20, 2021|url=https://archive.org/details/cu31924060109703/mode/2up|quote=100. Anyone borrowing money shall ... his contract .}}</ref><ref name="Harper 1904 p. 35">{{cite web|translator-last=Harper|translator-first=Robert Francis|author=Hammurabi|author-link=Hammurabi|year=1904|title=Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon|place=]|publisher=]|edition=2nd|page=|website=]|url=https://oll-resources.s3.us-east-2.amazonaws.com/oll3/store/titles/1276/0762_Bk.pdf|access-date=June 20, 2021|quote=§100. ...he shall write down ... returns to his merchant.}}</ref><ref name="King 1910">{{cite web|translator-last=King|translator-first=Leonard William|author=Hammurabi|author-link=Hammurabi|year=1910|title=Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon|place=]|publisher=]|website=]|url=https://avalon.law.yale.edu/ancient/hamframe.asp|access-date=June 20, 2021}}</ref> Law 122 stipulated that a ] of ], ], or other ] must present all articles and a signed ] of ] to a ] before depositing the articles with a banker, and Law 123 stipulated that a banker was discharged of any ] from a contract of bailment if the notary denied the existence of the contract. Law 124 stipulated that a depositor with a ] was entitled to ], and Law 125 stipulated that a banker was ] for replacement of deposits ] while in their ].<ref name="Sommer 1903 p. 77">{{cite journal|translator-last=Sommer|translator-first=Otto|author=Hammurabi|author-link=Hammurabi|title=Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon|year=1903|journal=Records of the Past|place=]|publisher=]|volume=2|issue=3|page=|access-date=June 20, 2021|url=https://archive.org/details/cu31924060109703/mode/2up|quote=122. If anyone entrusts to ... have committed an offence.}}</ref><ref name="Harper 1904 p. 43">{{cite web|translator-last=Harper|translator-first=Robert Francis|author=Hammurabi|author-link=Hammurabi|year=1904|title=Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon|place=]|publisher=]|edition=2nd|page=|website=]|url=https://oll-resources.s3.us-east-2.amazonaws.com/oll3/store/titles/1276/0762_Bk.pdf|access-date=June 20, 2021|quote=§122. If a man give ... it from the thief.}}</ref><ref name="King 1910" />
For French banking history, read the (in English or in French) on the .


Cuneiform records of the ] of Babylonia describe the family's financial activities as having occurred sometime after 1000&nbsp;BCE and ending sometime during the reign of ]. These records suggest a "lending house" (Silver 2002), a family engaging in "professional banking..." (Dandamaev ''et al.'' 2004), and economic activities similar to modern deposit banking. Another interpretation is that the family's activities are better described as entrepreneurship rather than banking (Wunsch 2007). The ] apparently took part in providing ] (Moshenskyi 2008).<ref>R Rollinger, C Ulf, K Schnegg – Commerce and Monetary Systems in the Ancient World: Means of Transmission and Cultural Interaction : Proceedings of the Fifth Annual Symposium of the Assyrian and Babylonian Intellectual Heritage Project, Held in Innsbruck, Austria, 3–8 October 2002 Franz Steiner Verlag, 2004 Retrieved 10 July 2012 {{ISBN|3515083790}}</ref><ref>Gwendolyn Leick (ed.) – ''The Babylonian world'' Routledge 2007 Retrieved 10 July 2012 {{ISBN|1134261284}}</ref><ref>MA Dandamaev, VG Lukonin, PL Kohl – Cambridge University Press, 11 November 2004 Retrieved 10 July 2012 {{ISBN|0521611911}}</ref><ref name="WI Davisson & JE Harper">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=O4zGe2nuCvgC&q=warehousing+and+trapezite+banking&pg=PA156|author1=WI Davisson |author2=JE Harper |title=European Economic History|publisher=Appleton-Century-Crofts 1972| access-date=10 July 2012|year=1972 }}</ref><ref>JP Nielsen – {{Dead link|date=August 2024 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }} ProQuest, 2008 Retrieved 10 July 2012 {{ISBN|054956926X}}</ref><ref>OJ Thatcher – ''The Library of Original Sources: Volume I (The Ancient World)'' The Minerva Group, Inc., 30 June 2004 {{ISBN|141021401X}} Retrieved 10 July 2012</ref><ref>RN Frye – C.H.Beck, 1984 Retrieved 10 July 2012 {{ISBN|3406093973}}</ref><ref>S Moshenskyi – Sergei Moshenskyi, 1 August 2008 Retrieved 10 July 2012 {{ISBN|1436306949}}</ref><ref>KR Nemet-Nejat – Greenwood Publishing Group, 1998 Retrieved 10 July 2012 {{ISBN|0313294976}}</ref><ref>JA Thompson – Paternoster Press, 1973 Retrieved 10 July 2012</ref>
===Oldest national banks===
* ] &mdash; The rise of the ]s, began operations in 1668
* ] &mdash; The evolution of modern central banking policies, established in 1694
* ] &mdash; The invention of centralized check and payment processing technology
* ]
* ]
* The Pennsylvania Land Bank, founded in 1723 and receiving the support of ] who wrote "Modest Enquiry into the Nature and Necessity of a Paper Currency" in ].
* ] (Iran) Founded in 1888 and was merged in Tejarat Bank in 1979 &mdash; History of banking in the Middle-East


==References== ====Asia Minor====

* and Guido Laura, ''Genoa and the history of finance: A series of firsts?'' 9th November 2004, ISBN 88-87822-16-6 (the book can be downloaded at www.giuseppefelloni.it)
{{Reflist}} {{See|Asia Minor}}

From the fourth millennium previously agricultural settlements began administrative activities.<ref>S R Steadman, G McMahon – Oxford University Press, 5 September 2011 {{ISBN|0195376145}} Retrieved 25 June 2012</ref><ref>A. G. Sagona, Claudia Sagona – Peeters Publishers, 2004 {{ISBN|9042913908}} Retrieved 25 June 2012</ref><ref>secondary – Luc-Normand Tellier PUQ, 2009 ISBN
2760515885 Retrieved 25 June 2012</ref><ref>Catholic Encyclopedia Retrieved 25 June 2012</ref>

The ] at ] was the largest depository of Asia. A pot hoard dated to 600 BCE was found in excavations by The British Museum during 1904. During the time of the cessation of the first Mithridatic war, the entire debt being held at the time was annulled by the council. ] is recorded to have stolen from the deposits on occasion. The temple served as a depository for Aristotle, Caesar, Dio Chrysostomus, Plautus, Plutarch, Strabo and Xenophon.<ref>{{cite book |author=Walter Augustus Hawley |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=0RUZfCxQqcYC&q=Asia+Minor |title=Asia Minor |publisher=Elibron.com |year=1918 | isbn=9781402185458 |access-date=3 June 2012}}</ref><ref>secondary – {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121104044244/http://www.britishmuseum.org/explore/highlights/article_index/a/the_archaic_temple_of_artemis.aspx |date=4 November 2012 }} Retrieved 3 June 2012</ref><ref>secondary – Cambridge University Press 2012. Retrieved 3 June 2012</ref><ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150205042158/https://www.britishmuseum.org/explore/highlights/highlight_objects/cm/t/the_pot-hoard_from_the_temple.aspx |date=5 February 2015 }} Retrieved 3 June 2012</ref><ref name="J. Murphy-O'Connor">{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=4FwV5fu8D_UC&q=archaeological+evidence+of+temple+banking&pg=PA65|author=] is Professor of the New Testament at the Ecole Biblique et Archeologique Francaise, Jerusalem (2008) | title=St. Paul's Ephesus: Texts and Archaeology|access-date= 3 June 2012|publisher=Liturgical Press, 2008|isbn= 978-0814652596|year=2008 }}</ref><ref>secondary – ] – G. Hawkins, W. Strahan, 1770. Retrieved 3 June 2012</ref><ref></ref>

The temple to Apollo in Didyma was constructed sometime in the 6th century. A large sum of gold was deposited within the treasury at the time by king ].<ref name="John Freely">{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=84WaOXNwWfoC&q=temples+deposit+large+army&pg=PA203|author= J Freely | title=The Western Shores Of Turkey: Discovering The Aegean And Mediterranean Coasts|access-date= 15 June 2012|publisher=Tauris Parke Paperbacks, 4 September 2004|isbn=1850436185|date= 4 September 2004 }}</ref><ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151018120458/http://www.britishmuseum.org/explore/highlights/highlight_objects/cm/g/gold_croesid_coin.aspx |date=18 October 2015 }} Retrieved 16 June 2012</ref>

====India====

{{main |History of banking in India}}
In ancient India there are evidences of loans from the ] (beginning 1750&nbsp;BCE). Later during the ] (321–185&nbsp;BCE), an instrument called adesha was in use, which was an order on a banker desiring him to pay the money of the note to a third person, which corresponds to the definition of a bill of exchange as we understand it today. During the Buddhist period, there was considerable use of these instruments. Merchants in large towns gave letters of credit to one another.<ref>C Gomez – Prentice-Hall 2008 Retrieved 11 July 2012 {{ISBN|8120335376}}</ref><ref>A Chavez Irapta, Et Al – Rex Bookstore, Inc., 2005 Retrieved 11 July 2012</ref><ref name="rbi.org.in">{{cite web|url=http://www.rbi.org.in/scripts/PublicationsView.aspx?id=155 |title=Evolution of Payment Systems in India =Reserve Bank of India |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20141101064330/http://www.rbi.org.in/scripts/PublicationsView.aspx?id=155 |archive-date=1 November 2014 }}</ref>

====China====

''Main: ]''

In ancient China, starting in the ] (221–206&nbsp;BCE), ] developed with the introduction of standardized coins that allowed easier trade across China, and led to development of letters of credit. These letters were issued by merchants who acted in ways that today we would understand as banks.<ref>{{cite book |title=Chinese currency and banking |last=Wagel |first=Srinivas |url=http://chestofbooks.com/finance/banking/Chinese-Currency-And-Banking/Chapter-VI-Banking-In-China.html |year=1915 }}</ref>

=== Ancient Egypt ===

{{Further|Egypt#Government and economy}}

Some scholars suggest that the Egyptian grain-banking system became so well-developed that it was comparable to major modern banks, both in terms of its number of branches and employees, and in terms of the total volume of transactions. During the rule of the Greek Ptolemies, the granaries were transformed into a network of banks centered in Alexandria, where the main accounts from all of the Egyptian regional grain-banks were recorded. This became the site of one of the earliest known government central banks, and may have reached its peak with the assistance of Greek bankers.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://wiki.mises.org/History_of_money_and_banking|title=History of Money and Banking|access-date=16 June 2020|archive-date=25 February 2023|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230225170354/https://wiki.mises.org/History_of_money_and_banking|url-status=dead}}</ref>

According to Muir (2009) there were two types of banks operating within Egypt: royal and private.<ref name="John Muir">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=epPJ4fnpRn0C&pg=PA80|author=John Muir|title=Life and Letters in the Ancient Greek World|pages=80–81|publisher=Routledge|date=2009|isbn=978-1134166015}}</ref> Documents made to show the banking of taxes were known as peptoken-records.<ref name="Clarysse Thompson Luft">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=53PED9gNMTgC&pg=PA82|author1=Willy Clarysse |author2=Dorothy J. Thompson|title=Counting the People in Hellenistic Egypt: Historical Studies|volume=2|publisher=Cambridge University Press|date=2006|page=82|isbn=9780521838399 }}</ref>

===Greece===

''Trapezitica'' is the first source documenting banking ''(]'' – p.&nbsp;41). The speeches of ] contain numerous references to the issuing of credit (Millett p.&nbsp;5). ] is credited to have made the first suggestion of the creation of an organisation known in the modern definition as a joint-stock bank in ''On Revenues'' written {{circa|353}} BCE<ref name="de Soto">{{cite book |author=J Huerta de Soto – 1998 (translated by M.A.Stroup 2012) |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=AJLGKdOZneMC&q=History+of+banking+in+Egypt&pg=PA51 |title=Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles |publisher=Ludwig von Mises Institute |year=2006 |isbn=1610161890 |access-date=15 June 2012}}</ref><ref name="Paul Millett"/><ref name="James William Gilbart"/><ref>] – H.G. Bohn, 1857 – Retrieved 9 June 2012</ref>

The city-states of Greece after the ] produced a government and culture sufficiently organized for the birth of a private citizenship and therefore an embryonic capitalist society, allowing for the separation of wealth from exclusive state ownership to the possibility of ownership by the individual.<ref name="Parker, W N">{{cite book|url=http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/engen.greece |author=Parker, W N |title=Europe, America and the Wider World: Essays on the Economic History of Western Capitalism |access-date=8 June 2012 |publisher=Cambridge University Press, 26 April 1991 |isbn=0521274796 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060502201333/http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/engen.greece |archive-date=2 May 2006 |date=26 April 1991 }}</ref><ref>R W Bulliet, P K Crossley, D R Headrick, S W Hirsch, L L Johnson – Cengage Learning, 1 January 2010 Retrieved 8 June 2012</ref>

According to one source (Dandamaev ''et al.''), ] were the first to trade using money, during the 5th century BCE, as opposed to earlier trade which occurred using forms of pre-money.<ref>MA Dandamaev, VG Lukonin, PL Kohl – published by ], 11 November 2004, {{ISBN|0521611911}}. Retrieved 7 September 2012</ref>

====Specific focus of funds====

The earliest forms of storage utilized were the rudimentary ] (ΘΗΣΑΥΡΌΣ<ref>] – J Davis 1898 – Retrieved 16 June 2012</ref>) which were made similar in form to the construction of a bee-hive, and were found for example in the Mycenae tombs of 1550–1500&nbsp;BCE.<ref>] – Kessinger Publishing, 1Jan 2003 {{ISBN|0766135284}} Retrieved 16 June 2012</ref><ref>secondary – Varro ''et al'' – Retrieved 16 June 2012</ref><ref>D Sacks, O Murray Oxford University Press, 6 February 1997 {{ISBN|0195112067}} Retrieved 16 June 2012</ref><ref>secondary – The journal of the Royal Society of Antiquaries of Ireland 1894 " ...great treasury tombs probably range from this time to 1200..."</ref><ref>J E Harrison – Cambridge University Press, 24 June 2010 {{ISBN|1108009492}} Retrieved 16 June 2012</ref><ref name="James Albert Harrill">{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=7qj9bbRlnGUC&q=money-boxes+beehive&pg=PA131 |author=J A Harrill |title=The Manumission of Slaves in Early Christianity |access-date=3 June 2012 |publisher=Mohr Siebeck |isbn=3161469356 |year = 1998}}</ref><ref name="Rüpke">{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=FRRLOltuxDcC&q=money-boxes+beehive&pg=PT235|author=J Rüpke |title=A Companion to Roman Religion |access-date= 3 June 2012 |publisher=John Wiley & Sons |isbn=978-1444341317 |date=25 March 2011}}</ref>

Private and civic entities within ancient Grecian society, especially ], performed financial transactions. (Gilbart p.&nbsp;3) The temples were the places where ] was deposited for ]. The three temples thought the most important were the ] in ], and temple of ] within ], and within ], the ]. These consisted of deposits, currency exchange, validation of coinage, and loans.<ref name="de Soto"/><ref name="James William Gilbart"/><ref name="Edward E. Cohen">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Wub1JM8CRwMC&q=trapezitai&pg=PA206 |author=Edward E. Cohen|title=Athenian Economy and Society: A Banking Perspective|publisher=Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press 1992 |access-date=5 September 2015|isbn=978-0-691-03609-0|date=7 November 2011}}(and prior date)</ref><ref name="William Smith">{{cite book |url=https://www.perseus.tufts.edu/hopper/text?doc=Perseus:text:1999.04.0063:entry=argentarii-cn&highlight=trapeziticus |author=W Smith, LLD, W Wayte, G. E. Marindin, Ed.| title=A Dictionary of Greek and Roman Antiquities (1890)|access-date=15 June 2012|publisher=Perseus of Tufts University }}</ref>

The first treasury to the ]nian temple was built before the end of the 7th century BCE. A ] of the temple was constructed by the city of ] during the 6th century.<ref name="Talbert">{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=4XwOAAAAQAAJ&q=treasuries+of+the+temple+to+Apollo+in+Delphi&pg=PA26 |author= R J A Talbert| title=Atlas of Classical History|access-date= 15 June 2012|publisher=Taylor & Francis, 1985|isbn=0709924488|year= 1985}}</ref><ref>secondary- Retrieved 15 June 2012</ref><ref>F S Kleiner, H Gardner, C J Mamiya, Cengage Learning, 1 January 2010 {{ISBN|1439085781}} {{ISBN|0495004782}} Retrieved 15 June 2012</ref>

Before the destruction by Persians during the 480 invasion, the Athenian Acropolis temple dedicated to Athena stored money; ] rebuilt a depository afterward contained within the ].<ref>The Manumission of Slaves in Early Christianity By James Albert Harrill {{ISBN|3161469356}} Retrieved 18 June 2012</ref>

During the reign of the Ptolemies, state depositories replaced temples as the location of security-deposits. Records exist to show this having occurred by the end of the reign of ] (305–284).<ref name="Temporini, Haase">{{cite book | author=], ]| title = Principat, Volume 8 | publisher=Walter de Gruyter, 1977| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=tg6Wj6AT_fMC&q=archaeological+evidence+of+temple+banking&pg=PA681| isbn = 3110073374|access-date=3 June 2012 | date = March 1978 }}</ref><ref>W. V. Harris – Oxford University Press, 14 February 2008 {{ISBN|019161517X}} Retrieved 9 June 2012</ref><ref>A R David Oxford University Press, 28 October 1999 {{ISBN|0195132157}} Retrieved 9 June 2012</ref><ref>J Tyldesley – Profile Books, 26 May 2011 {{ISBN|1847650449}} Retrieved 9 June 2012</ref>

As the need for new buildings to house operations increased, construction of these places within the cities began around the courtyards of the agora (markets).<ref>M Gagarin, E Fantham – Oxford University Press, 31 December 2009 Retrieved 17 July 2012 {{ISBN|0195170725}}</ref>

====Geographical focus of banking activities====

Athens received the ] treasury during 454.<ref>M Robertson- Cambridge University Press, 16 July 1981 {{ISBN|0521280842}} Retrieved 18 June 2012</ref>

During the late 3rd and 2nd century BCE, the Aegean island of ] became a prominent banking center.<ref name="Braithwaite & Drahos">{{cite book | url =https://books.google.com/books?id=DcEEW5OGWLcC&q=campsores&pg=PA90|author1=J Braithwaite |author2=P Drahos |title=Global Business Regulation|publisher=Cambridge University Press, 1 February 2000| access-date = 14 June 2012|isbn=0521784999|date=February 2000 }}</ref> During the 2nd century, there were for certain three banks and one temple depository within the city.<ref name="Keith Roberts">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=zBFuim7hVbMC&q=The+Origins+of+Business%2C+Money%2C+and+Markets |author=K Roberts |title=The Origins of Business, Money, and Markets |publisher=Columbia University Press |isbn=978-0231153263 |year= 2011}}</ref>

Thirty-five ] cities had private banks during the 2nd century (Roberts – p.&nbsp;130).<ref name="Keith Roberts"/>

Of the settlements of the Greco-Roman world of the 1st century CE, three were of pronounced wealth and centres of banking: ], ] and ].<ref>] – Society of Biblical Literature, 2000 Retrieved 14 June 2012</ref><ref>] – Continuum International Publishing Group, 1 June 2000 {{ISBN|1563383152}} Retrieved 14 June 2012</ref><ref>2nd – + + + </ref><ref>{{cite book |title=Celebrating Common Prayer (Eastern Orthodox liturgics) |publisher=Cassell & The European Province of the Society of Saint Francis |year=1992 |isbn=0-264-67284-4 }}</ref>

====Loans====

Many loans are recorded in writings from the classical age, although a very small proportion were provided by banks. Provision of these were likely an occurrence of Athens, with loans known to have been provided at some time at an annual interest of 12%. Within the boundaries of Athens, bankers' loans are recorded as having been issued on eleven occasions altogether (Bogaert 1968).<ref name="Paul Millett">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=0IriOXQSe5QC&q=Ancient+banking&pg=PA9 |author=P Millett| title=Lending and Borrowing in Ancient Athens|access-date=28 May 2012|publisher=Cambridge University Press, 9 May 2002|isbn=9780521893916|date=9 May 2002}}</ref><ref>DM Schaps – University of Michigan Press, 2004 Retrieved 17 July 2012 {{ISBN|047211333X}}</ref><ref> {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120711103111/http://www.oenb.at/en/ueber_die_oenb/geldmuseum/allg_geldgeschichte/antike/money_in_ancient_times.jsp |date=11 July 2012 }} Retrieved 29 May 2012</ref>

Banks sometimes made loans available confidentially, which is, they provided funds without being publicly and openly known to have done so. In addition, they kept depositors' names confidential as well. This intermediation ''per se'' was known as dia tes trapazēs, translated from Latin as "God will trap you".<ref name="Edward E. Cohen"/>

A loan was made by a Temple of Athens to the state during 433–427&nbsp;BCE.<ref>S L Budin (p. 113)</ref>

===Rome===
{{main|Banking in ancient Rome}}
]
Roman banking activities were a crucial presence within temples. For instance the minting of coins occurred within temples, most importantly the ] temple, though during the time of the Empire, public deposits gradually ceased to be held in temples, and instead were held in private depositories. Still, the ] inherited the mercantile practices from Greece (Parker).<ref name="Parker, W N"/><ref name="Temporini, Haase"/><ref name="David S. Landes, Joel Mokyr, William J. Baumol">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=6rw1fxYalfUC&q=Mesopotamian&pg=PA452|first=M. | last=Hudson|title=Entrepreneurs: From the Near Eastern Takeoff to the Roman Collapse ''within'' The Invention of Enterprise: Entrepreneurship from Ancient Mesopotamia to Modern Times | page=16 |publisher=], The Kauffman Foundation Series on Innovation and Entrepreneurship | date=26 February 2012 | isbn=978-1400833580 | access-date=8 September 2015}}</ref>

