Revision as of 10:34, 26 February 2006 editKDRGibby (talk | contribs)2,454 edits your complaint is still really stupid...i'm helping you with your discription.← Previous edit | Latest revision as of 20:13, 12 December 2024 edit undoAadirulez8 (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users43,495 editsm v2.05 - Autofix / Fix errors for CW project (Link equal to linktext)Tag: WPCleaner | ||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{Short description|Type of economic system}} | |||
{{NPOV-because|The article gives overwhelming weight to the views of academic economists who just so happen to believe that free markets are the best economic solution, including F.A. Hayek and Milton Friedman.}} | |||
{{more citations needed|date=November 2021}} | |||
A '''market economy''' is an ] in which ]s and ]s are ]d, with the ] at which goods and services are exchanged being determined by trades that occur as a result of sellers' ''asking prices'' matching buyers' ''bid prices''. | |||
], Seattle, Washington, United States, 1968]] | |||
{{economic systems sidebar|by coordination}} | |||
{{liberalism sidebar}} | |||
A '''market economy''' is an ] in which the decisions regarding ], ], and ] to the consumers are guided by the ] created by the forces of ]. The major characteristic of a market economy is the existence of ] that play a dominant role in the allocation of ] and the ].<ref>{{cite book|last=Gregory and Stuart|first=Paul & Robert|title=Comparing Economic Systems in the Twenty-First Century|edition=7th|publisher=George Hoffman|year=2004|isbn=0618261818|page=538|quote=Market Economy: Economy in which fundamentals of supply and demand provide signals regarding resource utilization.}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|title=The Future of the Market: An Essay on the Regulation of Money and Nature After the Collapse of "Actually Existing Socialism|url=https://archive.org/details/futureofmarketes0000altv|url-access=registration|author=Altvater, E.|year=1993|publisher=Verso|page=}}</ref> | |||
In a market economy, ask and bid prices are typically understood to be the result of ]s, with potential buyers bidding up to, but not more, than they are willing to pay for a good or service and potential sellers offering a price down to, but not lower, than that which they are willing to depart with a good or service. When these prices align, a trade is made, and exchange price is determined. Bid prices are influenced by competition among buyers and ask prices are influenced by competition among sellers. | |||
Market economies range from minimally regulated ] and '']'' systems where state activity is restricted to providing ]s and ] and safeguarding private ownership,<ref>{{cite book|title=Comparative Economic Transformations: Mainland China, Hungary, the Soviet Union, and Taiwan|author=Yu-Shan Wu|year=1995|publisher=Stanford University Press|pages=8|quote=In laissez-faire capitalism, the state restricts itself to providing public goods and services that the economy cannot generate by itself and to safeguarding private ownership and the smooth operation of the self-regulating market.}}</ref> to ] forms where the government plays an active role in correcting ]s and promoting ]. State-directed or ] economies are those where the state plays a directive role in guiding the overall development of the market through ] or ]—which guides yet does not substitute the market for ]—a form sometimes referred to as a ].<ref>{{cite book|title=The Future of the Market: An Essay on the Regulation of Money and Nature After the Collapse of "Actually Existing Socialism|url=https://archive.org/details/futureofmarketes0000altv|url-access=registration|author=Altvater, E.|year=1993|publisher=Verso|pages=–238}}</ref><ref>Tucker, Irvin B. p 491. Macroeconomics for Today. West Publishing. p. 491</ref> | |||
A market economy has no ] guiding its operation, yet theoretically organization emerges amidst the complex interplay of ] and price regarding a multitude of goods and services. Supporters of a market economy generally hold that the pursuit of ] is actually in the best interest of society. ] says: | |||
Market economies are contrasted with ] where investment and production decisions are embodied in an integrated economy-wide economic plan. In a ], economic planning is the principal allocation mechanism between firms rather than markets, with the economy's ] being owned and operated by a single organizational body. | |||
<blockquote>"By pursuing his own interest frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it. I have never known much good done by those who affected to trade for the good." (''Wealth of Nations'')</blockquote> | |||
== Characteristics == | |||
There are a variety of critics of market as an organizing principle of an economy. These critics range from those who reject markets entirely, in favor of a ], such as that advocated by ], to those who merely wish to see them regulated to various degrees, and they range from those who believe that ] is inherently ] to those who raise practical objections. One prominent practical objection is the claim that markets wreak havoc through their ] (things that the market price does not take into account), for example through environmental pollution. Another is the claim that through the creation of ], markets sow the seeds of their own destruction. | |||
=== Property rights === | |||