During 352&nbsp;BCE a rudimentary public bank (known as ''dēmosía trápeza'' <ref name="Brill Online ''Reference Works''">{{cite book |url=http://referenceworks.brillonline.com/entries/brill-s-new-pauly/trapezites-e1219020|author=Brill Online ''Reference Works''|title=Trapezites|date=October 2006|publisher=]|access-date=6 September 2015}}</ref>) was formed, with the passing of a consular directive to form a commission of ''mensarii'' to deal with debt in the impoverished lower classes. Another source shows banking practices during 325&nbsp;BCE when, on account of being in debt, the ] were required to borrow money, so newly appointed ''quinqueviri mensarii'' were commissioned to provide services to those who had security to provide, in exchange for money from the public treasury. Another source (J. Andreau) has the shops of banking of Ancient Rome firstly opening in the public forums during the period 318 to 310 BCE.<ref>Piotr Niczyporuk – published by the Central European Journal of Social Sciences and Humanities 2011 | 24(37) | 105-115 ''Studies in Logic, Grammar and Rhetoric'' (please see also the same source linked in full )</ref><ref name="Macleod">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Sm87AAAAcAAJ&q=Banking+in+Rome&pg=PA350 |author=H D Macleod |title=The theory and practice of banking, Volume 1 |publisher=Longmans, Green, 1855| access-date=9 April 2012|author-link=Henry Dunning Macleod |year=1855 }}</ref><ref name="Andreau"/>

In early ] deposit bankers were known as ''argentarii'' and at a later time (from the 2nd century CE onward) as ''nummularii'' (Andreau 1999 p.&nbsp;2) or ''mensarii''. The banking-houses were known as ''Taberae Argentarioe'' and ''Mensoe Numularioe''. They would set up their stalls in the middle of enclosed courtyards called ''macella'' on a long bench called a ''bancu'',{{citation needed|date=November 2019}} from which the words ''banco'' and ''bank'' are derived.<ref>{{Cite web|title=bank {{!}} Origin and meaning of bank by Online Etymology Dictionary|url=https://www.etymonline.com/word/bank|access-date=15 August 2020|website=www.etymonline.com|language=en}}</ref> As a money changer, the merchant at the ''bancu'' did not so much invest money as merely convert the foreign currency into the only legal tender in Rome—that of the Imperial Mint.<ref name="James William Gilbart">{{cite book |url=https://archive.org/details/historyandprinc00gilbgoog |page= |quote=Ancient banking. |author=J W Gilbart |title=The history and principles of banking: The laws of the currency, etc |publisher=G. Bell, 1866 | access-date=9 April 2012|author-link=James William Gilbart |year=1834 }}</ref><ref name="Macleod"/><ref name="Andreau">{{cite book |url=https://archive.org/details/bankingbusinessi00andr |url-access=registration |author=] (Director of Studies at the School of Higher study of the Social Sciences, Paris) |title=Banking and Business in the Roman World |publisher=Cambridge University Press, 14 October 1999| access-date=9 April 2012|isbn=9780521389327 |date=14 October 1999 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book | last = Matyszak | first = Philip | title = Ancient Rome on Five Denarii a Day | publisher=Thames & Hudson | year = 2007 | location = New York | page = 144 | isbn = 978-0-500-05147-4 }}</ref>

Operations of banking within Roman society were known as ''officium argentarii''. Statutes (125/126&nbsp;CE) of the Empire described "''letter from'' ''] to Quietus''" show rental monies to be collected from persons using land belonging to a temple and given to the temple treasurer, as decreed by Mettius Modestus, governor of Lycia and Pamphylia. A law, ''receptum argentarii'', obliged a bank to pay its clients debts under guarantee.<ref name="N. Benke">{{cite book |chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Ot8tAwitC7oC&q=argentarii&pg=PA226|author= Benke|first = N.|chapter=Gender and the Roman Law of Obligations |title = Obligations in Roman Law: Past, Present, and Future|publisher=University of Michigan Press|volume= 33 |series = Papers And Monographs Of The American Academy In Rome|isbn=978-0472118434|year=2012 |page = 226}}</ref><ref>A Chester Johnson, P Robinson Coleman-Norton, F Card Bourne – The Lawbook Exchange, Ltd., 1 October 2003 Retrieved 9 July 2012 {{ISBN|1584772913}}</ref><ref>B Burrell {{ISBN|9004125787}} p. 254</ref><ref>{{cite book|first = Reinhard |last =Zimmermann |page = 514|url = https://books.google.com/books?id=iFIT_NsmE7MC&q=argentarii&pg=PA514 |title = The Law of Obligations: Roman Foundations of the Civilian Tradition|publisher = Oxford University Press |date =1996 |edition = reprint, revised|isbn = 019876426X}}</ref>

] advocated the establishment of a state bank, funded by the sale of all the properties owned at the time by the state.<ref>{{cite book|first = Michael Ivanovitch|last = Rostovtzeff|url = https://books.google.com/books?id=6dgC37IqYW0C&q=state+bank+ancient+Egypt&pg=PA542|title = The Social & Economic History of the Roman Empire |page= 542|publisher= Biblo & Tannen Publishers |year =1926|isbn =0819621641}}</ref>

In the 4th century monopolies existed in ] and in the city of ] in Sardinia.<ref>Trade and Politics in Ancient Greece By Johannes Hasebroek (page 156) – Retrieved 14 July 2012</ref><ref>William Smith – Walton & Maberly, 1857 Retrieved 14 July 2012</ref>

The Roman empire at some time formalized the administrative aspect of banking and instituted greater regulation of financial institutions and financial practices. Charging ] on loans and paying interest on deposits became more highly developed and competitive. The development of Roman banks was limited, however, by the Roman preference for cash transactions. During the reign of the Roman emperor ] (260–268&nbsp;CE), there was a temporary breakdown of the Roman banking system after the banks rejected the flakes of copper produced by his mints. With the ascent of Christianity, banking became subject to additional restrictions, as the charging of interest was seen as immoral. With the decrease in economic activity after the fall of Rome and Islamic invasions, banking likely temporarily ended in Europe and was not revived until Mediterranean trade commenced again in the 12th century.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Glasner |first=David |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=JUgynjw4d_4C&pg=PA9 |title=Free Banking and Monetary Reform |date=1989-08-25 |publisher=Cambridge University Press |isbn=978-0-521-36175-0 |language=en}}</ref>

==Religious restrictions on interest==

Most early religious systems in the ancient Near East, and the secular codes arising from them, did not forbid ]. These societies regarded inanimate matter as alive, like plants, animals and people, and capable of reproducing itself. Hence if you lent 'food money', or monetary tokens of any kind, it was legitimate to charge interest.<ref>Johnson cites Fritz E. Heichelcheim: ''An Ancient Economic History'', 2 vols. (trans. Leiden 1965), i.104–566</ref> Food money in the shape of olives, dates, seeds or animals was lent out as early as {{circa|5000}} BCE, if not earlier. Among the ]ns, ], ] and ], interest was legal and often fixed by the state.<ref>]: ''A History of the Jews'' (New York: HarperCollins Publishers, 1987) {{ISBN|0-06-091533-1}}. pp. 172–173</ref>

===Judaism===

{{main|Loans and interest in Judaism|Jewish views of poverty, wealth and charity}}

The ] and later sections of the ] criticize interest-taking, but interpretations of the Biblical prohibition vary. One common understanding is that Jews are forbidden to charge interest upon loans made to other Jews, but obliged to charge interest on transactions with non-Jews. However, the Hebrew Bible itself gives numerous examples where this provision was evaded.

{{blockquote| ] 23:19 Thou shalt not lend upon interest to thy brother: interest of money, interest of victuals, interest of any thing that is lent upon interest.

] 23:20 Unto a foreigner thou mayest lend upon interest; but unto thy brother thou shalt not lend upon interest; that the LORD thy God may bless thee in all that thou puttest thy hand unto, in the land whither thou goest in to possess it.<ref>The Hebrew Bible in English
according to the JPS 1917 Edition. http://www.mechon-mamre.org/e/et/et0523.htm</ref>}}

] in ''Passionary of Christ and Antichrist''<ref>The references cited in the Passionary for this woodcut: {{bibleverse|1|John|2:14–16|9}}, {{bibleverse || Matthew|10:8|9}}, and {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100715152441/http://www.bookofconcord.com/defense_6_church.php |date=15 July 2010 }}</ref>]]
In general, it was seen as advantageous to avoid debt at all, to avoid being bound to someone else. Debt was to be avoided and not used to finance consumption, except when in need. However, laws against usury were among many the prophets condemned the people for breaking.<ref>Examples of debt:{{bibleverse|1|Samuel|22:2|NIV}}, {{bibleverse|2|Kings|4:1|NIV}}, Isaiah 50:1. Prophetic condemnation of usury: Ezekiel 22:12, Nehemiah 5:7 and 12:13. Cautions regarding debt: Prov 22:7, passim.</ref>

The interpretation that interest could be charged to non-Israelites would be used in the 14th century for Jews living within Christian societies in Europe to justify lending money for profit. This conveniently side stepped the rules against usury in both Judaism and Christianity, as Christians were not involved in the lending but were still free to take the loans.{{fact|date=November 2023}}

===Christianity===

{{main|Usury|Christian views on poverty and wealth|Christian finance}}
Originally, the charging of interest, known as ], was banned by Christian churches. This included charging a fee for the use of money, such as at a ]. However over time the charging of interest became acceptable due to the changing nature of money, and the term 'usury' came to be used for charging interest above the rate allowed by law.{{citation needed|date=May 2012}} The notion of "]" refers to banking and financial activities that came into existence several centuries ago. Despite the prohibition of ] and the Church's distrust towards exchange activities (as opposed to production activities),<ref>J. Le Goff, Marchands et banquiers au Moyen Âge, Puf Quadrige, 2011, p. 75</ref> a number of operations of a banking or financial nature are evidenced by the activities of the ] (12th century), ] (appeared in 1462) and the ] attached directly to the Vatican (money loans, guarantees, issuance of securities, investments, etc.)

The rise of ] in the 16th century weakened Rome's influence, and its dictates against usury became irrelevant in some areas, freeing up the development of banking in Northern Europe. In the late 18th century, Protestant merchant families began to move into banking to an increasing degree, especially in trading countries such as the United Kingdom (]), Germany (], ]) and the Netherlands (], ]). At the same time, new types of financial activities broadened the scope of banking far beyond its origins. One school of thought attributes to ] the setting of the stage for the later development of capitalism in northern Europe.<ref name="aura.abdn.ac.uk">{{cite journal | last1 = McKinnon | first1 = AM | year = 2010 | title = Elective affinities of the Protestant ethic: Weber and the chemistry of capitalism | url = http://aura.abdn.ac.uk/bitstream/2164/3035/1/McKinnon_Elective_Affinities_final_non_format.pdf | journal = Sociological Theory | volume = 28 | issue = 1| pages = 108–126 | doi=10.1111/j.1467-9558.2009.01367.x| hdl = 2164/3035 | s2cid = 144579790 | hdl-access = free }}</ref> In this view, elements of Calvinism represented a revolt against the medieval condemnation of usury and, implicitly, of profit in general. Such a connection was advanced in influential works by R. H. Tawney (1880–1962) and by ] (1864–1920). According to Weber, the ] was a force behind an unplanned and uncoordinated ] that influenced the development of ].

] propounds the theory that Christian rationality is the primary driver behind the success of capitalism and the Rise of the West.<ref>{{cite book |title=The Victory of Reason: How Christianity Led to Freedom, Capitalism, and Western Success|first=Rodney|last=Stark|location=New York |publisher=Random House |year=2005 |isbn=1-4000-6228-4|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Q9j6OoeWqK4C&q=Christianity+capitalism}}</ref>

===Islam===

{{main|Riba}}
The ] strictly prohibits lending money on Interest."Believers! Have fear of Allah and give up all outstanding interest if you do truly believe. But if you fail to do so then be warned of war from Allah and His Messenger. If you repent even now you have the right of the return of your capital; neither will you do wrong nor will you be wronged."(2:278-279) "O you who have believed, do not consume usury, doubled and multiplied, but fear Allah that you may be successful" (3:130) "and Allah has permitted trade and has forbidden interest" (2:275).

The Quran states that taking interest and making money through unethical means was prohibited for Muslims and in other communities in earlier times as well: "Because of the wrongdoing of the Jews We forbade them good things which were (before) made lawful unto them, and because of their much hindering from Allah's way, And of their taking usury when they were forbidden it, and of their devouring people's wealth by false pretenses, We have prepared for those of them who disbelieve a painful doom." (Al Quran – 4:160–161)

'']'' is forbidden in ] (]). Islamic jurists discuss two types of riba: an increase in capital with no services provided, which the ] prohibits, and commodity exchanges in unequal quantities, which the ] prohibits. Trade in promissory notes (e.g. fiat money and derivatives) is forbidden.{{citation needed|date=May 2012}}

Despite the prohibition of charging interest, during the 20th century a number of developments took place that would lead to an ] model where no interest is charged but banks would still operate for profit. This was done through charging for loans in alternative ways such as through fees and using different methods of risk sharing and ownership models such as ].

==Medieval Europe==

The roots of modern banking are traceable to medieval and early Renaissance Europe, including Italy's ] in the 12th and 13th centuries, France's ] in the 13th century and in particular the rich Italian cities such as ], ], and ].<ref>{{Cite web |title=HISTORY OF BANKING |url=http://www.historyworld.net/wrldhis/PlainTextHistories.asp?ParagraphID=gkl |access-date=2023-03-22 |website=www.historyworld.net}}</ref>

===Emergence of merchant banks===

{{main|Merchant bank}}
] bankers in Europe in the 13th century]]
The original banks were "]s" that Italian grain merchants invented in the ]. As ] merchants and bankers grew in wealth and credit based on the strength of the ] plains cereal crops, many displaced Jews fleeing Spanish persecution were attracted to the trade. They brought with them ancient practices from the Middle and Far East which had financed the trans-Asian ]. They applied these methods to finance grain production and distribution.

Barred from owning land in Italy, Jews entered the great trading ]s and halls of Lombardy, alongside local traders, and set up their benches to trade in crops. They had one great advantage over the locals: Christians were strictly forbidden from the sin of ], lending at interest, which was also condemned in the Islamic world, but with less strictness. The Jewish newcomers, on the other hand, could make high-risk loans to farmers against crops in the field without direct jurisdiction by the Church.{{Citation needed|date=February 2011}} They then began to advance payment against the future delivery of grain shipped to distant ports. In both cases they made a profit from the present discount against the future price. This two-handed trade was time-consuming and soon there arose a class of merchants who were trading grain ] instead of grain.

The Jewish trader performed both financing (credit) and ] (]) functions. Financing took the form of a crop loan at the beginning of the growing season, which allowed a farmer to cultivate his annual crop, with the associated expenses of seeding, growing, weeding, and harvesting. Underwriting in the form of crop, or commodity, insurance guaranteed the delivery of the crop to its buyer, typically a merchant wholesaler. In addition, traders performed the merchant function by making arrangements to supply the buyer with the crop through alternative sources—grain stores or alternate markets, for instance—in the event of crop failure. He could also keep the farmer (or other commodity producer) in business during a drought or other ], through the issuance of crop (or commodity) insurance against the hazard of crop failure.

Merchant banking progressed from financing trade on one's own behalf to settling trades for others, and then to holding deposits for settlement of "billette" or notes written by the people who were still brokering the actual grain. And so the merchant's "benches" (''bank'' is derived from the Italian for bench, ''{{Lang|it|banca}}'', as in a ]) in the great grain markets became centres for holding money against a ] (''billette'', a note, a letter of formal exchange, later a ] and later still a ]).

These deposited funds were intended to be held for the settlement of grain trades, but often were used for the bench's own trades in the meantime. The term bankrupt is a corruption of the Italian {{Lang|it|banca rotta}}, or broken bench, the symbolic ruin of an insolvent trader. The expression of "being broke" has a similar etymology.

===Crusades===

] in chain mail carrying the Holy Lance in one of the battles of the ]]]
In the 12th century, the need to transfer large sums of money to finance the ] stimulated the re-emergence of banking in western Europe. In 1162, ] levied the first of a series of taxes to support the crusades. The ] and ] Christian knights acted as Henry's bankers in the Holy Land. It is ]'s decree that allowed the success of the Templar. This decree freed the Templar from paying tithe to the church and also granted them the ability to collect tithe for their own profit.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Medievalists.net |date=2021-08-22 |title=Templar Banking: How to go from Donated Rags to Vast Riches |url=https://www.medievalists.net/2021/08/templar-banking/ |access-date=2024-04-29 |website=Medievalists.net |language=en-US}}</ref> The Templars' rich land holdings across Europe also emerged during 1100–1300 as the beginning of Europe-wide banking. They took in local currency and issued demand notes redeemable at any of their castles across Europe, allowing movement of money without the usual risk of robbery while traveling. It is unclear if the Templar Knights used any hidden codes or encryptions to protect the notes given from any possible fraud.<ref>{{Cite news |date=2017-01-30 |title=The warrior monks who invented banking |url=https://www.bbc.com/news/business-38499883 |access-date=2024-04-23 |work=BBC News |language=en-GB}}</ref>

===Discounting of interest===

To circumvent the moral prohibition on ], directly paying money for the use of money, the practice of ] developed, in theory giving depositors an interest (part ownership) in the trades performed with their money. Similar methods had long been employed in Islamic banking.

Medieval trade fairs, such as the one in ], contributed to the growth of banking{{When|date=April 2015}} in a curious way: moneychangers issued documents redeemable at other fairs, in exchange for hard currency. These documents could be cashed at another fair in a different country or at a future fair in the same location. If redeemable at a future date, they would often be ] by an amount comparable to a rate of interest. Eventually,{{When|date=April 2015}} these documents evolved into ], which could be redeemed at any office of the issuing banker. These bills made it possible to transfer large sums of money without the complications of hauling large chests of gold protected by armed guards.

===Italian bankers===
]
The ], sometimes mistakenly credited with establishing a ] in the 12th century, did not formally create a public bank until 1587. However in the 13th and 14th centuries its Grain Office did a banking business that included both deposits and lending.<ref name="ugolini">{{cite book|last=Ugolini|first=Stefano|year=2017|title=The Evolution of Central Banking: Theory and History}}</ref> The Republic's system of transferable public debt has also been identified as an important contribution to the development of banking.<ref name="macleod">{{cite book|last=Macleod|first=Henry Dunning|year=1856|title=The Theory and Practice of Banking|volume=1}}</ref>

In the middle of the 13th century, groups of Christians, particularly the Italian ] and French ], invented ]s to get around the ban on Christian usury;<ref name="Jewish Encyclopedia">''Jewish Encyclopedia''</ref> for example, one method of effecting a loan with interest was to offer money without interest, but also require that the loan be insured against possible loss or injury, and/or delays in repayment (see ]).<ref name="Jewish Encyclopedia"/> The Christians utilizing these legal loopholes became known as the ''pope's usurers'', and reduced the importance of the Jews to European monarchs.<ref name="Jewish Encyclopedia"/> Later in the Middle Ages, a distinction evolved between consumable necessities such as food and fuel versus durable goods, with usury permitted on loans that involved the latter.<ref name="Jewish Encyclopedia"/>
]
The most powerful banking families came from Florence, including the ], Mozzi,<ref name="Kleinhenz">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=1piMMqjAf1MC&q=banking+failure+1255&pg=PA348|author=C Kleinhenz|title=Medieval Italy: An Encyclopedia, Volume 1|publisher=Routledge, 2004| access-date=14 July 2012|isbn=0415939305|year=2004}}</ref> ] and ] families, which established branches in many other parts of Europe.<ref name="Hoggson, N. F. 1926"/> Probably the most famous was the ] bank, set up by ] in 1397 <ref name="autogenerated1995"/> and continuing until 1494.<ref>] (Professor of Economics Emeritus at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology – 2006) Retrieved 17 May 2012</ref> The oldest banking firm in current operation is ] S.p.A. (BMPS).

By the later Middle Ages, Christian merchants who lent money with interest gained ecclesiastical sanction, and Jews lost their privileged position as money-lenders.<ref name="Jewish Encyclopedia"/> Italian bankers would take their place, and by 1327, Avignon had 43 branches of Italian banking houses. In 1347, ] ] on loans. Later there was the bankruptcy of the Bardi (1343<ref name="Kleinhenz"/>) and Peruzzi (1346<ref name="Kleinhenz"/>). The accompanying growth of Italian banking in France was the start of the ] moneychangers in Europe, who moved from city to city along the busy pilgrim routes important for trade. Key cities in this period were ], the birthplace of Pope John XXII, and ].

] ''Stultifera Navis'' (]); ] attributed to ]]]

After 1400, the political turned somewhat against the Italian bankers. In 1401 King ] had some of them expelled. In 1403, ] prohibited them from taking profits in his kingdom. In 1409, ] imprisoned and then expelled Genoese bankers. In 1410, all Italian merchants were expelled from Paris. In 1407, the ],<ref name="H. C. Sleight, 1859">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=QxpOAAAAYAAJ&q=1407+Genoa+the+first+state-bank+of+deposit&pg=PA657|author=], ]|title=Merchants' magazine and commercial review, Volume 40|year=1859|publisher=F. Hunt, 1859}}</ref> the first state bank of deposit,<ref name="Braithwaite & Drahos"/><ref>2nd – Holdsworth, W. S. - 34 L. Q. Rev. 11 (1918) Retrieved 14 June 2012</ref> was founded in Genoa and was to dominate business in the Mediterranean.<ref name="Braithwaite & Drahos"/>

== 15th–17th centuries – Expansion ==

=== Italy ===

Between 1527 and 1572 a number of important banking family groups arose from the ] in northern Italy, such as the ], ] and ] families, who were especially influential and wealthy, the ], although perhaps less influential, and the Pinelli and the Lomellini.<ref>C Duggan – Cambridge University Press, 21 April 1994 Retrieved 14 July 2012 {{ISBN|0521408482}}</ref><ref>SB MacDonald, AL Gastmann – Transaction Publishers, 2004 Retrieved 14 July 2012 {{ISBN|0765808331}}</ref>

=== Spain and the Ottoman Empire ===

In 1401 the magistrates of ], then the capital of the ], established in the city the first replication of the Venetian model of exchange and deposit, the ] or ''Table of Exchange'', considered to be the first ] of Europe.<ref name="H. C. Sleight, 1831">{{cite book |url=https://archive.org/details/ageneralhistory00mcdugoog |page= |quote=Venice bank subscription fund. |author1=Thomas H. Goddard |author2=Alexander Hamilton |author3=George McDuffie |title=A general history of the most prominent banks in Europe:particularly the banks of England and France; the rise and progress of the Bank of North America; a full history of the late and present Bank of the United States |publisher=H. C. Sleight, 1831|year=1831 }}</ref><ref>Thomas Henry Dyer John Murray, 1861 Retrieved 14 May 2012</ref><ref></ref>

Halil Inalcik suggests that, in the 16th century, ] Jews (] from the House of Mendes) fleeing from Iberia introduced the techniques of European capitalism, banking and even the mercantilist concept of state economy to the Ottoman Empire.<ref>{{cite book |title=An economic and social history of the Ottoman Empire |first=Halil |last=Inalcik |publisher=Cambridge University Press |year=1997 |page=213 |isbn=9780521574563 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=1j-AtkBmn78C&q=Marrano+banking&pg=PA213}}</ref> In the 16th century, the leading financiers in Istanbul were Greeks and Jews. Many of the Jewish financiers were Marranos who had fled from Iberia during the period leading up to the ]. Some of these families brought great fortunes with them.<ref>{{cite book |title=Cities of the Middle East and North Africa: a historical encyclopedia |first1=Michael |last1=Dumper |first2=Bruce E. |last2=Stanley |publisher=ABC-CLIO|year=2007 |page=185 |isbn=9781576079195 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=3SapTk5iGDkC&q=Marrano+banking&pg=PA185}}</ref>
The most notable of the Jewish banking families in the 16th-century Ottoman Empire was the ] banking house of Mendes, which moved to Istanbul in 1552, under the protection of Sultan Suleiman the Magnificent. When Alvaro Mendes arrived in Istanbul in 1588, he is reported to have brought with him 85,000 gold ducats.<ref>{{cite book |title=An economic and social history of the Ottoman Empire, 1300–1914 |first1=Halil |last1=Inalcik |first2=Donald|last2=Quataert |publisher=Cambridge University Press |year=1994 |page=212|isbn=9780521343152 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=MWUlNdskNfIC&q=Marrano+banking&pg=PA212}}</ref> The Mendes family soon acquired a dominating position in the state finances of the Ottoman Empire and in commerce with Europe.<ref>{{cite book |title=Historic cities of the Islamic world|first=Clifford Edmund |last=Bosworth |publisher=BRILL |year=2007 |page=207|isbn=978-9004153882 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=UB4uSVt3ulUC&q=Marrano+banking&pg=PA207}}</ref>
]
They thrived in Baghdad during the 18th and 19th centuries under Ottoman rule, performing critical commercial functions such as moneylending and banking.<ref>{{cite book |title=Banking on Baghdad: inside Iraq's 7,000-year history of war, profit and conflict |first=Edwin |last=Black|publisher=John Wiley and Sons |year=2004 |page= |quote=Under Ottoman rule, during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, Jews continued to thrive, becoming part of the commercial and political ruling class. Like Christians, the Jews could engage in necessary commercial activities, such as moneylending and banking, that were proscribed for Moslems under Islamic law.|url=https://archive.org/details/bankingonbaghdad00edwi|url-access=registration |isbn=9780471708957 }}</ref> Like the ], the Jews could engage in necessary commercial activities, such as moneylending and banking, that were proscribed for Muslims under Islamic law.

===Court Jew===

{{main|Court Jew}}
]s were Jewish bankers or businessmen who lent money and handled the finances of some of the Christian European ], primarily in the 17th and 18th centuries.<ref name=dimont>{{cite book |last=Dimont |first=Max |title=Jews, God, and History |year=1962 |isbn=978-0-451-52940-4 |pages=273–4 |publisher=Signet Classic |author-link=Max Dimont}}</ref> Court Jews were precursors to the modern financier or ].<ref name=dimont /> Their jobs included raising revenues by ], negotiating loans, master of the mint, creating new sources for revenue, floating debentures, devising new taxes, and supplying the military.<ref name=dimont /><ref name=krefetz>{{cite book |last=Kreftz |first=Gerald |title=Jews and Money: The Myths and the Reality |year=1984 |isbn=978-0-89919-129-4 |page= |publisher=Ticknor & Fields |url=https://archive.org/details/jewsmoneymythsre0000kref/page/46 }}</ref> In addition, the court Jews acted as personal bankers for the nobility: They raised money to cover the noble's personal diplomacy and his extravagances.<ref name=krefetz />

Court Jews were skilled administrators and businessmen who received privileges in return for their services. They were most commonly found in Germany, Holland, and Austria, but also in Denmark, England, Hungary, Italy, Poland, Lithuania, Portugal, and Spain.<ref>Perry, p 131</ref><ref name=sombart>{{cite book |last=Sombart |first=Werner |title=The Jews and Modern Capitalism |year=1913 |pages=53–7 |isbn=978-0-217-35289-5 }}</ref> According to Dimont, virtually every duchy, principality, and palatinate in the ] had a court Jew.<ref name=dimont />
] of the ]]]

===Germany===

In the southern German realm, two great banking families emerged in the 15th century, the ] and the ]s. They came to control much of the European economy and to dominate international high finance in the 16th century.<ref>M Häberlein – University of Virginia Press, 12 March 2012 Retrieved 14 July 2012 {{ISBN|0813932440}}</ref><ref>C Duggan</ref><ref>History World</ref> The Fuggers built the first German social housing area for the poor in ], the ]. It still exists, but not the original Fugger Bank which lasted from 1487 to 1657.

Dutch bankers played a central role in establishing banking in the northern German city states. ] is the oldest bank in Germany and the world's second oldest, established in 1590 by Dutch brothers Hans and Paul Berenberg in Hamburg. The bank is still owned by the ].<ref>Price Waterhouse Coopers Financial Year Book FYB, 2009</ref>

===Netherlands===

{{further|Financial history of the Dutch Republic}}
In the 16th and 17th century, precious metals from the ], ], Japan and other locales were being imported into Europe, with corresponding ]. Thanks to the free coinage,{{clarify|date=February 2014}} the Bank of Amsterdam, and the heightened trade and commerce, the Netherlands attracted even more coin and bullion to be deposited in their banks. The concepts of ] and payment systems were further developed and spread to England and elsewhere.<ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.wachovia.com/file/checks_and_check_fraud.pdf |title=Guide to Checks and Check Fraud |publisher=] |page=4 |year=2003 |access-date=13 June 2011 |archive-date=28 September 2011 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110928041645/https://www.wachovia.com/file/checks_and_check_fraud.pdf |url-status=dead }}</ref>

===England===

{{further|Banking in the United Kingdom}}
In the City of London there were no banking houses operating in a manner recognized as so today until the 17th century,<ref>James Walvin 17 February 2011 British Broadcasting Corporation Retrieved 19 April 2012</ref><ref>British Banking History Society {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161109053128/http://www.banking-history.co.uk/history.html |date=9 November 2016 }} Retrieved 19 April 2012</ref> although the London ] was established in 1565.

==17th–19th centuries – The emergence of modern banking==

] was founded in 1609, painting by ]]]
By the end of the 16th century and during the 17th, the traditional banking functions of accepting deposits, ], ], and transferring funds were combined with the issuance of bank ] that served as a substitute for ] and ] coins.

New banking practices promoted commercial and industrial growth by providing a safe and convenient means of payment and a money supply more responsive to commercial needs, as well as by "discounting" business debt. By the end of the 17th century, banking was also becoming important for the funding requirements of the combative European states. This would lead on to government regulations and the first ]s. The success of the new banking techniques and practices in Amsterdam and London helped spread the concepts and ideas elsewhere in Europe.

===Goldsmiths of London===

{{see also|1=Goldsmiths, University of London#History|l1=History of Goldsmiths University, London|2=Goldsmith banker}}
Modern banking practice, including ] and the issue of ]s, emerged in the 17th century. At the time, wealthy merchants began to store their gold with the ]s of ], who possessed private vaults and charged a fee for their service. In exchange for each deposit of precious metal, the goldsmiths issued ]s certifying the quantity and purity of the metal they held as a bailee; these receipts could not be assigned, only the original depositor could collect the stored goods.

Gradually the goldsmiths began to lend the money out on behalf of the ]or, which led to the development of modern banking practices; ]s (which evolved into banknotes) were issued for money deposited as a loan to the goldsmith.<ref>Thus by the 19th century we find "n ordinary cases of deposits of money with banking corporations, or bankers, the transaction amounts to a mere loan or mutuum, and the bank is to restore, not the same money, but an equivalent sum, whenever it is demanded." Joseph Story, Commentaries on the Law of Bailments (1832, p. 66) and "Money, when paid into a bank, ceases altogether to be the money of the principal (see Parker v. Marchant, 1 Phillips 360); it is then the money of the banker, who is bound to return an equivalent by paying a similar sum to that deposited with him when he is asked for it." Lord Chancellor Cottenham, Foley v Hill (1848) 2 HLC 28.</ref>

These practices created a new kind of "money" that was actually debt, that is, goldsmiths' debt rather than silver or gold coin, a ] that had been regulated and controlled by the monarchy. This development required the acceptance in trade of the goldsmiths' promissory notes, payable on demand. Acceptance in turn required a general belief that coin would be available; and a ] normally served this purpose. Acceptance also required that the holders of debt be able to legally enforce an unconditional right to payment; it required that the notes (as well as drafts) be negotiable instruments. The concept of negotiability had emerged in fits and starts in European money markets, but it was well developed by the 17th century. Nevertheless, an Act of Parliament was required in the early 18th century (1704) to overrule court decisions holding that the goldsmiths' notes, despite the "customs of merchants", were not negotiable.<ref name="investandincome">{{cite web |url=http://www.investmentsandincome.com/banks-banking/banking_origin.html |title=Banking Origin and Development |publisher=Invest and Income |access-date=26 July 2011 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110808054731/http://www.investmentsandincome.com/banks-banking/banking_origin.html |archive-date=8 August 2011 |url-status=usurped}}</ref>

===The modern bank===

] of 1803 was handled by ] of London.]]
In 1695, the ] became one of the first banks to issue banknotes, the first being the short-lived banknotes issued by ] in 1661.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.britishnotes.co.uk/news_and_info/features/|title=A History of British Banknotes}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Geisst |first=Charles R. |title=Encyclopedia of American business history |year=2005 |location=New York |isbn=978-0-8160-4350-7 |page=39}}</ref> Initially, these were hand-written and issued on deposit or as a loan, and promised to pay the bearer the value of the note on demand in ]. By 1745, standardized printed notes ranging from £20 to £1,000 were being issued. Fully printed notes that did not require the name of the payee and the cashier's ] first appeared in 1855.<ref>{{Cite web |url=http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/banknotes/pages/about/history.aspx |title=A brief history of banknotes|access-date=17 December 2013}}</ref>

In the 18th century, services offered by banks increased. Clearing facilities, security investments, ]s and ] protections were introduced. ]s had been used since the 1600s in England and banks settled payments by direct courier to the issuing bank. Around 1770, they began meeting in a central location, and by the 1800s a dedicated space was established, known as a ]. The method used by the London clearing house involved each bank paying cash to an inspector and then being paid cash by the inspector at the end of each day. The first overdraft facility was set up in 1728 by the ].<ref>{{Cite web |url=http://www.eccount.com/financial-news/a-short-history-of-overdrafts/| title=A short history of overdrafts|publisher=eccount money|url-status=dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20131105155745/http://www.eccount.com/financial-news/a-short-history-of-overdrafts/#.UneWvFMqvp0|archive-date=5 November 2013}}</ref>

The number of banks increased during the ] and the growing international trade, especially in London. At the same time, new types of financial activities broadened the scope of banking. The merchant-banking families dealt in everything from ] ] to originating foreign ]. These new "merchant banks" facilitated trade growth, profiting from England's emerging dominance in seaborne shipping. Two immigrant families, ] and ], established merchant banking firms in London in the late 18th century and came to dominate world banking in the next century.

A great impetus to country banking came in 1797 when, with England threatened by war, the Bank of England suspended cash payments. A handful of Frenchmen landed in ], causing a panic. Shortly after this incident, Parliament authorised the Bank of England and country bankers to issue notes of low denomination.

====Chinese banking====

During the Qing dynasty, the private nationwide financial system in China was first developed by the ], with the creation of so-called "draft banks". The first draft bank ] was created around 1823 in Pingyao. Some large draft banks had branches in Russia, Mongolia and Japan to facilitate international trade. Throughout the 19th century, the central Shanxi region became the de facto financial centre of Qing China.

With the fall of the Qing dynasty, the financial centers gradually shifted to ], with western-style modern banks flourishing. Today, the financial centres in China are Hong Kong, Beijing, Shanghai and Shenzhen.

====Japanese banking====

In 1868, the ] government attempted to formulate a functioning banking system, which continued until some time during 1881. They emulated French models. The Imperial mint began using imported machines from Britain in the early years of the Meiji period.<ref name="Norio Tamaki">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=jJZVJz1YMzMC&q=Japanese+Banking|author=Norio Tamaki|title=Japanese Banking: A History, 1859-1959|publisher=Cambridge University Press|year=2005|isbn=9780521022330}}</ref><ref name="William M. Tsutsui">{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Qs-fmynkqqsC&q=Japanese+Banking&pg=PA159|author=William M. Tsutsui|title=Banking in Japan: The evolution of Japanese banking, 1868-1952 (p. xvi)|publisher=published by ] 1999, 255 pages, Routledge library of modern Japan|access-date=13 September 2015|isbn=9780415170123|year=1999}}</ref>

] was a formative figure of a later banking initiative.<ref name="Norio Tamaki"/>

===Development of central banking===
{{Main|Central bank}}

The ], established in 1401, is the first example of municipal, mostly public banks which pioneered central banking on a limited scale. It was soon emulated by the ] in the ], first established in 1407, and significantly later by the ] in the ] and by a network of institutions in ] that later consolidated into ]. Notable municipal central banks were established in the early 17th century in leading northwestern European commercial centers, namely the ] in 1609 and the ] in 1619.<ref>Quinn, Stephen; Roberds, William (2006), {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110503180739/http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=934871 |date=3 May 2011 }}, ], Working Paper 2006–13</ref> These institutions offered a public infrastructure for cashless international payments.<ref>Collins, Christopher. ''The Oxford Encyclopedia of Economic History, Volume 3. Banking: Middle Ages and Early Modern Period'', Oxford University Press, 2012, p. 223</ref>

The first national (as opposed to municipal) central bank was the Swedish central bank, known since 1866 as ], founded in ] in 1664 from the remains of the failed ].<ref> Riksbank.com {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080504165055/http://www.riksbank.com/templates/Page.aspx?id=9159|date=2008-05-04|df=y}}</ref> A generation later, the establishment of the ] was devised by ], following a 1691 proposal by ].<ref>{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=EkUTaZofJYEC&q=British+Parliamentary+reports+on+international+finance|title=Committee of Finance and Industry 1931 (Macmillan Report) description of the founding of Bank of England|quote="Its foundation in 1694 arose out the difficulties of the Government of the day in securing subscriptions to State loans. Its primary purpose was to raise and lend money to the State and in consideration of this service it received under its Charter and various Act of Parliament, certain privileges of issuing bank notes. The corporation commenced, with an assured life of twelve years after which the Government had the right to annul its Charter on giving one year's notice. Subsequent extensions of this period coincided generally with the grant of additional loans to the State."|access-date=10 May 2010|isbn=9780405112126|year=1979|publisher=Arno Press |archive-date=1 July 2023|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230701075449/https://books.google.com/books?id=EkUTaZofJYEC&q=British+Parliamentary+reports+on+international+finance|url-status=live}}</ref> A ] was granted on {{date|1694/07/27}} through the passage of the ].<ref>H. Roseveare, (1991, Longman), p. 34</ref> The bank was given exclusive possession of the government's balances, and was the only limited-liability corporation allowed to issue ]s.<ref>{{cite book|last=Bagehot|first=Walter|title=Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market (1873)|date=5 November 2010|publisher=Henry S. King and Co. (etext by Project Gutenberg)|location=London|url=http://www.gutenberg.org/ebooks/4359|access-date=24 January 2013|archive-date=9 May 2012|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120509060631/http://www.gutenberg.org/ebooks/4359|url-status=live}}</ref>{{page needed|date=October 2015}} In the early 18th century, a major experiment in national central banking failed in ] with ]'s ] in 1720-1721. A comparatively more successful attempt was the ] established by ] in 1782. The ], established in 1769 by ], was an outlier from the general pattern of early national central banks in that it was directly owned by the Imperial Russian government, rather than private individual shareholders. In the nascent ], ], as Secretary of the Treasury in the 1790s, set up the ] despite heavy opposition from ].<ref>Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. "A History of Central Banking in the United States" {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180929233339/https://www.minneapolisfed.org/about/more-about-the-fed/history-of-the-fed/history-of-central-banking |date=29 September 2018 }}</ref>

Central banks were established in many European countries during the 19th century.<ref>{{cite book|author=Clifford Gomez|title=Banking and Finance: Theory, Law and Practice|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_4Nkye6tpWcC&pg=PA100|year=2011|publisher=PHI|page=100|isbn=9788120342378|access-date=29 September 2018|archive-date=1 July 2023|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230701075943/https://books.google.com/books?id=_4Nkye6tpWcC&pg=PA100|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|author1=Michael D. Bordo|author2=Marc Flandreau|author3=Jan F. Qvigstad|title=Central Banks at a Crossroads: What Can We Learn from History?|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=cZ0rDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA2|year=2016|publisher=Cambridge UP|pages=1–17|isbn=9781107149663|access-date=29 September 2018|archive-date=1 July 2023|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230701075943/https://books.google.com/books?id=cZ0rDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA2|url-status=live}}</ref> Napoleon created the ] in 1800, in order to stabilize and develop the French economy and to improve the financing of his wars.<ref>{{cite book|author=Michael Stephen Smith|title=The Emergence of Modern Business Enterprise in France, 1800–1930|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=zs26hd5keYkC&pg=PA59|year=2006|publisher=Harvard UP|page=59|isbn=9780674019393|access-date=29 September 2018|archive-date=1 July 2023|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230701080153/https://books.google.com/books?id=zs26hd5keYkC&pg=PA59|url-status=live}}</ref> The Bank of France remained the most important Continental European central bank throughout the 19th century.{{cn|date=July 2023}} The ] was founded in 1812, soon after Finland had been taken over from Sweden by Russia to become a ].<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.suomenpankki.fi/en/suomen_pankki/tehtavat/Pages/history.aspx?hl=history|title=History|publisher=Bank of Finland|access-date=28 October 2014|url-status=dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20141028111153/http://www.suomenpankki.fi/en/suomen_pankki/tehtavat/Pages/history.aspx?hl=history|archive-date=28 October 2014}}</ref> Simultaneously, a quasi-central banking role was played by a small group of powerful family-run banking networks, typified by the ], with branches in major cities across Europe, as well as ] in Switzerland and ] in Germany.<ref>Niall Ferguson, ''The House of Rothschild: Volume 1: Money's Prophets: 1798–1848'' (1999).</ref><ref>Gabriele Teichmann, "Sal. Oppenheim jr. & Cie., Cologne." ''Financial History Review'' 1.1 (1994): 69–78, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180929194901/https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/financial-history-review/article/sal-oppenheim-jr-cie-cologne/2F1E283B5C787E2FC508A7F1ABA24A34 |date=29 September 2018 }}.</ref>

The 19th and early 20th centuries central banks in most of Europe and ] developed under the international ]. ] or ]s were common at the time.{{cn|date=July 2023}} Problems with collapses of banks during downturns, however, led to wider support for central banks in those nations which did not as yet possess them, for example in Australia.{{cn|date=July 2023}} In the United States, the role of a central bank had been ended in the so-called ] of the 1830s by President ].<ref>Bray Hammond, "Jackson's Fight with the 'Money Power{{'"}}. ''American Heritage'' (June 1956) 7#4: 9–11, 100–103.</ref> In 1913, the U.S. created the ] through the passing of ].<ref>Miklos Sebok, "President Wilson and the International Origins of the Federal Reserve System—A Reappraisal." ''White House Studies'' 10.4 (2011): 424–447.</ref>

Following ], the ] (EFO) of the ], influenced by the ideas of ] and other leading policymakers and economists of the time, took an active role to promote the independence of central bank, a key component of the economic orthodoxy the EFO fostered at the ]. The EFO thus directed the creation of the ] in ], ], ], and ], as well as comprehensive reforms of the ] and ]. Similar ideas were emulated in other newly independent European countries, e.g. for the ].<ref name=DeCecco>{{citation |title=Central Banking in Central and Eastern Europe: Lessons From the Interwar Years' Experience |author=Marcello De Cecco |year=1994 |publisher=International Monetary Fund |url=https://www.elibrary.imf.org/view/journals/001/1994/127/article-A001-en.xml |location=Washington DC}}</ref>

By 1935, the only significant independent nation that did not possess a central bank was ], which subsequently developed a precursor thereto in 1945 and the present ] twenty years later. After gaining independence, numerous African and Asian countries also established central banks or monetary unions. The ], which had been established during British colonial rule as a private company, was nationalized in 1949 following India's independence. By the early 21st century, most of the world's countries had a national central bank set up as a ] institution, albeit with widely varying degrees of independence.

===Rothschilds===

]
The ] pioneered international finance in the early 19th century. The family provided loans to the Bank of England and purchased government bonds in the stock markets.<ref>{{cite web |title=Rothschild: history of a London banking dynasty |website=] |date=4 February 2011 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230604002458/https://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/newsbysector/banksandfinance/8302288/Rothschild-history-of-a-London-banking-dynasty.html |archive-date=2023-06-04 |url-status=live |url=https://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/newsbysector/banksandfinance/8302288/Rothschild-history-of-a-London-banking-dynasty.html}}</ref> Their wealth has been estimated to possibly be the most in modern history.<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.investopedia.com/articles/insights/052416/top-10-wealthiest-families-world.asp|title = 10 of the Wealthiest Families in the World}}</ref> In 1804, ] began to deal on the ] in financial instruments such as foreign bills and government securities. From 1809 Rothschild began to deal in ], and developed this as a cornerstone of his business. From 1811 on, in negotiation with ] ], he undertook to transfer money to pay ]'s troops, on campaign in ] against ], and later to make subsidy payments to British allies when these organized new troops after Napoleon's disastrous ]. His four brothers helped co-ordinate activities across the continent, and the family developed a network of agents, shippers and couriers to transport gold—and information—across Europe. This private intelligence service enabled Nathan to receive in London the news of Wellington's victory at the ] a full day ahead of the government's official messengers.<ref>{{cite ODNB |first1=Victor |last1=Gray |first2=Melanie |last2=Aspey |chapter=Rothschild, Nathan Mayer (1777–1836) |title=Oxford Dictionary of National Biography |orig-year=2004 |edition=Online |date=May 2006 |chapter-url=http://www.oxforddnb.com/view/article/24162 |access-date=21 May 2007 |title-link=Oxford Dictionary of National Biography |doi=10.1093/ref:odnb/24162 }}</ref>

The Rothschild family were instrumental in supporting railway systems across the world and in complex government financing for projects such as the ]. The family bought up a large proportion of the property in ], London. Major businesses directly founded by Rothschild family capital include Alliance Assurance (1824) (now ]); ] (1845); ] (1873); Société Le Nickel (1880) (now ]); and Imétal (1962) (now ]). The Rothschilds financed the founding of ], as well as ] on his expeditions in Africa and the creation of the colony of ].<ref>Niall Ferguson, ''The House of Rothschild: Volume 2: The World's Banker: 1849–1999'' (2000)</ref>

The Japanese government approached the London and Paris families for funding during the ]. The London consortium's issue of Japanese ]s would total £11.5&nbsp;million (at 1907 currency rates).<ref name="Rothschild archive">Richard Smethurst, {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20070216130517/http://www.rothschildarchive.org/ib/articles/AR2006Japan.pdf |date=16 February 2007 }}. Retrieved 4 September 2007.</ref>

From 1919 to 2004 the Rothschilds' Bank in London played a role as place of the ].