For market economies to function efficiently, governments must establish clearly defined and enforceable ] for assets and capital goods. However, property rights do not specifically mean private property rights and market economies do not logically presuppose the existence of ] of the ]. Market economies can and often do include various types of ] or autonomous ]s that acquire ] and raw materials in ]s. These enterprises utilize a market-determined free price system to allocate capital goods and labor.<ref name="auburn.edu">{{cite web | url=http://www.auburn.edu/~johnspm/gloss/market_economy | title=A Glossary of Political Economy Terms, Market economy | author=Paul M. Johnson | year=2005 | publisher=Auburn University | access-date=28 December 2012 | archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121227012016/http://www.auburn.edu/~johnspm/gloss/market_economy | archive-date=27 December 2012 | url-status=dead }}</ref> In addition, there are many variations of ] where the majority of capital assets are socially owned with markets allocating resources between socially owned firms. These models range from systems based on ] based on ] to a combination of public ownership of the ] with ]s.<ref>{{cite book |last= Bock man|first= Johanna |title= Markets in the name of Socialism: The Left-Wing origins of Neoliberalism|publisher= Stanford University Press|year= 2011|isbn= 978-0804775663}}{{page needed|date=March 2022}}</ref> | |||
=== Supply and demand === | |||
Some proponents of market economies believe that governments should not diminish market freedom because they disagree on what is a market externality and what are government created externalities, and disagree over what the appropriate level of intervention is necessary to solve market created externalities. Others believe that government should intervene to prevent market failure while preserving the general character of a market economy. | |||
Supply and demand supposedly work in tandem. The economic theory is that supply slopes upwards as people buy more and demand drops as prices rise and people buy less.<ref name=":0">{{Cite web |title=Supply and Demand: Why Markets Tick |url=https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/fandd/issues/Series/Back-to-Basics/Supply-and-Demand#:~:text=Supply%20is%20generally%20considered%20to,higher%20prices,%20consumers%20buy%20less. |access-date=2024-09-22 |website=IMF |language=en}}</ref> | |||
In the model of a ] the state intervenes where the market does not fulfill the needs of the market participants. ] is a prominent proponent of this idea. | |||
Market economies rely upon a price system to signal market actors to adjust production and investment. Price formation relies on the interaction of supply and demand to reach or approximate an equilibrium where the unit price for a particular good or service is at a point where the quantity demanded equals the quantity supplied. | |||
The economists' model of a ] is one in which there is no governmental intervention or other coercion. The theoretical model of a large-scale free market economy does not occur legally, however the ] may be seen as an actualized free market economy. | |||
The price data point where the supply and demand lines intersect is called the ].<ref name=":0" /> ] | |||
==Free market economy== | |||
] | |||
{{main|Free market economy}} | |||
Governments can intervene by establishing ]s or price floors in specific markets (such as ] laws in the labor market), or use ] to discourage certain consumer behavior or to address market externalities generated by certain transactions (]es). Different perspectives exist on the role of government in both regulating and guiding market economies and in addressing social inequalities produced by markets. Fundamentally, a market economy requires that a price system affected by supply and demand exists as the primary mechanism for allocating resources irrespective of the level of regulation. | |||
Free market economics is often conflated with capitalism but there is currently no capitalist state that has a free market. Even the United States, which often represents capitalism worldwide, has restrictions upon the freedom of factors in the economy. Free markets are also conflated with anarchy as many people believe that free market implies an absence of government. Only a few free market scholars advocate the elimination of government, most including ] and ] believed government had a role to play, albeit a limited one. Most free market scholars believe that governments should be limited to at least: operating a court system for the settlement of disputes, maintaining stable currency (combating inflation), protecting market competition and consumers, and protecting the country through national defense. These scholars debate and disagree with each other on whether or not governments are necessary to have government funded roads, schools, post offices, libraries, police stations, and fire stations, as some free market scholars believe the market can solve their externalities. | |||
== Capitalism == | |||
In order for an economy to be considered a true free market, the factors of labor, goods, services, and capital, must be free from government restrictions and trading barriers so they are able to move freely across borders | |||
{{main|Capitalism}} | |||
{{Capitalism sidebar}} | |||