===Napoleonic wars and Paris===

] had the goal of overtaking London to make Paris the premier financial center of the world, but the war in 1870 reduced the range of Parisian financial influence.<ref>Youssef Cassis and Éric Bussière, eds., ''London and Paris as International Financial Centres in the Twentieth Century'' (2005) ch 3</ref> Paris had emerged as an international center of finance in the mid-19th century second only to London.<ref>Alain Plessis, "The history of banks in France." in Pohl, Manfred, and Sabine Freitag, eds. ''Handbook on the history of European banks'' (Edward Elgar Publishing, 1994) pp: 185–296. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20181003050928/http://euro.fbf.fr/en/files/888HK2/History_banks_france_EN.pdf |date=3 October 2018 }}</ref> It had a strong national bank and numerous aggressive private banks that financed projects all across Europe and the expanding French Empire.

One key development was setting up one of the main branches of the ]. In 1812, ] arrived in Paris from Frankfurt, and set up the bank "De Rothschild Frères".<ref>Joan Comay, ''Who's who in Jewish History'' (2001) pp 305–14, 455</ref> This bank funded Napoleon's return from Elba and became one of the leading banks in European finance. The ] funded France's major wars and colonial expansion.<ref>Niall Ferguson, ''The House of Rothschild: Volume 2: The World's Banker: 1849-1999'' (1998) pp 82–84, 206–14, 297–300,</ref> The ], founded in 1796 helped resolve the financial crisis of 1848 and emerged as a powerful central bank. The ] (CNEP) was established during the financial crisis and the republican revolution of 1848. Its innovations included both private and public sources in funding large projects, and the creation of a network of local offices to reach a much larger pool of depositors.

===Building societies===

] were established as ]s owned by their members as ]s. The origins of the building society as an institution lie in late-18th century ]—a town which was undergoing rapid economic and physical expansion driven by a multiplicity of small metalworking firms, whose many highly skilled and prosperous owners readily invested in property.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Ashworth|first=Herbert|title=The Building Society Story|year=1980|publisher=Franey & Co.|location=London|isbn=0-900382-38-4|page=4}}; {{Cite book|last=Berg|first=Maxine|editor=Berg, Maxine|title=Markets and Manufacture in Early Industrial Europe|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=NfkNAAAAQAAJ|access-date=7 September 2010|year=1991|publisher=Routledge|location=London|isbn=0-415-03720-4|page=194|chapter=Commerce and Creativity in Eighteenth-Century Birmingham|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=NfkNAAAAQAAJ&pg=PA173}}</ref>

Many of the early building societies were based in ]s or ]s, which had become the focus for a network of clubs and societies for co-operation and the exchange of ideas among Birmingham's highly active citizenry as part of the movement known as the ].<ref>{{Cite book|last=Jones|first=Peter M.|title=Industrial Enlightenment: Science, technology and culture in Birmingham and the West Midlands, 1760–1820|year=2009|publisher=Manchester University Press|location=Manchester|isbn=978-0-7190-7770-8|page=65}}; {{Cite news|first=Carl|last=Chinn|title=Brum's building society origins|url=http://www.thefreelibrary.com/Brum's+building+society+origins-a0188990857|work=Birmingham Mail|publisher=Birmingham Post and Mail Ltd.|date=15 November 2008|access-date=6 September 2010}}</ref> The first building society to be established was ], founded by Richard Ketley, the landlord of the ''Golden Cross'' inn, in 1775.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.bsa.org.uk/consumer/factsheets/100009.htm|title=The History of Building Societies|access-date=6 September 2010|last=Rex|first=Simon|date=20 April 2010|publisher=Building Societies Association|archive-date=23 August 2013|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130823203217/http://www.bsa.org.uk/consumer/factsheets/100009.htm|url-status=dead}}; {{Cite book|last=Ashworth|first=Herbert|title=The Building Society Story|year=1980|publisher=Franey & Co.|location=London|isbn=0-900382-38-4|page=2}}</ref>

Members of Ketley's society paid a monthly subscription to a central pool of funds which was used to finance the building of houses for members, which in turn acted as ] to attract further funding to the society, enabling further construction.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Peterson|first=Christopher L.|date=July 2003|title=Truth, Understanding, and High-Cost Consumer Credit: The Historical Context of the Truth in Lending Act|journal=Florida Law Review|issue=55|pages=839–840}}</ref><ref>{{Citation|last=Clark|first=Peter|year=2002|title=British Clubs and Societies 1580–1800: The Origins of an Associational World|location=Oxford|publisher=Oxford University Press|page=129|isbn=0-19-924843-5|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=h18rP1hrNLQC&pg=PA129|access-date=20 November 2010}}</ref> The first outside the ] was established in ] in 1785.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Cleary|first=E. J.|title=The Building Society Movement|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=pajPAAAAMAAJ|access-date=7 September 2010|year=1965|publisher=Elek Books|location=London|oclc=11817434|pages=11–12|isbn=9780236311446}}</ref>

===Mutual savings bank===

]]]
]s also emerged at that time, as financial institutions chartered by government, without capital stock, and owned by their members who subscribe to common funds. The institution most frequently identified as the first modern savings bank was the "Savings and Friendly Society" organized by the ] in 1810, in Ruthwell, ]. Rev. Duncan established the small bank in order to encourage his working class congregation to develop thrift.

Another precursor to the modern savings bank originated in Germany, with ] and ] who developed ] models that led on to the ] movement. The traditional banks had viewed poor and rural communities as ] because of very small, seasonal flows of cash and very limited human resources. In the ] the concepts of cooperative banking spread through northern Europe and onto the US at the turn of the 20th century under a wide range of different names.

===Postal savings system===

{{main |Postal savings system}}
To provide depositors who did not have access to banks a safe, convenient method to save money and to promote saving among the poor, the postal savings system was introduced in ] in 1861. It was vigorously supported by ], then ], who saw it as a cheap way to finance the public debt. At the time, banks were mainly in the cities and largely catered to wealthy customers. Rural citizens and the poor had no choice but to keep their funds at home or on their persons. The original ] was limited to deposits of £30 a year with a maximum balance of £150. Interest was paid at the rate of two and one-half percent per year on whole pounds in the account.

Similar institutions were created in a number of different countries in Europe, North America, and Japan. One example was in 1881 the Dutch government created the Rijkspostspaarbank (State post savings bank), a postal savings system to encourage workers to start saving. Four decades later they added the Postcheque and ]dienst services allowing working families to make payments via post offices in the Netherlands.

==20th century==

The first decade of the 20th century saw the ] in the US, which led to numerous ] and became known as the bankers panic.

===Great Depression===

] early in the Great Depression]]
During the Crash of 1929 preceding the ], margin requirements were only 10%.<ref name="Margin Requirements">{{cite journal|last=Fortune|first=Peter|date=Sep–Oct 2000|title= Margin Requirements, Margin Loans, and Margin Rates: Practice and Principles – analysis of history of margin credit regulations – Statistical Data Included|journal=New England Economic Review|url= http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m3937/is_2000_Sept-Oct/ai_80855422/pg_5}}</ref> Brokerage firms, in other words, would lend $9 for every $1 an investor had deposited. When the market fell, brokers called in these loans, which could not be paid back. Banks began to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors attempted to withdraw their deposits en masse, triggering multiple ]s. Government guarantees and Federal Reserve banking regulations to prevent such panics were ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to the loss of billions of dollars in assets.<ref name="lhf-30s">{{cite web|access-date=22 May 2008|url=http://www.livinghistoryfarm.org/farminginthe30s/money_08.html|title=Bank Failures|publisher=Living History Farm|archive-url=http://webarchive.loc.gov/all/20090219185825/http://livinghistoryfarm.org/farminginthe30s/money_08.html|archive-date=19 February 2009|url-status=dead}}</ref> Outstanding debts became heavier, because prices and incomes fell by 20–50% but the debts remained at the same dollar amount. After the panic of 1929, and during the first 10 months of 1930, 744 US banks failed. By April 1933, around $7&nbsp;billion in deposits had been frozen in failed banks or those left unlicensed after the ].<ref>"Friedman and Schwartz, Monetary History of the United States", 352</ref>
]
Bank failures snowballed as desperate bankers called in loans that borrowers did not have time or money to repay. With future profits looking poor, ] and construction slowed or completely ceased. In the face of bad loans and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks became even more conservative in their lending.<ref name="lhf-30s"/> Banks built up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A ] developed and the downward spiral accelerated. In all, over 9,000 banks failed during the 1930s.

In response, many countries significantly increased ]. The U.S. established the ] in 1933, and passed the ], which separated ] and ]. This was to avoid more risky investment banking activities from ever again causing commercial bank failures.

===World Bank and the development of payment technology===

] to a customer, informing on the introduction of ]]]
] news report on the introduction of ] in Sydney. People could only receive $25 at a time and the bank card was sent back to the user at a later date.]]
During the post ] period and with the introduction of the ] in 1944, two organizations were created: the ] (IMF) and the ].<ref>{{Cite web |url=http://www.princeton.edu/~ies/IES_Essays/E192.pdf |title=Raymond F. Mikesell, ''The Bretton Woods Debates: A Memoir'', Essays in International Finance 192 (Princeton: International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University, 1994) |access-date=22 October 2014 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170618123931/http://www.princeton.edu/~ies/IES_Essays/E192.pdf |archive-date=18 June 2017 |url-status=dead }}</ref> Encouraged by these institutions, commercial banks started to lend to sovereign states in the third world. This was at the same time as inflation started to rise in the west. The ] was eventually abandoned in 1971 and a number of the banks were caught out and became bankrupt due to third world country debt defaults.

This was also a time of increasing use of technology in ]. In 1959, banks agreed on a standard for machine readable characters (]) that was patented in the United States for use with ], which led to the first automated reader-sorter machines. In the 1960s, the first ] (ATM) or cash machines were developed and first machines started to appear by the end of the decade.<ref>{{cite news| url = https://www.bloomberg.com/news/2013-03-27/how-the-atm-revolutionized-the-banking-business.html | title = How the ATM Revolutionized the Banking Business | newspaper = Bloomberg.com | publisher = ] | date = 27 March 2013}}</ref> Banks started to become heavy investors in computer technology to automate much of the manual processing, which began a shift by banks from large clerical staffs to new automated systems. By the 1970s the first ] started to develop that would lead to ]s for both international and domestic payments. The international ] payment network was established in 1973 and domestic payment systems were developed around the world by banks working together with governments.<ref>{{cite news|title=SWIFT History|url=http://www.swift.com/about_swift/company_information/swift_history.page?lang=en|publisher=]|access-date=22 October 2014|archive-date=26 December 2012|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121226183922/http://www.swift.com/about_swift/company_information/swift_history.page?lang=en|url-status=dead}}</ref>

===Deregulation and globalization===

]
Global banking and capital market services proliferated during the 1980s after ] of financial markets in a number of countries. The 1986 ']' in London allowing banks to access capital markets in new ways, which led to significant changes to the way banks operated and accessed capital. It also started a trend where retail banks started to acquire investment banks and stock brokers creating ]s that offered a wide range of banking services.<ref>{{cite news | title = In Depth – Big Bang | newspaper = ] | date= 29 October 2006 | url = http://www.ft.com/indepth/bigbang | access-date = 29 October 2006 | archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20061115010307/http://www.ft.com/indepth/bigbang| archive-date= 15 November 2006 | url-status= live}}</ref> The trend also spread to the US after much of the ] was repealed in 1999 (during the Clinton Administration), this saw US retail banks embark on big rounds of mergers and acquisitions and also engage in investment banking activities.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.sec.gov/news/press/2008/2008-230.htm|title=Chairman Cox Announces End of Consolidated Supervised Entities Program|work=press release 2008-230|publisher=SEC|access-date=14 March 2014|author=Chairman Cox|date=26 September 2008}}</ref>

Financial services continued to grow through the 1980s and 1990s as a result of a great increase in demand from companies, governments, and financial institutions, but also because financial market conditions were buoyant and, on the whole, bullish. Interest rates in the United States declined from about 15% for two-year U.S. Treasury notes to about 5% during the 20-year period, and financial assets grew then at a rate approximately twice the rate of the world economy.

This period saw a significant internationalization of financial markets. The increase of U.S. Foreign investments from Japan not only provided the funds to corporations in the U.S., but also helped finance the federal government.

The dominance of U.S. financial markets was disappearing and there was an increasing interest in foreign stocks. The extraordinary growth of foreign financial markets results from both large increases in the pool of savings in foreign countries, such as Japan, and, especially, the deregulation of foreign financial markets, which enabled them to expand their activities. Thus, American corporations and banks started seeking investment opportunities abroad, prompting the development in the U.S. of mutual funds specializing in trading in foreign stock markets.{{citation needed|date=October 2014}}

Such growing internationalization and opportunity in financial services changed the competitive landscape, as now many banks would demonstrate a preference for the "universal banking" model prevalent in Europe. ]s are free to engage in all forms of financial services, make investments in client companies, and function as much as possible as a "one-stop" supplier of both retail and wholesale financial services.<ref>, 18 September 2008, '']''</ref>

==21st century==

The early 2000s were marked by consolidation of existing banks and entrance into the market of other financial intermediaries: ]. Large corporate players were beginning to find their way into the financial service community, offering competition to established banks. The main services offered included ], pension, mutual, ] and ]s, loans and ] and ]. Indeed, by the end of 2001 the market capitalisation of the world's 15 largest financial services providers included four non-banks.{{citation needed|date=November 2019}}

The first decade of the 21st century saw the culmination of the technical innovation in banking over the previous 30 years and saw a major shift away from traditional banking to ]. Starting in 2015 developments such as ] made it easier for third parties to access bank transaction data and introduced standard API and security models.

The process of financial innovation also advanced enormously in the first few decades of the 21st century, increasing the importance and profitability of nonbank finance. Such profitability priorly restricted to the non-banking industry, has prompted the ] (OCC) to encourage banks to explore other financial instruments, diversifying banks' business as well as improving banking economic health. Hence, as the distinct financial instruments are being explored and adopted by both the banking and non-banking industries, the distinction between different financial institutions is gradually vanishing. For example, in 2020, the OCC muddled the distinction between traditional banking and the cryptocurrency ecosystem when it published a number of interpretive letters clarifying national banks' ability to custody cryptocurrency and provide banking services to cryptocurrency companies,<ref>{{Cite web|last=Office of the Comptroller of the Currency|date=July 22, 2020|title=Re: Authority of a National Bank to Provide Cryptocurrency Custody Services for Customers|url=https://www.occ.gov/topics/charters-and-licensing/interpretations-and-actions/2020/int1170.pdf|website=OCC.gov}}</ref> as well as use blockchain innovations like ]s as settlement infrastructure.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Office of the Comptroller of the Currency|date=January 4, 2021|title=OCC Chief Counsel's Interpretation on National Bank and Federal Savings Association Authority to Use Independent Node Verification Networks and Stablecoins for Payment Activities|url=https://www.occ.gov/news-issuances/news-releases/2021/nr-occ-2021-2a.pdf|website=OCC.gov}}</ref> In addition, in 2021, the OCC granted its first federal banking charter to ], a digital asset platform for institutions.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Office of the Comptroller of the Currency|date=January 13, 2021|title=OCC Conditionally Approves Conversion of Anchorage Digital Bank|url=https://www.occ.gov/news-issuances/news-releases/2021/nr-occ-2021-6.html|website=OCC.gov}}</ref>

===2007–2008 financial crisis===
], a UK bank]]
The ] caused significant stress on banks around the world. The failure of a large number of major banks resulted in government bail-outs. The collapse and fire sale of ] to ] in March 2008 and the collapse of ] in September that same year led to a credit crunch and global banking crises. In response governments around the world bailed-out, nationalised or arranged fire sales for a large number of major banks. Starting with the Irish government on 29 September 2008,<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.ntma.ie/IrishEconomy/bankGuaranteeScheme.php |title=Bank Guarantee Scheme & Recapitalisation |date=22 October 2008 |publisher=] |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090302085910/http://www.ntma.ie/IrishEconomy/bankGuaranteeScheme.php |archive-date=2 March 2009 }}</ref> governments around the world provided wholesale guarantees to underwriting banks to avoid panic of ] to the whole banking system. These events spawned the term ']' and resulted in a lot of discussion about the ] of these actions.

==Major events in the history of banking==

*1100 – ] run earliest European wide/Mideast banking until the 14th century.
*1397 – The ] of Florence is established in Italy and operates until 1494.
*1542 – ], the English Crown's policy of coin debasement during the reigns of ] and ].
*1553 – The first ], the ], was chartered in London.
*1602 – The ] was established by the ] for dealings in its printed stocks and bonds.
*1609 – The ] (Amsterdam Exchange Bank) was founded.
*1656 – The first European bank to use banknotes opened in Sweden for private clients, in 1668 the institution converted to a public bank.<ref> Statistical Society of London 1874 . Retrieved 15 May 2012</ref><ref>], Donald Eugene Smith, Charles Seymour C.A. Nichols Publishing Company, 1923 Retrieved 15 May 2012</ref><ref></ref>
*1690s – The ] was the first of the ] to issue permanently circulating ]s.
*1694 – The ] was founded to supply money to the English King.
*1695 – The Parliament of Scotland created the ].
*1716 – ] opened ] in France.
*1717 – Master of the ] ] established a new mint ratio between silver and gold that had the effect of driving silver out of circulation (]) and putting Britain on a ].
*1720 – The ] and John Law's ] failure caused a European financial crisis and forced many bankers out of business.
*1775 – The first ], ], was established in ].
*1782 – The ] opened.<ref name="Walter B. Wriston Archives"/>
*1791 – The ] was chartered by the United States Congress for 20 years.
*1800 – The ] establishes European wide banking.
*1800 – Napoleon Bonaparte founds the ] on 18 January.<ref name="Banque de France">{{cite web | url =http://www.banque-france.fr/en/banque-de-france/history/the-milestones/1800-creation-of-the-banque-de-france.html | title = history|author=Banque de France| access-date = 18 May 2012}}</ref><ref name="ReferenceA">Kindleberger – p. 12 (see : Sources)</ref>
*1811 – The Senate tied on a vote to renew the charter of the ] charter. Vice President George Clinton broke the tie and voted against renewal, and the bank was dissolved.
*1816 – The ] was chartered for 20 years. Difficulties financing the government during and after the ] overcame the resistance to central banking that lead to the expiration of the First Bank of the United States' charter five years earlier.
*1817 – The ] was established.<ref name="Walter B. Wriston Archives">{{cite web |url=http://dca.lib.tufts.edu/features/wriston/about/bankingtimeline.html |title=Walter B. Wriston Archives |publisher=Tufts University |access-date=14 May 2012 |archive-date=19 May 2012 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120519093222/http://dca.lib.tufts.edu/features/wriston/about/bankingtimeline.html |url-status=dead }}</ref>
*1818 – The first savings bank of Paris was established.<ref name="ReferenceA"/>
*1825 – ] in which 70 UK banks fail
*1862 – To finance the ], the federal government under U.S. President ] issued ] paper money, called "]".
*1874 – The ] was passed provided for the redemption of United States paper currency, in gold, beginning in 1879.
*1913 – The ] created the ], the central banking system of the United States, and granted it the legal authority to issue legal tender.
*1930–33 – In the wake of the ], 9,000 banks close, wiping out one third of the money supply in the United States.<ref>Hawkins, William, , ''The Washington Times'', 12 May 2008</ref>
*1933 – ] signed by U.S. President ] forbade ownership of gold coin, gold bullion, and gold certificates by US citizens beyond a certain amount, effectively ending the convertibility of US dollars into gold.
*1971 – The ] was a series of economic measures taken by U.S. President ] which canceled the direct convertibility of the United States dollar to gold by foreign nations. This essentially ended the existing ] of international financial exchange.
*1986 – The ] (deregulation of London financial markets) served as a catalyst to reaffirm London's position as a global centre of world banking.
*2007 – Start of the ] including a credit crunch that led to the failure and bail-out of a large number of the world's biggest banks.
*2008 – ] collapses, the largest bank failure in history up to that point.


==See also== ==See also==

{{Portal|Banks}}
{{div col}}
* ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ] *]
*]
* ]
*]
*]
* ]
*]
*]
*]
*]
*]
{{div col end}}

==References==

===Footnotes===

{{Reflist|2|group=nb}}

===Citations===

{{Reflist|30em}}

==Further reading==

*Andreades, Andreas Michael. ''History of the Bank of England'' (Routledge, 2013)
*]. ''Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialization: A Study in Comparative Economic History'' (1967)
*Cameron, Rondo et al. ''International Banking 1870–1914'' (1992)
*{{Cite book| isbn = 978-0-19-965862-6| editor1-last=Cassis |editor1-first=Youssef |editor2-last=Grossman |editor2-first=Richard S. |editor3-last=Schenk |editor3-first=Catherine R. | title = The Oxford Handbook of Banking and Financial History | date = 2016 |location=New York |publisher=Oxford University Press}}
*Feis, Herbert. ''Europe the World's Banker, 1870–1914'' (1930)
* ]. '']'' (2008).
* Ferguson, Niall. ''The House of Rothschild: Volume 2: The World's Banker: 1849-1999'' (2000)
*Grossman, Richard S. ''Unsettled Account: The Evolution of Banking in the Industrialized World Since 1800'' (Princeton University Press; 2010) 384 pages. Considers how crises, bailouts, mergers, and regulations have shaped the history of banking in Western Europe, the United States, Canada, Japan, and Australia.
*], '']'' (Princeton University Press, 1957)
*Hudson, Peter James. "On the History and Historiography of Banking in the Caribbean." ''Small Axe'' 18.1 43 (2014): 22–37.
*Jaffe, Steven H., and Jessica Lautin. ''Capital of Capital: Money, Banking, and Power in New York City'' (Columbia University Press, 2014)
*] – {{ISBN|0415378672}}
* Klebaner, Benjamin J. ''American commercial banking: A history'' (Twayne, 1990).
*Kobrak, Christopher, and ], eds. ''History and Financial Crisis: Lessons from the 20th Century'' (Routledge, 2014)
*Komai, Alejandro, and Gary Richardson. "A history of financial regulation in the USA from the beginning until today: 1789 to 2011." in ''Handbook of Financial Data and Risk Information I'' (2014): 385+.
* Lane, Nicholas. "The Fathers of English Banking." ''History Today'' (Mar 1953) 3#3 pp 190–199
* Meltzer, Allan H. ''A History of the Federal Reserve'' (2 vol. U of Chicago Press, 2010) on U.S.
* Michie, Ranald C. ''British Banking: Continuity and Change from 1694 to the Present'' (Oxford UP, 2016) 334 pp.
* Murphy, Sharon Ann. ''Other People's Money: How Banking Worked in the Early American Republic'' (2017)
*Neal, Larry. "How it all began: the monetary and financial architecture of Europe during the first global capital markets, 1648–1815." ''Financial History Review'' (2000) 7#2 pp: 117–140.
*], '']''.
*Soyeda, Juichi. ''A history of banking in Japan''


==External links== ==External links==

* '']'' by ].
{{wikiquote}}
* Rothbard, Murray N. / Richardson & Snyder. 1983. ''The Mystery of Banking'' .
*
* ]. ''Money: Whence It Came, Where It Went''
* at Encyclopedia.com
*


] ]
]
]

Latest revision as of 01:23, 28 November 2024

Detailed history of the formation of the bank

Part of a series on financial services
Banking
Types of banks Lists of banks
Accounts · Cards
Accounts
Transaction (checking / current)
Cards
Funds transfer
Terms
Related topics

The history of banking began with the first prototype banks, that is, the merchants of the world, who gave grain loans to farmers and traders who carried goods between cities. This was around 2000 BCE in Assyria, India and Sumer. Later, in ancient Greece and during the Roman Empire, lenders based in temples gave loans, while accepting deposits and performing the change of money. Archaeology from this period in ancient China and India also show evidences of money lending.

Many scholars trace the historical roots of the modern banking system to medieval and Renaissance Italy, particularly the affluent cities of Florence, Venice and Genoa. The Bardi and Peruzzi families dominated banking in 14th century Florence, establishing branches in many other parts of Europe. The most famous Italian bank was the Medici Bank, established by Giovanni Medici in 1397. The oldest bank still in existence is Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena, headquartered in Siena, Italy, which has been operating continuously since 1472. Until the end of 2002, the oldest bank still in operation was the Banco di Napoli headquartered in Naples, Italy, which had been operating since 1463.

Development of banking spread from northern Italy throughout the Holy Roman Empire, and in the 15th and 16th century to northern Europe. This was followed by a number of important innovations that took place in Amsterdam during the Dutch Republic in the 17th century, and in London since the 18th century. During the 20th century, developments in telecommunications and computing caused major changes to banks' operations and let banks dramatically increase in size and geographic spread. The 2007–2008 financial crisis led to many bank failures, including some of the world's largest banks, and provoked much debate about bank regulation.

Ancient authority

Further information: Economic history of the world and History of economics

The shift from a reliance on hunting and gathering of foods to agricultural practices, starting sometime after 12,000 BCE, resulted in increased stability of economic relations. Such changes in socio-economic conditions began approximately 10,000 years ago in the Fertile Crescent, about 9,500 years ago in northern China, about 5,500 years ago in Mexico, and approximately 4,500 years ago in the eastern parts of the United States.

Monetary

Ancient types of money known as grain-money and food cattle-money were used from around 9000 BCE as two of the earliest commodities used for purposes of bartering.

Anatolian obsidian as a raw material for Stone Age tools was being distributed from as early as about 12,500 BCE, and organized trading of it was occurring during the 9th millennium BCE (Cauvin; Chataigner 1989). Sardinia was one of the four main sites for sourcing the material deposits of obsidian within the Mediterranean; trade using obsidian was replaced during the 3rd millennium BCE by trade of copper and silver.

Record-keeping

Detailed account of raw materials and workdays for a basketry workshop. Clay, c. 2040 BCE (Ur III)
Further information: History of accounting § Ancient history, and History of accounting

Objects used for record keeping, "bulla" and tokens, have been recovered from within Near East excavations, dated to a period beginning 8000 BCE and ending 1500 BCE, as records of the counting of agricultural produce. Commencing in the late fourth millennia mnemonic symbols were in use by members of temples and palaces to record stocks of produce. Types of records accounting for trade exchanges of payments were first being made about 3200 BCE. The Code of Hammurabi, written on a clay tablet around 1700 BCE, describes the regulation of banking activity within the civilization (Armstrong); although still rudimentary, banking was well enough developed to justify laws governing banking operations. Later during the Achaemenid Empire (after 646 BCE), further evidence is found of banking practices in the Mesopotamia region.

Structural

By the 5th millennium BCE, the settlements of Sumer, such as Eridu, were formed around a central temple. In the fifth millennium, people began to build and live in the civilization of cities, providing a structure for the construction of institutions and establishments. Tell Brak and Uruk were two early urban settlements.

Earliest forms of banking

See also: Banker (ancient)

Asia

Mesopotamia and Persia

Further information: Mesopotamia § Economy and agriculture

Banking as an archaic activity (or quasi-banking) is thought to have begun as early as the latter part of the 4th millennium BCE, to the 3rd millennia BCE.

Among many other things, the Code of Hammurabi recorded interest-bearing loans.

Prior to the reign of Sargon I of Akkad (2335–2280 BCE) the occurrence of trade was limited to the internal boundaries of each city-state of Babylon and the temple located at the centre of economic activity therein; trade at the time for citizens external to the city was forbidden.

In Babylonia of 2000 BCE, people depositing gold were required to pay amounts as much as one sixtieth of the total deposited. Both the palaces and temple are known to have provided lending and issuing from the wealth they held—the palaces to a lesser extent. Such loans typically involved issuing seed-grain, with re-payment from the harvest. These basic social agreements were documented in clay tablets, with an agreement on interest accrual. The habit of depositing and storing of wealth in temples continued at least until 209 BCE, as evidenced by Antiochus III having ransacked or pillaged the temple of Aine in Ecbatana (Media) of gold and silver.

More information comes from the code commissioned by Hammurabi, king of Babylon c. 1792–1750 BCE. Law 100 stipulated that repayment of a loan by a debtor to a creditor was to be on a schedule with a maturity date specified in written contractual terms. Law 122 stipulated that a depositor of gold, silver, or other property must present all articles and a signed contract of bailment to a notary before depositing the articles with a banker, and Law 123 stipulated that a banker was discharged of any liability from a contract of bailment if the notary denied the existence of the contract. Law 124 stipulated that a depositor with a notarized contract of bailment was entitled to redeem the entirety of their deposit, and Law 125 stipulated that a banker was liable for replacement of deposits stolen while in their possession.

Cuneiform records of the house of Egibi of Babylonia describe the family's financial activities as having occurred sometime after 1000 BCE and ending sometime during the reign of Darius I. These records suggest a "lending house" (Silver 2002), a family engaging in "professional banking..." (Dandamaev et al. 2004), and economic activities similar to modern deposit banking. Another interpretation is that the family's activities are better described as entrepreneurship rather than banking (Wunsch 2007). The Murashu family apparently took part in providing credit (Moshenskyi 2008).

Asia Minor

Further information: Asia Minor

From the fourth millennium previously agricultural settlements began administrative activities.

The temple of Artemis at Ephesus was the largest depository of Asia. A pot hoard dated to 600 BCE was found in excavations by The British Museum during 1904. During the time of the cessation of the first Mithridatic war, the entire debt being held at the time was annulled by the council. Mark Antony is recorded to have stolen from the deposits on occasion. The temple served as a depository for Aristotle, Caesar, Dio Chrysostomus, Plautus, Plutarch, Strabo and Xenophon.

The temple to Apollo in Didyma was constructed sometime in the 6th century. A large sum of gold was deposited within the treasury at the time by king Croesus.

India

Main article: History of banking in India

In ancient India there are evidences of loans from the Vedic period (beginning 1750 BCE). Later during the Maurya dynasty (321–185 BCE), an instrument called adesha was in use, which was an order on a banker desiring him to pay the money of the note to a third person, which corresponds to the definition of a bill of exchange as we understand it today. During the Buddhist period, there was considerable use of these instruments. Merchants in large towns gave letters of credit to one another.

China

Main: History of banking in China

In ancient China, starting in the Qin dynasty (221–206 BCE), Chinese currency developed with the introduction of standardized coins that allowed easier trade across China, and led to development of letters of credit. These letters were issued by merchants who acted in ways that today we would understand as banks.

Ancient Egypt

Further information: Egypt § Government and economy

Some scholars suggest that the Egyptian grain-banking system became so well-developed that it was comparable to major modern banks, both in terms of its number of branches and employees, and in terms of the total volume of transactions. During the rule of the Greek Ptolemies, the granaries were transformed into a network of banks centered in Alexandria, where the main accounts from all of the Egyptian regional grain-banks were recorded. This became the site of one of the earliest known government central banks, and may have reached its peak with the assistance of Greek bankers.

According to Muir (2009) there were two types of banks operating within Egypt: royal and private. Documents made to show the banking of taxes were known as peptoken-records.

Greece

Trapezitica is the first source documenting banking (de Soto – p. 41). The speeches of Demosthenes contain numerous references to the issuing of credit (Millett p. 5). Xenophon is credited to have made the first suggestion of the creation of an organisation known in the modern definition as a joint-stock bank in On Revenues written c. 353 BCE

The city-states of Greece after the Persian Wars produced a government and culture sufficiently organized for the birth of a private citizenship and therefore an embryonic capitalist society, allowing for the separation of wealth from exclusive state ownership to the possibility of ownership by the individual.

According to one source (Dandamaev et al.), trapezites were the first to trade using money, during the 5th century BCE, as opposed to earlier trade which occurred using forms of pre-money.

Specific focus of funds

The earliest forms of storage utilized were the rudimentary money-boxes (ΘΗΣΑΥΡΌΣ) which were made similar in form to the construction of a bee-hive, and were found for example in the Mycenae tombs of 1550–1500 BCE.

Private and civic entities within ancient Grecian society, especially Greek temples, performed financial transactions. (Gilbart p. 3) The temples were the places where treasure was deposited for safe-keeping. The three temples thought the most important were the temple to Artemis in Ephesus, and temple of Hera within Samos, and within Delphi, the temple to Apollo. These consisted of deposits, currency exchange, validation of coinage, and loans.

The first treasury to the Apollonian temple was built before the end of the 7th century BCE. A treasury of the temple was constructed by the city of Siphnos during the 6th century.

Before the destruction by Persians during the 480 invasion, the Athenian Acropolis temple dedicated to Athena stored money; Pericles rebuilt a depository afterward contained within the Parthenon.

During the reign of the Ptolemies, state depositories replaced temples as the location of security-deposits. Records exist to show this having occurred by the end of the reign of Ptolemy I (305–284).

As the need for new buildings to house operations increased, construction of these places within the cities began around the courtyards of the agora (markets).

Geographical focus of banking activities

Athens received the Delian league's treasury during 454.

During the late 3rd and 2nd century BCE, the Aegean island of Delos became a prominent banking center. During the 2nd century, there were for certain three banks and one temple depository within the city.

Thirty-five Hellenistic cities had private banks during the 2nd century (Roberts – p. 130).

Of the settlements of the Greco-Roman world of the 1st century CE, three were of pronounced wealth and centres of banking: Athens, Corinth and Patras.

Loans

Many loans are recorded in writings from the classical age, although a very small proportion were provided by banks. Provision of these were likely an occurrence of Athens, with loans known to have been provided at some time at an annual interest of 12%. Within the boundaries of Athens, bankers' loans are recorded as having been issued on eleven occasions altogether (Bogaert 1968).

Banks sometimes made loans available confidentially, which is, they provided funds without being publicly and openly known to have done so. In addition, they kept depositors' names confidential as well. This intermediation per se was known as dia tes trapazēs, translated from Latin as "God will trap you".

A loan was made by a Temple of Athens to the state during 433–427 BCE.

Rome

Main article: Banking in ancient Rome
Gold coin produced by the Roman Imperial Mint

Roman banking activities were a crucial presence within temples. For instance the minting of coins occurred within temples, most importantly the Juno Moneta temple, though during the time of the Empire, public deposits gradually ceased to be held in temples, and instead were held in private depositories. Still, the Roman Empire inherited the mercantile practices from Greece (Parker).

During 352 BCE a rudimentary public bank (known as dēmosía trápeza ) was formed, with the passing of a consular directive to form a commission of mensarii to deal with debt in the impoverished lower classes. Another source shows banking practices during 325 BCE when, on account of being in debt, the Plebeians were required to borrow money, so newly appointed quinqueviri mensarii were commissioned to provide services to those who had security to provide, in exchange for money from the public treasury. Another source (J. Andreau) has the shops of banking of Ancient Rome firstly opening in the public forums during the period 318 to 310 BCE.

In early Ancient Rome deposit bankers were known as argentarii and at a later time (from the 2nd century CE onward) as nummularii (Andreau 1999 p. 2) or mensarii. The banking-houses were known as Taberae Argentarioe and Mensoe Numularioe. They would set up their stalls in the middle of enclosed courtyards called macella on a long bench called a bancu, from which the words banco and bank are derived. As a money changer, the merchant at the bancu did not so much invest money as merely convert the foreign currency into the only legal tender in Rome—that of the Imperial Mint.

Operations of banking within Roman society were known as officium argentarii. Statutes (125/126 CE) of the Empire described "letter from Caesar to Quietus" show rental monies to be collected from persons using land belonging to a temple and given to the temple treasurer, as decreed by Mettius Modestus, governor of Lycia and Pamphylia. A law, receptum argentarii, obliged a bank to pay its clients debts under guarantee.

Cassius Dio advocated the establishment of a state bank, funded by the sale of all the properties owned at the time by the state.

In the 4th century monopolies existed in Byzantium and in the city of Olbia in Sardinia.

The Roman empire at some time formalized the administrative aspect of banking and instituted greater regulation of financial institutions and financial practices. Charging interest on loans and paying interest on deposits became more highly developed and competitive. The development of Roman banks was limited, however, by the Roman preference for cash transactions. During the reign of the Roman emperor Gallienus (260–268 CE), there was a temporary breakdown of the Roman banking system after the banks rejected the flakes of copper produced by his mints. With the ascent of Christianity, banking became subject to additional restrictions, as the charging of interest was seen as immoral. With the decrease in economic activity after the fall of Rome and Islamic invasions, banking likely temporarily ended in Europe and was not revived until Mediterranean trade commenced again in the 12th century.

Religious restrictions on interest

Most early religious systems in the ancient Near East, and the secular codes arising from them, did not forbid usury. These societies regarded inanimate matter as alive, like plants, animals and people, and capable of reproducing itself. Hence if you lent 'food money', or monetary tokens of any kind, it was legitimate to charge interest. Food money in the shape of olives, dates, seeds or animals was lent out as early as c. 5000 BCE, if not earlier. Among the Mesopotamians, Hittites, Phoenicians and Egyptians, interest was legal and often fixed by the state.

Judaism

Main articles: Loans and interest in Judaism and Jewish views of poverty, wealth and charity

The Torah and later sections of the Hebrew Bible criticize interest-taking, but interpretations of the Biblical prohibition vary. One common understanding is that Jews are forbidden to charge interest upon loans made to other Jews, but obliged to charge interest on transactions with non-Jews. However, the Hebrew Bible itself gives numerous examples where this provision was evaded.

Deuteronomy 23:19 Thou shalt not lend upon interest to thy brother: interest of money, interest of victuals, interest of any thing that is lent upon interest. Deuteronomy 23:20 Unto a foreigner thou mayest lend upon interest; but unto thy brother thou shalt not lend upon interest; that the LORD thy God may bless thee in all that thou puttest thy hand unto, in the land whither thou goest in to possess it.

Christ drives the Usurers out of the Temple, a woodcut by Lucas Cranach the Elder in Passionary of Christ and Antichrist

In general, it was seen as advantageous to avoid debt at all, to avoid being bound to someone else. Debt was to be avoided and not used to finance consumption, except when in need. However, laws against usury were among many the prophets condemned the people for breaking.

The interpretation that interest could be charged to non-Israelites would be used in the 14th century for Jews living within Christian societies in Europe to justify lending money for profit. This conveniently side stepped the rules against usury in both Judaism and Christianity, as Christians were not involved in the lending but were still free to take the loans.

Christianity

Main articles: Usury, Christian views on poverty and wealth, and Christian finance

Originally, the charging of interest, known as usury, was banned by Christian churches. This included charging a fee for the use of money, such as at a bureau de change. However over time the charging of interest became acceptable due to the changing nature of money, and the term 'usury' came to be used for charging interest above the rate allowed by law. The notion of "Christian finance" refers to banking and financial activities that came into existence several centuries ago. Despite the prohibition of usury and the Church's distrust towards exchange activities (as opposed to production activities), a number of operations of a banking or financial nature are evidenced by the activities of the Knights Templar (12th century), Mounts of Piety (appeared in 1462) and the Apostolic Chamber attached directly to the Vatican (money loans, guarantees, issuance of securities, investments, etc.)

The rise of Protestantism in the 16th century weakened Rome's influence, and its dictates against usury became irrelevant in some areas, freeing up the development of banking in Northern Europe. In the late 18th century, Protestant merchant families began to move into banking to an increasing degree, especially in trading countries such as the United Kingdom (Barings), Germany (Schroders, Berenbergs) and the Netherlands (Hope & Co., Gülcher & Mulder). At the same time, new types of financial activities broadened the scope of banking far beyond its origins. One school of thought attributes to Calvinism the setting of the stage for the later development of capitalism in northern Europe. In this view, elements of Calvinism represented a revolt against the medieval condemnation of usury and, implicitly, of profit in general. Such a connection was advanced in influential works by R. H. Tawney (1880–1962) and by Max Weber (1864–1920). According to Weber, the Protestant work ethic was a force behind an unplanned and uncoordinated mass action that influenced the development of capitalism.

Rodney Stark propounds the theory that Christian rationality is the primary driver behind the success of capitalism and the Rise of the West.

Islam

Main article: Riba

The Quran strictly prohibits lending money on Interest."Believers! Have fear of Allah and give up all outstanding interest if you do truly believe. But if you fail to do so then be warned of war from Allah and His Messenger. If you repent even now you have the right of the return of your capital; neither will you do wrong nor will you be wronged."(2:278-279) "O you who have believed, do not consume usury, doubled and multiplied, but fear Allah that you may be successful" (3:130) "and Allah has permitted trade and has forbidden interest" (2:275).

The Quran states that taking interest and making money through unethical means was prohibited for Muslims and in other communities in earlier times as well: "Because of the wrongdoing of the Jews We forbade them good things which were (before) made lawful unto them, and because of their much hindering from Allah's way, And of their taking usury when they were forbidden it, and of their devouring people's wealth by false pretenses, We have prepared for those of them who disbelieve a painful doom." (Al Quran – 4:160–161)

Riba is forbidden in Islamic economic jurisprudence (fiqh). Islamic jurists discuss two types of riba: an increase in capital with no services provided, which the Qur'an prohibits, and commodity exchanges in unequal quantities, which the Sunnah prohibits. Trade in promissory notes (e.g. fiat money and derivatives) is forbidden.

Despite the prohibition of charging interest, during the 20th century a number of developments took place that would lead to an Islamic banking model where no interest is charged but banks would still operate for profit. This was done through charging for loans in alternative ways such as through fees and using different methods of risk sharing and ownership models such as leasing.

Medieval Europe

The roots of modern banking are traceable to medieval and early Renaissance Europe, including Italy's Lombards in the 12th and 13th centuries, France's Cahorsins in the 13th century and in particular the rich Italian cities such as Florence, Venice, and Genoa.

Emergence of merchant banks

Main article: Merchant bank
Map showing the penetration of Sienese bankers in Europe in the 13th century

The original banks were "merchant banks" that Italian grain merchants invented in the Middle Ages. As Lombardy merchants and bankers grew in wealth and credit based on the strength of the Lombard plains cereal crops, many displaced Jews fleeing Spanish persecution were attracted to the trade. They brought with them ancient practices from the Middle and Far East which had financed the trans-Asian silk routes. They applied these methods to finance grain production and distribution.

Barred from owning land in Italy, Jews entered the great trading piazzas and halls of Lombardy, alongside local traders, and set up their benches to trade in crops. They had one great advantage over the locals: Christians were strictly forbidden from the sin of usury, lending at interest, which was also condemned in the Islamic world, but with less strictness. The Jewish newcomers, on the other hand, could make high-risk loans to farmers against crops in the field without direct jurisdiction by the Church. They then began to advance payment against the future delivery of grain shipped to distant ports. In both cases they made a profit from the present discount against the future price. This two-handed trade was time-consuming and soon there arose a class of merchants who were trading grain debt instead of grain.

The Jewish trader performed both financing (credit) and underwriting (insurance) functions. Financing took the form of a crop loan at the beginning of the growing season, which allowed a farmer to cultivate his annual crop, with the associated expenses of seeding, growing, weeding, and harvesting. Underwriting in the form of crop, or commodity, insurance guaranteed the delivery of the crop to its buyer, typically a merchant wholesaler. In addition, traders performed the merchant function by making arrangements to supply the buyer with the crop through alternative sources—grain stores or alternate markets, for instance—in the event of crop failure. He could also keep the farmer (or other commodity producer) in business during a drought or other crop failure, through the issuance of crop (or commodity) insurance against the hazard of crop failure.

Merchant banking progressed from financing trade on one's own behalf to settling trades for others, and then to holding deposits for settlement of "billette" or notes written by the people who were still brokering the actual grain. And so the merchant's "benches" (bank is derived from the Italian for bench, banca, as in a counter) in the great grain markets became centres for holding money against a bill (billette, a note, a letter of formal exchange, later a bill of exchange and later still a cheque).