Capitalism is an economic system where the ] are largely or entirely ] and ], structured on the process of ]. In general, in capitalist systems investment, distribution, income and prices are determined by markets, whether regulated or unregulated. | |||
There are different variations of capitalism with different relationships to markets. In '']'' and ] variations of capitalism, markets are utilized most extensively with minimal or no state intervention and minimal or no regulation over prices and the supply of goods and services. In ], ] and ], markets continue to play a dominant role, but they are regulated to some extent by the government in order to correct ]s or to promote social welfare. In ] systems, markets are relied upon the least, with the state relying heavily on either ] and/or ] to accumulate capital. | |||
===Adam Smith's theory=== | |||
{{Sectstub}} | |||
Capitalism has been dominant in the Western world since the end of ]. However, it is argued that the term ''mixed economies'' more precisely describes most contemporary economies due to their containing both private-owned and state-owned enterprises. In capitalism, prices determine the demand-supply scale. Higher demand for certain goods and services leads to higher prices and lower demand for certain goods lead to lower prices, in relation to supply. | |||
==Decisionmaking== | |||
The "economy" is usually associated with ]. | |||
=== Free-market capitalism === | |||
Generally market economies are bottom up in decisionmaking as consumers input information to producers through prices paid when purchasing products on the market. For a brief time during the 20th century even self described capitalist states engaged in top down market command where the government and or producers attempted to command and direct resources to valued uses. All states today have some form of control over the market that removes the free and unrestricted direction of resources from consumers and prices such as ], and corporate ]. ] and many other microeconomists, believe that these forms of intervention provide incentives for resources to be sent, and sometimes wasted, producing products society may not value as much as a product that is, as a result of these restrictions, not being produced. | |||
{{see also|Free market}} | |||
A capitalist free-market economy is an economic system where prices for goods and services are set freely by the forces of supply and demand and are expected by its supporters to reach their point of equilibrium without intervention by government policy. It typically entails support for highly competitive markets, private ownership of productive enterprises. ''Laissez-faire'' is a more extensive form of free-market economy where the role of the state is limited to protecting ] and enforcing ]. | |||
=== ''Laissez-faire'' === | |||
==Market externalities== | |||
{{main|Laissez-faire}} | |||
Examples of ]s, or ], include negative externalities, ], lack of provision of ]s, and ] disparities such as extreme ]. Market failures are the result of the market not receiving enough or appropriate information through singles such as prices. For example there is currently no way for the market to understand the cost or harm ] causes to society. These failures are the reason some think have thought that limited ] is necessary. | |||
{{see also|Economic liberalism}} | |||
''Laissez-faire'' is synonymous with what was referred to as strict ] economy during the early and mid-19th century{{Citation needed|date=December 2014}} as a ] ideal to achieve. It is generally understood that the necessary components for the functioning of an idealized free market include the complete absence of government regulation, subsidies, artificial price pressures and government-granted monopolies (usually classified as ] by free market advocates) and no taxes or tariffs other than what is necessary for the government to provide protection from coercion and theft, maintaining peace and property rights and providing for basic public goods. ] advocates of ] see the state as morally ] and economically unnecessary and destructive. Although ''laissez-faire'' has been commonly associated with capitalism, there is a similar ] ''laissez-faire'' system called ], also known as ] and ] to distinguish it from ''laissez-faire'' capitalism.<ref>Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). ''Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty''. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia{{page needed|date=March 2022}}</ref><ref>"It introduces an eye-opening approach to radical social thought, rooted equally in libertarian socialism and market anarchism." Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). ''Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty''. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. p. back cover.</ref><ref>"But there has always been a market-oriented strand of libertarian socialism that emphasizes voluntary cooperation between producers. And markets, properly understood, have always been about cooperation. As a commenter at Reason magazine's Hit&Run blog, remarking on ]'s link to the Kelly article, put it: "every trade is a cooperative act." In fact, it's a fairly common observation among market anarchists that genuinely free markets have the most legitimate claim to the label "socialism." {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160310111716/https://c4ss.org/content/670