These deposited funds were intended to be held for the settlement of grain trades, but often were used for the bench's own trades in the meantime. The term bankrupt is a corruption of the Italian banca rotta, or broken bench, the symbolic ruin of an insolvent trader. The expression of "being broke" has a similar etymology.

Crusades

Adhemar de Monteil in chain mail carrying the Holy Lance in one of the battles of the First Crusade

In the 12th century, the need to transfer large sums of money to finance the Crusades stimulated the re-emergence of banking in western Europe. In 1162, Henry II of England levied the first of a series of taxes to support the crusades. The Templar and Hospitaller Christian knights acted as Henry's bankers in the Holy Land. It is Pope Innocent II's decree that allowed the success of the Templar. This decree freed the Templar from paying tithe to the church and also granted them the ability to collect tithe for their own profit. The Templars' rich land holdings across Europe also emerged during 1100–1300 as the beginning of Europe-wide banking. They took in local currency and issued demand notes redeemable at any of their castles across Europe, allowing movement of money without the usual risk of robbery while traveling. It is unclear if the Templar Knights used any hidden codes or encryptions to protect the notes given from any possible fraud.

Discounting of interest

To circumvent the moral prohibition on usury, directly paying money for the use of money, the practice of discounting developed, in theory giving depositors an interest (part ownership) in the trades performed with their money. Similar methods had long been employed in Islamic banking.

Medieval trade fairs, such as the one in Hamburg, contributed to the growth of banking in a curious way: moneychangers issued documents redeemable at other fairs, in exchange for hard currency. These documents could be cashed at another fair in a different country or at a future fair in the same location. If redeemable at a future date, they would often be discounted by an amount comparable to a rate of interest. Eventually, these documents evolved into bills of exchange, which could be redeemed at any office of the issuing banker. These bills made it possible to transfer large sums of money without the complications of hauling large chests of gold protected by armed guards.

Italian bankers

A 14th century manuscript depicting bankers in an Italian counting house

The Republic of Venice, sometimes mistakenly credited with establishing a Bank of Venice in the 12th century, did not formally create a public bank until 1587. However in the 13th and 14th centuries its Grain Office did a banking business that included both deposits and lending. The Republic's system of transferable public debt has also been identified as an important contribution to the development of banking.

In the middle of the 13th century, groups of Christians, particularly the Italian Lombards and French Cahorsins, invented legal loopholes to get around the ban on Christian usury; for example, one method of effecting a loan with interest was to offer money without interest, but also require that the loan be insured against possible loss or injury, and/or delays in repayment (see contractum trinius). The Christians utilizing these legal loopholes became known as the pope's usurers, and reduced the importance of the Jews to European monarchs. Later in the Middle Ages, a distinction evolved between consumable necessities such as food and fuel versus durable goods, with usury permitted on loans that involved the latter.

Coat of arms for the Medici family

The most powerful banking families came from Florence, including the Acciaiuoli, Mozzi, Bardi and Peruzzi families, which established branches in many other parts of Europe. Probably the most famous was the Medici bank, set up by Giovanni di Bicci de' Medici in 1397 and continuing until 1494. The oldest banking firm in current operation is Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena S.p.A. (BMPS).

By the later Middle Ages, Christian merchants who lent money with interest gained ecclesiastical sanction, and Jews lost their privileged position as money-lenders. Italian bankers would take their place, and by 1327, Avignon had 43 branches of Italian banking houses. In 1347, Edward III of England defaulted on loans. Later there was the bankruptcy of the Bardi (1343) and Peruzzi (1346). The accompanying growth of Italian banking in France was the start of the Lombard moneychangers in Europe, who moved from city to city along the busy pilgrim routes important for trade. Key cities in this period were Cahors, the birthplace of Pope John XXII, and Figeac.

Of Usury, from Brant's Stultifera Navis (the Ship of Fools); woodcut attributed to Albrecht Dürer

After 1400, the political turned somewhat against the Italian bankers. In 1401 King Martin I of Aragon had some of them expelled. In 1403, Henry IV of England prohibited them from taking profits in his kingdom. In 1409, Flanders imprisoned and then expelled Genoese bankers. In 1410, all Italian merchants were expelled from Paris. In 1407, the Bank of Saint George, the first state bank of deposit, was founded in Genoa and was to dominate business in the Mediterranean.

15th–17th centuries – Expansion

Italy

Between 1527 and 1572 a number of important banking family groups arose from the Genoese Republic in northern Italy, such as the Grimaldi, Spinola and Pallavicino families, who were especially influential and wealthy, the Doria, although perhaps less influential, and the Pinelli and the Lomellini.

Spain and the Ottoman Empire

In 1401 the magistrates of Barcelona, then the capital of the Principality of Catalonia, established in the city the first replication of the Venetian model of exchange and deposit, the Taula de canvi de Barcelona or Table of Exchange, considered to be the first public bank of Europe.

Halil Inalcik suggests that, in the 16th century, Marrano Jews (Doña Gracia from the House of Mendes) fleeing from Iberia introduced the techniques of European capitalism, banking and even the mercantilist concept of state economy to the Ottoman Empire. In the 16th century, the leading financiers in Istanbul were Greeks and Jews. Many of the Jewish financiers were Marranos who had fled from Iberia during the period leading up to the expulsion of Jews from Spain. Some of these families brought great fortunes with them. The most notable of the Jewish banking families in the 16th-century Ottoman Empire was the Marrano banking house of Mendes, which moved to Istanbul in 1552, under the protection of Sultan Suleiman the Magnificent. When Alvaro Mendes arrived in Istanbul in 1588, he is reported to have brought with him 85,000 gold ducats. The Mendes family soon acquired a dominating position in the state finances of the Ottoman Empire and in commerce with Europe.

Pompeius Occo (1483–1537) came from a northern German family and grew up in Augsburg. In 1511 he settled in Amsterdam as a representative of the Fugger banking house and business firm of Augsburg.

They thrived in Baghdad during the 18th and 19th centuries under Ottoman rule, performing critical commercial functions such as moneylending and banking. Like the Armenians, the Jews could engage in necessary commercial activities, such as moneylending and banking, that were proscribed for Muslims under Islamic law.

Court Jew

Main article: Court Jew

Court Jews were Jewish bankers or businessmen who lent money and handled the finances of some of the Christian European noble houses, primarily in the 17th and 18th centuries. Court Jews were precursors to the modern financier or Secretary of the Treasury. Their jobs included raising revenues by tax farming, negotiating loans, master of the mint, creating new sources for revenue, floating debentures, devising new taxes, and supplying the military. In addition, the court Jews acted as personal bankers for the nobility: They raised money to cover the noble's personal diplomacy and his extravagances.

Court Jews were skilled administrators and businessmen who received privileges in return for their services. They were most commonly found in Germany, Holland, and Austria, but also in Denmark, England, Hungary, Italy, Poland, Lithuania, Portugal, and Spain. According to Dimont, virtually every duchy, principality, and palatinate in the Holy Roman Empire had a court Jew.

Cornelius Berenberg of the Berenberg banking dynasty

Germany

In the southern German realm, two great banking families emerged in the 15th century, the Fuggers and the Welsers. They came to control much of the European economy and to dominate international high finance in the 16th century. The Fuggers built the first German social housing area for the poor in Augsburg, the Fuggerei. It still exists, but not the original Fugger Bank which lasted from 1487 to 1657.

Dutch bankers played a central role in establishing banking in the northern German city states. Berenberg Bank is the oldest bank in Germany and the world's second oldest, established in 1590 by Dutch brothers Hans and Paul Berenberg in Hamburg. The bank is still owned by the Berenberg dynasty.

Netherlands

Further information: Financial history of the Dutch Republic

In the 16th and 17th century, precious metals from the New World, Gold Coast, Japan and other locales were being imported into Europe, with corresponding price increases. Thanks to the free coinage, the Bank of Amsterdam, and the heightened trade and commerce, the Netherlands attracted even more coin and bullion to be deposited in their banks. The concepts of fractional-reserve banking and payment systems were further developed and spread to England and elsewhere.

England

Further information: Banking in the United Kingdom

In the City of London there were no banking houses operating in a manner recognized as so today until the 17th century, although the London Royal Exchange was established in 1565.

17th–19th centuries – The emergence of modern banking

The old town hall in Amsterdam where the Bank of Amsterdam was founded in 1609, painting by Pieter Saenredam

By the end of the 16th century and during the 17th, the traditional banking functions of accepting deposits, moneylending, money changing, and transferring funds were combined with the issuance of bank debt that served as a substitute for gold and silver coins.

New banking practices promoted commercial and industrial growth by providing a safe and convenient means of payment and a money supply more responsive to commercial needs, as well as by "discounting" business debt. By the end of the 17th century, banking was also becoming important for the funding requirements of the combative European states. This would lead on to government regulations and the first central banks. The success of the new banking techniques and practices in Amsterdam and London helped spread the concepts and ideas elsewhere in Europe.

Goldsmiths of London

See also: History of Goldsmiths University, London and Goldsmith banker

Modern banking practice, including fractional reserve banking and the issue of banknotes, emerged in the 17th century. At the time, wealthy merchants began to store their gold with the goldsmiths of London, who possessed private vaults and charged a fee for their service. In exchange for each deposit of precious metal, the goldsmiths issued receipts certifying the quantity and purity of the metal they held as a bailee; these receipts could not be assigned, only the original depositor could collect the stored goods.

Gradually the goldsmiths began to lend the money out on behalf of the depositor, which led to the development of modern banking practices; promissory notes (which evolved into banknotes) were issued for money deposited as a loan to the goldsmith.

These practices created a new kind of "money" that was actually debt, that is, goldsmiths' debt rather than silver or gold coin, a commodity that had been regulated and controlled by the monarchy. This development required the acceptance in trade of the goldsmiths' promissory notes, payable on demand. Acceptance in turn required a general belief that coin would be available; and a fractional reserve normally served this purpose. Acceptance also required that the holders of debt be able to legally enforce an unconditional right to payment; it required that the notes (as well as drafts) be negotiable instruments. The concept of negotiability had emerged in fits and starts in European money markets, but it was well developed by the 17th century. Nevertheless, an Act of Parliament was required in the early 18th century (1704) to overrule court decisions holding that the goldsmiths' notes, despite the "customs of merchants", were not negotiable.

The modern bank

The Louisiana Purchase of 1803 was handled by Francis Baring and Company of London.

In 1695, the Bank of England became one of the first banks to issue banknotes, the first being the short-lived banknotes issued by Stockholms Banco in 1661. Initially, these were hand-written and issued on deposit or as a loan, and promised to pay the bearer the value of the note on demand in specie. By 1745, standardized printed notes ranging from £20 to £1,000 were being issued. Fully printed notes that did not require the name of the payee and the cashier's signature first appeared in 1855.

In the 18th century, services offered by banks increased. Clearing facilities, security investments, cheques and overdraft protections were introduced. Cheques had been used since the 1600s in England and banks settled payments by direct courier to the issuing bank. Around 1770, they began meeting in a central location, and by the 1800s a dedicated space was established, known as a bankers' clearing house. The method used by the London clearing house involved each bank paying cash to an inspector and then being paid cash by the inspector at the end of each day. The first overdraft facility was set up in 1728 by the Royal Bank of Scotland.

The number of banks increased during the Industrial Revolution and the growing international trade, especially in London. At the same time, new types of financial activities broadened the scope of banking. The merchant-banking families dealt in everything from underwriting bonds to originating foreign loans. These new "merchant banks" facilitated trade growth, profiting from England's emerging dominance in seaborne shipping. Two immigrant families, Rothschild and Baring, established merchant banking firms in London in the late 18th century and came to dominate world banking in the next century.

A great impetus to country banking came in 1797 when, with England threatened by war, the Bank of England suspended cash payments. A handful of Frenchmen landed in Pembrokeshire, causing a panic. Shortly after this incident, Parliament authorised the Bank of England and country bankers to issue notes of low denomination.

Chinese banking

During the Qing dynasty, the private nationwide financial system in China was first developed by the Shanxi merchants, with the creation of so-called "draft banks". The first draft bank Rishengchang was created around 1823 in Pingyao. Some large draft banks had branches in Russia, Mongolia and Japan to facilitate international trade. Throughout the 19th century, the central Shanxi region became the de facto financial centre of Qing China.

With the fall of the Qing dynasty, the financial centers gradually shifted to Shanghai, with western-style modern banks flourishing. Today, the financial centres in China are Hong Kong, Beijing, Shanghai and Shenzhen.

Japanese banking

In 1868, the Meiji government attempted to formulate a functioning banking system, which continued until some time during 1881. They emulated French models. The Imperial mint began using imported machines from Britain in the early years of the Meiji period.

Masayoshi Matsukata was a formative figure of a later banking initiative.

Development of central banking

Main article: Central bank

The Taula de canvi de Barcelona, established in 1401, is the first example of municipal, mostly public banks which pioneered central banking on a limited scale. It was soon emulated by the Bank of Saint George in the Republic of Genoa, first established in 1407, and significantly later by the Banco del Giro in the Republic of Venice and by a network of institutions in Naples that later consolidated into Banco di Napoli. Notable municipal central banks were established in the early 17th century in leading northwestern European commercial centers, namely the Bank of Amsterdam in 1609 and the Hamburger Bank in 1619. These institutions offered a public infrastructure for cashless international payments.

The first national (as opposed to municipal) central bank was the Swedish central bank, known since 1866 as Sveriges Riksbank, founded in Stockholm in 1664 from the remains of the failed Stockholms Banco. A generation later, the establishment of the Bank of England was devised by Charles Montagu, 1st Earl of Halifax, following a 1691 proposal by William Paterson. A royal charter was granted on 27 July 1694 through the passage of the Tonnage Act. The bank was given exclusive possession of the government's balances, and was the only limited-liability corporation allowed to issue banknotes. In the early 18th century, a major experiment in national central banking failed in France with John Law's Banque Royale in 1720-1721. A comparatively more successful attempt was the Bank of Spain established by King Charles III in 1782. The Russian Assignation Bank, established in 1769 by Catherine the Great, was an outlier from the general pattern of early national central banks in that it was directly owned by the Imperial Russian government, rather than private individual shareholders. In the nascent United States, Alexander Hamilton, as Secretary of the Treasury in the 1790s, set up the First Bank of the United States despite heavy opposition from Jeffersonian Republicans.

Central banks were established in many European countries during the 19th century. Napoleon created the Banque de France in 1800, in order to stabilize and develop the French economy and to improve the financing of his wars. The Bank of France remained the most important Continental European central bank throughout the 19th century. The Bank of Finland was founded in 1812, soon after Finland had been taken over from Sweden by Russia to become a grand duchy. Simultaneously, a quasi-central banking role was played by a small group of powerful family-run banking networks, typified by the House of Rothschild, with branches in major cities across Europe, as well as Hottinguer in Switzerland and Oppenheim in Germany.

The 19th and early 20th centuries central banks in most of Europe and Japan developed under the international gold standard. Free banking or currency boards were common at the time. Problems with collapses of banks during downturns, however, led to wider support for central banks in those nations which did not as yet possess them, for example in Australia. In the United States, the role of a central bank had been ended in the so-called Bank War of the 1830s by President Andrew Jackson. In 1913, the U.S. created the Federal Reserve System through the passing of The Federal Reserve Act.

Following World War I, the Economic and Financial Organization (EFO) of the League of Nations, influenced by the ideas of Montagu Norman and other leading policymakers and economists of the time, took an active role to promote the independence of central bank, a key component of the economic orthodoxy the EFO fostered at the Brussels Conference (1920). The EFO thus directed the creation of the Oesterreichische Nationalbank in Austria, Hungarian National Bank, Bank of Danzig, and Bank of Greece, as well as comprehensive reforms of the Bulgarian National Bank and Bank of Estonia. Similar ideas were emulated in other newly independent European countries, e.g. for the National Bank of Czechoslovakia.

By 1935, the only significant independent nation that did not possess a central bank was Brazil, which subsequently developed a precursor thereto in 1945 and the present Central Bank of Brazil twenty years later. After gaining independence, numerous African and Asian countries also established central banks or monetary unions. The Reserve Bank of India, which had been established during British colonial rule as a private company, was nationalized in 1949 following India's independence. By the early 21st century, most of the world's countries had a national central bank set up as a public sector institution, albeit with widely varying degrees of independence.

Rothschilds

The Frankfurt terminus of the Taunus railroad, financed by the Rothschilds. Opened in 1840, it was one of Germany's first railroads.

The Rothschild family pioneered international finance in the early 19th century. The family provided loans to the Bank of England and purchased government bonds in the stock markets. Their wealth has been estimated to possibly be the most in modern history. In 1804, Nathan Mayer Rothschild began to deal on the London stock exchange in financial instruments such as foreign bills and government securities. From 1809 Rothschild began to deal in gold bullion, and developed this as a cornerstone of his business. From 1811 on, in negotiation with Commissary-General John Charles Herries, he undertook to transfer money to pay Wellington's troops, on campaign in Portugal and Spain against Napoleon, and later to make subsidy payments to British allies when these organized new troops after Napoleon's disastrous Russian campaign. His four brothers helped co-ordinate activities across the continent, and the family developed a network of agents, shippers and couriers to transport gold—and information—across Europe. This private intelligence service enabled Nathan to receive in London the news of Wellington's victory at the Battle of Waterloo a full day ahead of the government's official messengers.

The Rothschild family were instrumental in supporting railway systems across the world and in complex government financing for projects such as the Suez Canal. The family bought up a large proportion of the property in Mayfair, London. Major businesses directly founded by Rothschild family capital include Alliance Assurance (1824) (now Royal & SunAlliance); Chemin de Fer du Nord (1845); Rio Tinto Group (1873); Société Le Nickel (1880) (now Eramet); and Imétal (1962) (now Imerys). The Rothschilds financed the founding of De Beers, as well as Cecil Rhodes on his expeditions in Africa and the creation of the colony of Rhodesia.

The Japanese government approached the London and Paris families for funding during the Russo-Japanese War. The London consortium's issue of Japanese war bonds would total £11.5 million (at 1907 currency rates).

From 1919 to 2004 the Rothschilds' Bank in London played a role as place of the gold fixing.

Napoleonic wars and Paris

Napoleon III had the goal of overtaking London to make Paris the premier financial center of the world, but the war in 1870 reduced the range of Parisian financial influence. Paris had emerged as an international center of finance in the mid-19th century second only to London. It had a strong national bank and numerous aggressive private banks that financed projects all across Europe and the expanding French Empire.

One key development was setting up one of the main branches of the Rothschild family. In 1812, James Mayer Rothschild arrived in Paris from Frankfurt, and set up the bank "De Rothschild Frères". This bank funded Napoleon's return from Elba and became one of the leading banks in European finance. The Rothschild banking family of France funded France's major wars and colonial expansion. The Banque de France, founded in 1796 helped resolve the financial crisis of 1848 and emerged as a powerful central bank. The Comptoir National d'Escompte de Paris (CNEP) was established during the financial crisis and the republican revolution of 1848. Its innovations included both private and public sources in funding large projects, and the creation of a network of local offices to reach a much larger pool of depositors.

Building societies

Building societies were established as financial institutions owned by their members as mutual organizations. The origins of the building society as an institution lie in late-18th century Birmingham—a town which was undergoing rapid economic and physical expansion driven by a multiplicity of small metalworking firms, whose many highly skilled and prosperous owners readily invested in property.

Many of the early building societies were based in taverns or coffeehouses, which had become the focus for a network of clubs and societies for co-operation and the exchange of ideas among Birmingham's highly active citizenry as part of the movement known as the Midlands Enlightenment. The first building society to be established was Ketley's Building Society, founded by Richard Ketley, the landlord of the Golden Cross inn, in 1775.

Members of Ketley's society paid a monthly subscription to a central pool of funds which was used to finance the building of houses for members, which in turn acted as collateral to attract further funding to the society, enabling further construction. The first outside the English Midlands was established in Leeds in 1785.

Mutual savings bank

A page with a pre-printed table. It has handwritten entries showing amounts of deposits and withdrawals, and the balance. Each entry has a post office date stamp.
A customer's deposit book, for a Post Office Savings Account

Mutual savings banks also emerged at that time, as financial institutions chartered by government, without capital stock, and owned by their members who subscribe to common funds. The institution most frequently identified as the first modern savings bank was the "Savings and Friendly Society" organized by the Reverend Henry Duncan in 1810, in Ruthwell, Scotland. Rev. Duncan established the small bank in order to encourage his working class congregation to develop thrift.

Another precursor to the modern savings bank originated in Germany, with Franz Hermann Schulze-Delitzsch and Friedrich Wilhelm Raiffeisen who developed cooperative banking models that led on to the credit union movement. The traditional banks had viewed poor and rural communities as unbankable because of very small, seasonal flows of cash and very limited human resources. In the history of credit unions the concepts of cooperative banking spread through northern Europe and onto the US at the turn of the 20th century under a wide range of different names.

Postal savings system

Main article: Postal savings system

To provide depositors who did not have access to banks a safe, convenient method to save money and to promote saving among the poor, the postal savings system was introduced in Great Britain in 1861. It was vigorously supported by William Ewart Gladstone, then Chancellor of the Exchequer, who saw it as a cheap way to finance the public debt. At the time, banks were mainly in the cities and largely catered to wealthy customers. Rural citizens and the poor had no choice but to keep their funds at home or on their persons. The original Post Office Savings Bank was limited to deposits of £30 a year with a maximum balance of £150. Interest was paid at the rate of two and one-half percent per year on whole pounds in the account.

Similar institutions were created in a number of different countries in Europe, North America, and Japan. One example was in 1881 the Dutch government created the Rijkspostspaarbank (State post savings bank), a postal savings system to encourage workers to start saving. Four decades later they added the Postcheque and Girodienst services allowing working families to make payments via post offices in the Netherlands.

20th century

The first decade of the 20th century saw the Panic of 1907 in the US, which led to numerous runs on banks and became known as the bankers panic.

Great Depression

Crowd at New York's American Union Bank during a bank run early in the Great Depression

During the Crash of 1929 preceding the Great Depression, margin requirements were only 10%. Brokerage firms, in other words, would lend $9 for every $1 an investor had deposited. When the market fell, brokers called in these loans, which could not be paid back. Banks began to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors attempted to withdraw their deposits en masse, triggering multiple bank runs. Government guarantees and Federal Reserve banking regulations to prevent such panics were ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to the loss of billions of dollars in assets. Outstanding debts became heavier, because prices and incomes fell by 20–50% but the debts remained at the same dollar amount. After the panic of 1929, and during the first 10 months of 1930, 744 US banks failed. By April 1933, around $7 billion in deposits had been frozen in failed banks or those left unlicensed after the March Bank Holiday.

Senator Carter Glass and Rep. Henry B. Steagall (1933)

Bank failures snowballed as desperate bankers called in loans that borrowers did not have time or money to repay. With future profits looking poor, capital investment and construction slowed or completely ceased. In the face of bad loans and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks became even more conservative in their lending. Banks built up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A vicious cycle developed and the downward spiral accelerated. In all, over 9,000 banks failed during the 1930s.

In response, many countries significantly increased financial regulation. The U.S. established the Securities and Exchange Commission in 1933, and passed the Glass–Steagall Act, which separated investment banking and commercial banking. This was to avoid more risky investment banking activities from ever again causing commercial bank failures.

World Bank and the development of payment technology

1967 letter by the Midland Bank to a customer, informing on the introduction of electronic data processing
1969 ABC news report on the introduction of ATMs in Sydney. People could only receive $25 at a time and the bank card was sent back to the user at a later date.

During the post Second World War period and with the introduction of the Bretton Woods system in 1944, two organizations were created: the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. Encouraged by these institutions, commercial banks started to lend to sovereign states in the third world. This was at the same time as inflation started to rise in the west. The gold standard was eventually abandoned in 1971 and a number of the banks were caught out and became bankrupt due to third world country debt defaults.

This was also a time of increasing use of technology in retail banking. In 1959, banks agreed on a standard for machine readable characters (MICR) that was patented in the United States for use with cheques, which led to the first automated reader-sorter machines. In the 1960s, the first automated teller machines (ATM) or cash machines were developed and first machines started to appear by the end of the decade. Banks started to become heavy investors in computer technology to automate much of the manual processing, which began a shift by banks from large clerical staffs to new automated systems. By the 1970s the first payment systems started to develop that would lead to electronic payment systems for both international and domestic payments. The international SWIFT payment network was established in 1973 and domestic payment systems were developed around the world by banks working together with governments.

Deregulation and globalization

Bishopsgate in the City of London

Global banking and capital market services proliferated during the 1980s after deregulation of financial markets in a number of countries. The 1986 'Big Bang' in London allowing banks to access capital markets in new ways, which led to significant changes to the way banks operated and accessed capital. It also started a trend where retail banks started to acquire investment banks and stock brokers creating universal banks that offered a wide range of banking services. The trend also spread to the US after much of the Glass–Steagall Act was repealed in 1999 (during the Clinton Administration), this saw US retail banks embark on big rounds of mergers and acquisitions and also engage in investment banking activities.

Financial services continued to grow through the 1980s and 1990s as a result of a great increase in demand from companies, governments, and financial institutions, but also because financial market conditions were buoyant and, on the whole, bullish. Interest rates in the United States declined from about 15% for two-year U.S. Treasury notes to about 5% during the 20-year period, and financial assets grew then at a rate approximately twice the rate of the world economy.

This period saw a significant internationalization of financial markets. The increase of U.S. Foreign investments from Japan not only provided the funds to corporations in the U.S., but also helped finance the federal government.

The dominance of U.S. financial markets was disappearing and there was an increasing interest in foreign stocks. The extraordinary growth of foreign financial markets results from both large increases in the pool of savings in foreign countries, such as Japan, and, especially, the deregulation of foreign financial markets, which enabled them to expand their activities. Thus, American corporations and banks started seeking investment opportunities abroad, prompting the development in the U.S. of mutual funds specializing in trading in foreign stock markets.

Such growing internationalization and opportunity in financial services changed the competitive landscape, as now many banks would demonstrate a preference for the "universal banking" model prevalent in Europe. Universal banks are free to engage in all forms of financial services, make investments in client companies, and function as much as possible as a "one-stop" supplier of both retail and wholesale financial services.

21st century

The early 2000s were marked by consolidation of existing banks and entrance into the market of other financial intermediaries: non-bank financial institution. Large corporate players were beginning to find their way into the financial service community, offering competition to established banks. The main services offered included insurance, pension, mutual, money market and hedge funds, loans and credits and securities. Indeed, by the end of 2001 the market capitalisation of the world's 15 largest financial services providers included four non-banks.

The first decade of the 21st century saw the culmination of the technical innovation in banking over the previous 30 years and saw a major shift away from traditional banking to internet banking. Starting in 2015 developments such as open banking made it easier for third parties to access bank transaction data and introduced standard API and security models.

The process of financial innovation also advanced enormously in the first few decades of the 21st century, increasing the importance and profitability of nonbank finance. Such profitability priorly restricted to the non-banking industry, has prompted the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) to encourage banks to explore other financial instruments, diversifying banks' business as well as improving banking economic health. Hence, as the distinct financial instruments are being explored and adopted by both the banking and non-banking industries, the distinction between different financial institutions is gradually vanishing. For example, in 2020, the OCC muddled the distinction between traditional banking and the cryptocurrency ecosystem when it published a number of interpretive letters clarifying national banks' ability to custody cryptocurrency and provide banking services to cryptocurrency companies, as well as use blockchain innovations like stablecoins as settlement infrastructure. In addition, in 2021, the OCC granted its first federal banking charter to Anchorage Digital, a digital asset platform for institutions.

2007–2008 financial crisis

2007 bank run on Northern Rock, a UK bank

The 2007–2008 financial crisis caused significant stress on banks around the world. The failure of a large number of major banks resulted in government bail-outs. The collapse and fire sale of Bear Stearns to JPMorgan Chase in March 2008 and the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September that same year led to a credit crunch and global banking crises. In response governments around the world bailed-out, nationalised or arranged fire sales for a large number of major banks. Starting with the Irish government on 29 September 2008, governments around the world provided wholesale guarantees to underwriting banks to avoid panic of systemic failure to the whole banking system. These events spawned the term 'too big to fail' and resulted in a lot of discussion about the moral hazard of these actions.

Major events in the history of banking

See also

References

Footnotes

  1. The word "bank" reflects the origins of banking in temples. According to the famous passage from the New Testament, when Christ drove the money changers out of the temple in Jerusalem, he overturned their tables. Matthew 21.12. In Greece, bankers were known as trapezitai, a name derived from the tables where they sat. Similarly, the English word bank comes from the Italian banca, for bench or counter.

Citations

  1. ^ Hoggson, N. F. (1926) Banking Through the Ages, New York, Dodd, Mead & Company.
  2. ^ Goldthwaite, R. A. Banks, Places and Entrepreneurs in Renaissance Florence, (1995)
  3. Boland, Vincent (12 June 2009). "Modern dilemma for world's oldest bank". Financial Times. Retrieved 23 February 2010.
  4. R Marks was Richard and Billie Deihl Professor of History at Whittier College during 2000 (7 December 2006). The Origins of the Modern World: Fate and Fortune in the Rise of the West. Rowman & Littlefield, 7 December 2006. ISBN 9781461700005. Retrieved 1 June 2012.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  5. Rondo E. Cameron (1993). A Concise Economic History of the World: From Paleolithic Times to the Present. Oxford University Press, 11 March 1993. ISBN 9780195074451. Retrieved 1 June 2012.
  6. Ian Hodder – Religion in the Emergence of Civilization: Çatalhöyük as a Case Study Cambridge University Press, 30 August 2010 Retrieved 25 June 2012
  7. MA Dandamaev – A Political History of the Achaemenid Empire BRILL, 1989 Retrieved 15 July 2012
  8. Mario Liverani (4 December 2013). The Ancient Near East: History, Society and Economy. Routledge, 4 December 2013. ISBN 978-1134750849. Retrieved 12 February 2015. (p. 76 – "record-keeping & bulla"
  9. A Robinson (5 April 2010). Writing and Script: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford University Press, 1 October 2009. ISBN 978-0199567782. Retrieved 8 June 2012.
  10. H J Nissen; P Damerow; R K Englund (1993). Archaic bookkeeping. University of Chicago Press, 1993. ISBN 0226586596. Retrieved 8 June 2012.
  11. ^ M Liverani. Uruk: the first city. Translated by Z Bahrani; M Van de Mieroop. Equinox, 2006.
  12. A Kuhrt (1995). The Ancient Near East, C. 3000–330 BC, Volume 1. Routledge, 1995. ISBN 0415167639. Retrieved 16 June 2012.
  13. B Teissier (1 January 1984). Ancient Near Eastern Cylinder Seals from the Marcopoli Collection. University of California Press, 1984. ISBN 0520049276. Retrieved 16 June 2012.
  14. H Williams (5 April 2010). Building Type Basics for Banks and Financial Institutions. John Wiley & Sons, 5 April 2010. ISBN 978-0470278628. Retrieved 8 June 2012.
  15. D Schmandt-Besserat – Counting to Cuneiform University of Texas Press, 1992 ISBN 0292707835 Retrieved 8 June 2012
  16. ^ Moorey, P R S (1999). Ancient Mesopotamia :Materials and Industries The Archaeological Evidence. Eisenbrauns, 1 November 1999. ISBN 1575060426. Retrieved 8 June 2012.
  17. P Watson – The Great Divide: History and Human Nature in the Old World and the New Hachette UK, 12 January 2012 -Retrieved 9 June 2012
  18. Brian M. Fagan. World prehistory: a brief introduction. Prentice Hall, 2002.
  19. Ur, Jason A. 2007 Early Mesopotamian urbanism: a new view from the North. Antiquity 81(313): 585–600. – Retrieved 1 July 2012
  20. M. Chahin – The Kingdom of Armenia: A History Routledge, 2001 ISBN 0700714529
  21. ME Stevens Temples, Tithes, and Taxes: The Temple and the Economic Life of Ancient Israel Baker Academic, 2006 ISBN 0801047773
  22. N Luhmann – Risk: A Sociological Theory Transaction Publishers, 2005 ISBN 0202307646 (p. 181)
  23. Davies, R; Davies, G. A History of Money from Ancient Times to the Present Day. Cardiff: University of Wales Press, 1996.
  24. naissance de la banque universalis.fr Accessed 15 September 2018
  25. Chahin, M. – Before the Greeks James Clarke & Co., 1996 ISBN 0718829506 Retrieved 8 June 2012
  26. Beaudreau, B C – World Trade iUniverse, 13 September 2004 ISBN 0595778445 Retrieved 8 June 2012
  27. secondary references – + + +
  28. GW Bromiley – International Standard Bible Encyclopedia: A-D Wm. B. Eerdmans Publishing, 13 February 1995 Retrieved 14 July 2012 ISBN 0802837816
  29. the British Museum -image and information of a clay tablet showing practice from an earlier period Retrieved 9 April 2012
  30. Orsingher, R Translated by D.S.Ault. Banks of the World. Walker and Company New York. Retrieved 9 April 2012.
  31. G G Aperghis – The Seleukid Royal Economy: The Finances And Financial Administration Of The Seleukid Empire Cambridge University Press, 23 December 2004 ISBN 0521837073 Retrieved 10 June 2012
  32. A Holm -translated by F. Clarke- The History of Greece from Its Commencement to the Close of the Independence of the Greek Nation, Vol. 4 of 4 Macmillan & Co 1898 – ISBN 1440041237 Retrieved 10 June 2012
  33. C AnthonA Classical Dictionary: Containing an Account of the Principal Proper Names Mentioned in Ancient Authors and Intended to Elucidate All the Important Points Connected with Geography, History, Biography, Mythology, and Fine Arts of the Greeks and Romans; Together with an Account of Coins, Weights, and Measures, with Tabular Values of the Same Harper & Brothers, 1855 – Retrieved 10 June 2012
  34. W SmithDictionary of Greek and Roman geography, Volume 2 Walton & Maberly, 1857 – Retrieved 10 June 2012
  35. Encyclopædia Britannica shows is "... Hamadān, Iran ..." – Retrieved 10 June 2012
  36. Hammurabi (1903). "Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon". Records of the Past. 2 (3). Translated by Sommer, Otto. Washington, DC: Records of the Past Exploration Society: 75. Retrieved 20 June 2021. 100. Anyone borrowing money shall ... his contract .
  37. Hammurabi (1904). "Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon" (PDF). Liberty Fund. Translated by Harper, Robert Francis (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. p. 35. Retrieved 20 June 2021. §100. ...he shall write down ... returns to his merchant.
  38. ^ Hammurabi (1910). "Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon". Avalon Project. Translated by King, Leonard William. New Haven, CT: Yale Law School. Retrieved 20 June 2021.
  39. Hammurabi (1903). "Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon". Records of the Past. 2 (3). Translated by Sommer, Otto. Washington, DC: Records of the Past Exploration Society: 77. Retrieved 20 June 2021. 122. If anyone entrusts to ... have committed an offence.
  40. Hammurabi (1904). "Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon" (PDF). Liberty Fund. Translated by Harper, Robert Francis (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. p. 43. Retrieved 20 June 2021. §122. If a man give ... it from the thief.
  41. R Rollinger, C Ulf, K Schnegg – Commerce and Monetary Systems in the Ancient World: Means of Transmission and Cultural Interaction : Proceedings of the Fifth Annual Symposium of the Assyrian and Babylonian Intellectual Heritage Project, Held in Innsbruck, Austria, 3–8 October 2002 M Silver – Modern Ancients Franz Steiner Verlag, 2004 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 3515083790
  42. Gwendolyn Leick (ed.) – The Babylonian world C Wunsch – The Egibi Family Routledge 2007 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 1134261284
  43. MA Dandamaev, VG Lukonin, PL Kohl – The Culture And Social Institutions Of Ancient Iran Cambridge University Press, 11 November 2004 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 0521611911
  44. WI Davisson; JE Harper (1972). European Economic History. Appleton-Century-Crofts 1972. Retrieved 10 July 2012.
  45. JP Nielsen – Sons and Descendants: A Social History of Kin Groups and Family Names in the Early Neo-Babylonian Period ProQuest, 2008 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 054956926X
  46. OJ Thatcher – The Library of Original Sources: Volume I (The Ancient World) The Minerva Group, Inc., 30 June 2004 ISBN 141021401X translated by – TG Pinches Retrieved 10 July 2012
  47. RN Frye – Handbuch der Altertumswissenschaft, Part 3, Volume 7 C.H.Beck, 1984 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 3406093973
  48. S Moshenskyi – History of the Weksel Sergei Moshenskyi, 1 August 2008 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 1436306949
  49. KR Nemet-Nejat –Daily Life in Ancient Mesopotamia Greenwood Publishing Group, 1998 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 0313294976
  50. JA Thompson – The Bible and archaeology Paternoster Press, 1973 Retrieved 10 July 2012
  51. S R Steadman, G McMahon – The Oxford Handbook of Ancient Anatolia: (10,000–323 Bce) Oxford University Press, 5 September 2011 ISBN 0195376145 Retrieved 25 June 2012
  52. A. G. Sagona, Claudia Sagona – Archaeology at the North-east Anatolian Frontier, I.: An Historical Geography and a Field Survey of the Bayburt Province Peeters Publishers, 2004 ISBN 9042913908 Retrieved 25 June 2012
  53. secondary – Luc-Normand Tellier Urban World History: An Economic and Geographical Perspective PUQ, 2009 ISBN 2760515885 Retrieved 25 June 2012
  54. Catholic Encyclopedia New Advent Retrieved 25 June 2012
  55. Walter Augustus Hawley (1918). Asia Minor. Elibron.com. ISBN 9781402185458. Retrieved 3 June 2012.
  56. secondary – The British Museum Archived 4 November 2012 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 3 June 2012
  57. secondary – Dio Chrysostom Orations: 7, 12 and 36 (Edited by: D. A. Russell, St John's College, Oxford) Cambridge University Press 2012. Retrieved 3 June 2012
  58. The British Museum Archived 5 February 2015 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 3 June 2012
  59. J. Murphy-O'Connor is Professor of the New Testament at the Ecole Biblique et Archeologique Francaise, Jerusalem (2008) (2008). St. Paul's Ephesus: Texts and Archaeology. Liturgical Press, 2008. ISBN 978-0814652596. Retrieved 3 June 2012.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  60. secondary – N HookeThe Roman History, from the Building of Rome to the Ruin of the Commonwealth, Volume 3 G. Hawkins, W. Strahan, 1770. Retrieved 3 June 2012
  61. (p. 126) K Roberts →
  62. J Freely (4 September 2004). The Western Shores Of Turkey: Discovering The Aegean And Mediterranean Coasts. Tauris Parke Paperbacks, 4 September 2004. ISBN 1850436185. Retrieved 15 June 2012.
  63. The British Museum Archived 18 October 2015 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 16 June 2012
  64. C Gomez – Financial Markets Institutions And Financial Services Prentice-Hall 2008 Retrieved 11 July 2012 ISBN 8120335376
  65. A Chavez Irapta, Et Al – Introduction to Asia: History, Culture, and Civilization Rex Bookstore, Inc., 2005 Retrieved 11 July 2012
  66. "Evolution of Payment Systems in India =Reserve Bank of India". Archived from the original on 1 November 2014.
  67. Wagel, Srinivas (1915). Chinese currency and banking.
  68. "History of Money and Banking". Archived from the original on 25 February 2023. Retrieved 16 June 2020.
  69. John Muir (2009). Life and Letters in the Ancient Greek World. Routledge. pp. 80–81. ISBN 978-1134166015.
  70. Willy Clarysse; Dorothy J. Thompson (2006). Counting the People in Hellenistic Egypt: Historical Studies. Vol. 2. Cambridge University Press. p. 82. ISBN 9780521838399.
  71. ^ J Huerta de Soto – 1998 (translated by M.A.Stroup 2012) (2006). Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles. Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 1610161890. Retrieved 15 June 2012.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  72. ^ P Millett (9 May 2002). Lending and Borrowing in Ancient Athens. Cambridge University Press, 9 May 2002. ISBN 9780521893916. Retrieved 28 May 2012.
  73. ^ J W Gilbart (1834). The history and principles of banking: The laws of the currency, etc. G. Bell, 1866. p. 9. Retrieved 9 April 2012. Ancient banking.
  74. J S WatsonXenophon's Minor Works: Comprising the Agesilaus, Hiero, Oeconomicus, Banquet, Apology of Socrates, The Treatises on the Lacedaemonian and Athenian Governments, On Revenues of Athens, On Horsemanship, On the Duties of a Cavalry Officer, and On Hunting H.G. Bohn, 1857 – Retrieved 9 June 2012
  75. ^ Parker, W N (26 April 1991). Europe, America and the Wider World: Essays on the Economic History of Western Capitalism. Cambridge University Press, 26 April 1991. ISBN 0521274796. Archived from the original on 2 May 2006. Retrieved 8 June 2012.
  76. R W Bulliet, P K Crossley, D R Headrick, S W Hirsch, L L Johnson – The Earth and Its Peoples: A Global History, Volume 1 Cengage Learning, 1 January 2010 Retrieved 8 June 2012
  77. MA Dandamaev, VG Lukonin, PL Kohl – The Culture And Social Institutions Of Ancient Iran (p. 216) published by Cambridge University Press, 11 November 2004, ISBN 0521611911. Retrieved 7 September 2012
  78. J ParkhurstA Greek and English Lexicon to the New Testament: In which the Words and Phrases ... are Distinctly Explained, and the Meanings Assigned to Each Authorized by References to Passages of Scripture, and Frequently ... Confirmed by Citations from the Old Testament and from the Greek Writers. To this Work is Prefixed, a ... Greek Grammar ... J Davis 1898 – Retrieved 16 June 2012
  79. J E HarrisonEpilegomena to the Study of Greek Religions and Themis a Study of the Social Origins of Greek Religion Kessinger Publishing, 1Jan 2003 ISBN 0766135284 Retrieved 16 June 2012
  80. secondary – Varro et al Retrieved 16 June 2012
  81. D Sacks, O Murray A Dictionary of the Ancient Greek World Oxford University Press, 6 February 1997 ISBN 0195112067 Retrieved 16 June 2012
  82. secondary – The journal of the Royal Society of Antiquaries of Ireland 1894 " ...great treasury tombs probably range from this time to 1200..."
  83. J E Harrison – Themis: A Study of the Social Origins of Greek Religion Cambridge University Press, 24 June 2010 ISBN 1108009492 Retrieved 16 June 2012
  84. J A Harrill (1998). The Manumission of Slaves in Early Christianity. Mohr Siebeck. ISBN 3161469356. Retrieved 3 June 2012.
  85. J Rüpke (25 March 2011). A Companion to Roman Religion. John Wiley & Sons. ISBN 978-1444341317. Retrieved 3 June 2012.
  86. ^ Edward E. Cohen (7 November 2011). Athenian Economy and Society: A Banking Perspective. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press 1992. ISBN 978-0-691-03609-0. Retrieved 5 September 2015.(and prior date)
  87. W Smith, LLD, W Wayte, G. E. Marindin, Ed. A Dictionary of Greek and Roman Antiquities (1890). Perseus of Tufts University. Retrieved 15 June 2012.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  88. R J A Talbert (1985). Atlas of Classical History. Taylor & Francis, 1985. ISBN 0709924488. Retrieved 15 June 2012.
  89. secondary- Retrieved 15 June 2012
  90. F S Kleiner, H Gardner, C J Mamiya, Gardner's Art Through the Ages: A Global History, Enhanced Cengage Learning, 1 January 2010 ISBN 1439085781 Art Through The Ages: The Western Perspective ISBN 0495004782 Retrieved 15 June 2012
  91. The Manumission of Slaves in Early Christianity By James Albert Harrill ISBN 3161469356 Retrieved 18 June 2012
  92. ^ H Temporini, W Haase (March 1978). Principat, Volume 8. Walter de Gruyter, 1977. ISBN 3110073374. Retrieved 3 June 2012.
  93. W. V. Harris – The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans Oxford University Press, 14 February 2008 ISBN 019161517X Retrieved 9 June 2012
  94. A R David Handbook to Life in Ancient Egypt Oxford University Press, 28 October 1999 ISBN 0195132157 Retrieved 9 June 2012
  95. J Tyldesley – Cleopatra: Last Queen of Egypt Profile Books, 26 May 2011 ISBN 1847650449 Retrieved 9 June 2012
  96. M Gagarin, E Fantham – The Oxford Encyclopedia of Ancient Greece and Rome, Volume 1 Oxford University Press, 31 December 2009 Retrieved 17 July 2012 ISBN 0195170725
  97. M Robertson- A Shorter History of Greek Art Cambridge University Press, 16 July 1981 ISBN 0521280842 Retrieved 18 June 2012
  98. ^ J Braithwaite; P Drahos (February 2000). Global Business Regulation. Cambridge University Press, 1 February 2000. ISBN 0521784999. Retrieved 14 June 2012.
  99. ^ K Roberts (2011). The Origins of Business, Money, and Markets. Columbia University Press. ISBN 978-0231153263.
  100. B R BraxtonThe tyranny of resolution: I Corinthians 7:17–24 Society of Biblical Literature, 2000 Retrieved 14 June 2012
  101. Sze-Kar WanPower in Weakness: Conflict and Rhetoric in Paul's Second Letter to the Corinthians Continuum International Publishing Group, 1 June 2000 ISBN 1563383152 Retrieved 14 June 2012
  102. 2nd – + + +
  103. Celebrating Common Prayer (Eastern Orthodox liturgics). Cassell & The European Province of the Society of Saint Francis. 1992. ISBN 0-264-67284-4.
  104. DM Schaps – The Invention of Coinage and the Monetization of Ancient Greece University of Michigan Press, 2004 Retrieved 17 July 2012 ISBN 047211333X
  105. Oesterreichische Nationalbank Archived 11 July 2012 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 29 May 2012
  106. S L Budin (p. 113)
  107. Hudson, M. (26 February 2012). Entrepreneurs: From the Near Eastern Takeoff to the Roman Collapse within The Invention of Enterprise: Entrepreneurship from Ancient Mesopotamia to Modern Times. Princeton University Press, The Kauffman Foundation Series on Innovation and Entrepreneurship. p. 16. ISBN 978-1400833580. Retrieved 8 September 2015.
  108. Brill Online Reference Works (October 2006). Trapezites. Koninklijke Brill NV. Retrieved 6 September 2015.
  109. Piotr Niczyporuk – Mensarii, bankers acting for public and private benefit published by the Central European Journal of Social Sciences and Humanities 2011 | 24(37) | 105-115 Studies in Logic, Grammar and Rhetoric (please see also the same source linked in full here)
  110. ^ H D Macleod (1855). The theory and practice of banking, Volume 1. Longmans, Green, 1855. Retrieved 9 April 2012.
  111. ^ J Andreau (Director of Studies at the School of Higher study of the Social Sciences, Paris) (14 October 1999). Banking and Business in the Roman World. Cambridge University Press, 14 October 1999. ISBN 9780521389327. Retrieved 9 April 2012.
  112. "bank | Origin and meaning of bank by Online Etymology Dictionary". www.etymonline.com. Retrieved 15 August 2020.
  113. Matyszak, Philip (2007). Ancient Rome on Five Denarii a Day. New York: Thames & Hudson. p. 144. ISBN 978-0-500-05147-4.
  114. Benke, N. (2012). "Gender and the Roman Law of Obligations". Obligations in Roman Law: Past, Present, and Future. Papers And Monographs Of The American Academy In Rome. Vol. 33. University of Michigan Press. p. 226. ISBN 978-0472118434.
  115. A Chester Johnson, P Robinson Coleman-Norton, F Card Bourne – Ancient Roman Statutes: A Translation With Introduction, Commentary, Glossary, and Index The Lawbook Exchange, Ltd., 1 October 2003 Retrieved 9 July 2012 ISBN 1584772913
  116. B Burrell ISBN 9004125787 p. 254
  117. Zimmermann, Reinhard (1996). The Law of Obligations: Roman Foundations of the Civilian Tradition (reprint, revised ed.). Oxford University Press. p. 514. ISBN 019876426X.
  118. Rostovtzeff, Michael Ivanovitch (1926). The Social & Economic History of the Roman Empire. Biblo & Tannen Publishers. p. 542. ISBN 0819621641.
  119. Trade and Politics in Ancient Greece By Johannes Hasebroek (page 156) – Retrieved 14 July 2012
  120. William Smith – Dictionary of Greek and Roman geography, Volume 2 Walton & Maberly, 1857 Retrieved 14 July 2012
  121. Glasner, David (25 August 1989). Free Banking and Monetary Reform. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-36175-0.
  122. Johnson cites Fritz E. Heichelcheim: An Ancient Economic History, 2 vols. (trans. Leiden 1965), i.104–566
  123. Johnson, Paul: A History of the Jews (New York: HarperCollins Publishers, 1987) ISBN 0-06-091533-1. pp. 172–173
  124. The Hebrew Bible in English according to the JPS 1917 Edition. http://www.mechon-mamre.org/e/et/et0523.htm
  125. The references cited in the Passionary for this woodcut: 1 John 2:14–16, Matthew 10:8, and The Apology of the Augsburg Confession, Article 8, Of the Church Archived 15 July 2010 at the Wayback Machine
  126. Examples of debt:1 Samuel 22:2, 2 Kings 4:1, Isaiah 50:1. Prophetic condemnation of usury: Ezekiel 22:12, Nehemiah 5:7 and 12:13. Cautions regarding debt: Prov 22:7, passim.
  127. J. Le Goff, Marchands et banquiers au Moyen Âge, Puf Quadrige, 2011, p. 75
  128. McKinnon, AM (2010). "Elective affinities of the Protestant ethic: Weber and the chemistry of capitalism" (PDF). Sociological Theory. 28 (1): 108–126. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9558.2009.01367.x. hdl:2164/3035. S2CID 144579790.
  129. Stark, Rodney (2005). The Victory of Reason: How Christianity Led to Freedom, Capitalism, and Western Success. New York: Random House. ISBN 1-4000-6228-4.
  130. "HISTORY OF BANKING". www.historyworld.net. Retrieved 22 March 2023.
  131. Medievalists.net (22 August 2021). "Templar Banking: How to go from Donated Rags to Vast Riches". Medievalists.net. Retrieved 29 April 2024.
  132. "The warrior monks who invented banking". BBC News. 30 January 2017. Retrieved 23 April 2024.
  133. Ugolini, Stefano (2017). The Evolution of Central Banking: Theory and History.
  134. Macleod, Henry Dunning (1856). The Theory and Practice of Banking. Vol. 1.
  135. ^ Jewish Encyclopedia
  136. ^ C Kleinhenz (2004). Medieval Italy: An Encyclopedia, Volume 1. Routledge, 2004. ISBN 0415939305. Retrieved 14 July 2012.
  137. Charles P. Kindleberger (Professor of Economics Emeritus at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology – 2006) A Financial History of Western Europe Retrieved 17 May 2012
  138. Freeman Hunt, William B. Dana (1859). Merchants' magazine and commercial review, Volume 40. F. Hunt, 1859.
  139. 2nd – Holdsworth, W. S. -Early History of Banking 34 L. Q. Rev. 11 (1918) Retrieved 14 June 2012
  140. C Duggan – A Concise History of Italy Cambridge University Press, 21 April 1994 Retrieved 14 July 2012 ISBN 0521408482
  141. SB MacDonald, AL Gastmann – A History of Credit and Power in the Western World Transaction Publishers, 2004 Retrieved 14 July 2012 ISBN 0765808331
  142. Thomas H. Goddard; Alexander Hamilton; George McDuffie (1831). A general history of the most prominent banks in Europe:particularly the banks of England and France; the rise and progress of the Bank of North America; a full history of the late and present Bank of the United States. H. C. Sleight, 1831. p. 10. Venice bank subscription fund.
  143. Thomas Henry Dyer The history of modern Europe: from the fall of Constantinople in 1453 to the war in the Crimea in 1857, Volume 2 John Murray, 1861 Retrieved 14 May 2012
  144. La Vanguardia - El Banco de Barcelona financia el segundo viaje de Colón
  145. Inalcik, Halil (1997). An economic and social history of the Ottoman Empire. Cambridge University Press. p. 213. ISBN 9780521574563.
  146. Dumper, Michael; Stanley, Bruce E. (2007). Cities of the Middle East and North Africa: a historical encyclopedia. ABC-CLIO. p. 185. ISBN 9781576079195.
  147. Inalcik, Halil; Quataert, Donald (1994). An economic and social history of the Ottoman Empire, 1300–1914. Cambridge University Press. p. 212. ISBN 9780521343152.
  148. Bosworth, Clifford Edmund (2007). Historic cities of the Islamic world. BRILL. p. 207. ISBN 978-9004153882.
  149. Black, Edwin (2004). Banking on Baghdad: inside Iraq's 7,000-year history of war, profit and conflict. John Wiley and Sons. p. 335. ISBN 9780471708957. Under Ottoman rule, during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, Jews continued to thrive, becoming part of the commercial and political ruling class. Like Christians, the Jews could engage in necessary commercial activities, such as moneylending and banking, that were proscribed for Moslems under Islamic law.
  150. ^ Dimont, Max (1962). Jews, God, and History. Signet Classic. pp. 273–4. ISBN 978-0-451-52940-4.
  151. ^ Kreftz, Gerald (1984). Jews and Money: The Myths and the Reality. Ticknor & Fields. p. 46. ISBN 978-0-89919-129-4.
  152. Perry, p 131
  153. Sombart, Werner (1913). The Jews and Modern Capitalism. pp. 53–7. ISBN 978-0-217-35289-5.
  154. M Häberlein – The Fuggers of Augsburg: Pursuing Wealth and Honor in Renaissance Germany University of Virginia Press, 12 March 2012 Retrieved 14 July 2012 ISBN 0813932440
  155. C Duggan
  156. History World
  157. Price Waterhouse Coopers Financial Year Book FYB, 2009
  158. "Guide to Checks and Check Fraud" (PDF). Wachovia Bank. 2003. p. 4. Archived from the original (PDF) on 28 September 2011. Retrieved 13 June 2011.
  159. James Walvin 17 February 2011 Slavery and the Building of Britain British Broadcasting Corporation Retrieved 19 April 2012
  160. British Banking History Society A History of English Clearing Banks Archived 9 November 2016 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 19 April 2012
  161. Thus by the 19th century we find "n ordinary cases of deposits of money with banking corporations, or bankers, the transaction amounts to a mere loan or mutuum, and the bank is to restore, not the same money, but an equivalent sum, whenever it is demanded." Joseph Story, Commentaries on the Law of Bailments (1832, p. 66) and "Money, when paid into a bank, ceases altogether to be the money of the principal (see Parker v. Marchant, 1 Phillips 360); it is then the money of the banker, who is bound to return an equivalent by paying a similar sum to that deposited with him when he is asked for it." Lord Chancellor Cottenham, Foley v Hill (1848) 2 HLC 28.
  162. "Banking Origin and Development". Invest and Income. Archived from the original on 8 August 2011. Retrieved 26 July 2011.
  163. "A History of British Banknotes".
  164. Geisst, Charles R. (2005). Encyclopedia of American business history. New York. p. 39. ISBN 978-0-8160-4350-7.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  165. "A brief history of banknotes". Retrieved 17 December 2013.
  166. "A short history of overdrafts". eccount money. Archived from the original on 5 November 2013.
  167. ^ Norio Tamaki (2005). Japanese Banking: A History, 1859-1959. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521022330.
  168. William M. Tsutsui (1999). Banking in Japan: The evolution of Japanese banking, 1868-1952 (p. xvi). published by Taylor & Francis 1999, 255 pages, Routledge library of modern Japan. ISBN 9780415170123. Retrieved 13 September 2015.
  169. Quinn, Stephen; Roberds, William (2006), "An Economic Explanation of the Early Bank of Amsterdam, Debasement, Bills of Exchange, and the Emergence of the First Central Bank" Archived 3 May 2011 at the Wayback Machine, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Working Paper 2006–13
  170. Collins, Christopher. The Oxford Encyclopedia of Economic History, Volume 3. Banking: Middle Ages and Early Modern Period, Oxford University Press, 2012, p. 223
  171. History of Sveriges Riksbank Riksbank.com Archived 2008-05-04 at the Wayback Machine
  172. Committee of Finance and Industry 1931 (Macmillan Report) description of the founding of Bank of England. Arno Press. 1979. ISBN 9780405112126. Archived from the original on 1 July 2023. Retrieved 10 May 2010. Its foundation in 1694 arose out the difficulties of the Government of the day in securing subscriptions to State loans. Its primary purpose was to raise and lend money to the State and in consideration of this service it received under its Charter and various Act of Parliament, certain privileges of issuing bank notes. The corporation commenced, with an assured life of twelve years after which the Government had the right to annul its Charter on giving one year's notice. Subsequent extensions of this period coincided generally with the grant of additional loans to the State.
  173. H. Roseveare, The Financial Revolution 1660–1760 (1991, Longman), p. 34
  174. Bagehot, Walter (5 November 2010). Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market (1873). London: Henry S. King and Co. (etext by Project Gutenberg). Archived from the original on 9 May 2012. Retrieved 24 January 2013.
  175. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. "A History of Central Banking in the United States" online Archived 29 September 2018 at the Wayback Machine
  176. Clifford Gomez (2011). Banking and Finance: Theory, Law and Practice. PHI. p. 100. ISBN 9788120342378. Archived from the original on 1 July 2023. Retrieved 29 September 2018.
  177. Michael D. Bordo; Marc Flandreau; Jan F. Qvigstad (2016). Central Banks at a Crossroads: What Can We Learn from History?. Cambridge UP. pp. 1–17. ISBN 9781107149663. Archived from the original on 1 July 2023. Retrieved 29 September 2018.
  178. Michael Stephen Smith (2006). The Emergence of Modern Business Enterprise in France, 1800–1930. Harvard UP. p. 59. ISBN 9780674019393. Archived from the original on 1 July 2023. Retrieved 29 September 2018.
  179. "History". Bank of Finland. Archived from the original on 28 October 2014. Retrieved 28 October 2014.
  180. Niall Ferguson, The House of Rothschild: Volume 1: Money's Prophets: 1798–1848 (1999).
  181. Gabriele Teichmann, "Sal. Oppenheim jr. & Cie., Cologne." Financial History Review 1.1 (1994): 69–78, online in English Archived 29 September 2018 at the Wayback Machine.
  182. Bray Hammond, "Jackson's Fight with the 'Money Power'". American Heritage (June 1956) 7#4: 9–11, 100–103.
  183. Miklos Sebok, "President Wilson and the International Origins of the Federal Reserve System—A Reappraisal." White House Studies 10.4 (2011): 424–447.
  184. Marcello De Cecco (1994), Central Banking in Central and Eastern Europe: Lessons From the Interwar Years' Experience, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund
  185. "Rothschild: history of a London banking dynasty". The Daily Telegraph. 4 February 2011. Archived from the original on 4 June 2023.
  186. "10 of the Wealthiest Families in the World".
  187. Gray, Victor; Aspey, Melanie (May 2006) . "Rothschild, Nathan Mayer (1777–1836)". Oxford Dictionary of National Biography. Oxford Dictionary of National Biography (Online ed.). Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/ref:odnb/24162. Retrieved 21 May 2007. (Subscription or UK public library membership required.)
  188. Niall Ferguson, The House of Rothschild: Volume 2: The World's Banker: 1849–1999 (2000)
  189. Richard Smethurst,"Takahasi Korekiyo, the Rothschilds and the Russo-Japanese War, 1904–1907" Archived 16 February 2007 at the Wayback Machine. Retrieved 4 September 2007.
  190. Youssef Cassis and Éric Bussière, eds., London and Paris as International Financial Centres in the Twentieth Century (2005) ch 3
  191. Alain Plessis, "The history of banks in France." in Pohl, Manfred, and Sabine Freitag, eds. Handbook on the history of European banks (Edward Elgar Publishing, 1994) pp: 185–296. online Archived 3 October 2018 at the Wayback Machine
  192. Joan Comay, Who's who in Jewish History (2001) pp 305–14, 455
  193. Niall Ferguson, The House of Rothschild: Volume 2: The World's Banker: 1849-1999 (1998) pp 82–84, 206–14, 297–300,
  194. Ashworth, Herbert (1980). The Building Society Story. London: Franey & Co. p. 4. ISBN 0-900382-38-4.; Berg, Maxine (1991). "Commerce and Creativity in Eighteenth-Century Birmingham". In Berg, Maxine (ed.). Markets and Manufacture in Early Industrial Europe. London: Routledge. p. 194. ISBN 0-415-03720-4. Retrieved 7 September 2010.
  195. Jones, Peter M. (2009). Industrial Enlightenment: Science, technology and culture in Birmingham and the West Midlands, 1760–1820. Manchester: Manchester University Press. p. 65. ISBN 978-0-7190-7770-8.; Chinn, Carl (15 November 2008). "Brum's building society origins". Birmingham Mail. Birmingham Post and Mail Ltd. Retrieved 6 September 2010.
  196. Rex, Simon (20 April 2010). "The History of Building Societies". Building Societies Association. Archived from the original on 23 August 2013. Retrieved 6 September 2010.; Ashworth, Herbert (1980). The Building Society Story. London: Franey & Co. p. 2. ISBN 0-900382-38-4.
  197. Peterson, Christopher L. (July 2003). "Truth, Understanding, and High-Cost Consumer Credit: The Historical Context of the Truth in Lending Act". Florida Law Review (55): 839–840.
  198. Clark, Peter (2002), British Clubs and Societies 1580–1800: The Origins of an Associational World, Oxford: Oxford University Press, p. 129, ISBN 0-19-924843-5, retrieved 20 November 2010
  199. Cleary, E. J. (1965). The Building Society Movement. London: Elek Books. pp. 11–12. ISBN 9780236311446. OCLC 11817434. Retrieved 7 September 2010.
  200. Fortune, Peter (September–October 2000). "Margin Requirements, Margin Loans, and Margin Rates: Practice and Principles – analysis of history of margin credit regulations – Statistical Data Included". New England Economic Review.
  201. ^ "Bank Failures". Living History Farm. Archived from the original on 19 February 2009. Retrieved 22 May 2008.
  202. "Friedman and Schwartz, Monetary History of the United States", 352
  203. "Raymond F. Mikesell, The Bretton Woods Debates: A Memoir, Essays in International Finance 192 (Princeton: International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University, 1994)" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 18 June 2017. Retrieved 22 October 2014.
  204. "How the ATM Revolutionized the Banking Business". Bloomberg.com. Bloomberg News. 27 March 2013.
  205. "SWIFT History". SWIFT. Archived from the original on 26 December 2012. Retrieved 22 October 2014.
  206. "In Depth – Big Bang". Financial Times. 29 October 2006. Archived from the original on 15 November 2006. Retrieved 29 October 2006.
  207. Chairman Cox (26 September 2008). "Chairman Cox Announces End of Consolidated Supervised Entities Program". press release 2008-230. SEC. Retrieved 14 March 2014.
  208. Investment banking – Is there a future?, 18 September 2008, The Economist
  209. Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (22 July 2020). "Re: Authority of a National Bank to Provide Cryptocurrency Custody Services for Customers" (PDF). OCC.gov.
  210. Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (4 January 2021). "OCC Chief Counsel's Interpretation on National Bank and Federal Savings Association Authority to Use Independent Node Verification Networks and Stablecoins for Payment Activities" (PDF). OCC.gov.
  211. Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (13 January 2021). "OCC Conditionally Approves Conversion of Anchorage Digital Bank". OCC.gov.
  212. "Bank Guarantee Scheme & Recapitalisation". National Treasury Management Agency. 22 October 2008. Archived from the original on 2 March 2009.
  213. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Royal Statistical Society (Great Britain) Statistical Society of London 1874 . Retrieved 15 May 2012
  214. Josephus Nelson Larned, Donald Eugene Smith, Charles Seymour The new Larned History for ready reference, reading and research: the actual words of the world's best historians, biographers and specialists; a complete system of history for all uses, extending to all countries and subjects and representing the better and newer literature of history, Volume 7 C.A. Nichols Publishing Company, 1923 Retrieved 15 May 2012
  215. oxforddictionaries
  216. ^ "Walter B. Wriston Archives". Tufts University. Archived from the original on 19 May 2012. Retrieved 14 May 2012.
  217. Banque de France. "history". Retrieved 18 May 2012.
  218. ^ Kindleberger – p. 12 (see : Sources)
  219. Hawkins, William, "Panic Control", The Washington Times, 12 May 2008

Further reading

  • Andreades, Andreas Michael. History of the Bank of England (Routledge, 2013)
  • Cameron, Rondo. Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialization: A Study in Comparative Economic History (1967)
  • Cameron, Rondo et al. International Banking 1870–1914 (1992)
  • Cassis, Youssef; Grossman, Richard S.; Schenk, Catherine R., eds. (2016). The Oxford Handbook of Banking and Financial History. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-965862-6.
  • Feis, Herbert. Europe the World's Banker, 1870–1914 (1930) online
  • Ferguson, Niall. The Ascent of Money: A Financial History of the World (2008).
  • Ferguson, Niall. The House of Rothschild: Volume 2: The World's Banker: 1849-1999 (2000)
  • Grossman, Richard S. Unsettled Account: The Evolution of Banking in the Industrialized World Since 1800 (Princeton University Press; 2010) 384 pages. Considers how crises, bailouts, mergers, and regulations have shaped the history of banking in Western Europe, the United States, Canada, Japan, and Australia.
  • Hammond, Bray, Banks and Politics in America, from the Revolution to the Civil War (Princeton University Press, 1957)
  • Hudson, Peter James. "On the History and Historiography of Banking in the Caribbean." Small Axe 18.1 43 (2014): 22–37.
  • Jaffe, Steven H., and Jessica Lautin. Capital of Capital: Money, Banking, and Power in New York City (Columbia University Press, 2014)
  • Kindleberger, Charles P.A Financial History of Western Europe ISBN 0415378672
  • Klebaner, Benjamin J. American commercial banking: A history (Twayne, 1990). online
  • Kobrak, Christopher, and Wilkins, Mira, eds. History and Financial Crisis: Lessons from the 20th Century (Routledge, 2014)
  • Komai, Alejandro, and Gary Richardson. "A history of financial regulation in the USA from the beginning until today: 1789 to 2011." in Handbook of Financial Data and Risk Information I (2014): 385+.
  • Lane, Nicholas. "The Fathers of English Banking." History Today (Mar 1953) 3#3 pp 190–199
  • Meltzer, Allan H. A History of the Federal Reserve (2 vol. U of Chicago Press, 2010) on U.S.
  • Michie, Ranald C. British Banking: Continuity and Change from 1694 to the Present (Oxford UP, 2016) 334 pp. online review
  • Murphy, Sharon Ann. Other People's Money: How Banking Worked in the Early American Republic (2017) online review
  • Neal, Larry. "How it all began: the monetary and financial architecture of Europe during the first global capital markets, 1648–1815." Financial History Review (2000) 7#2 pp: 117–140.
  • Rothbard, Murray N., History of Money and Banking in the United States. Full text (510 pages) in pdf format
  • Soyeda, Juichi. A history of banking in Japan

External links

Categories: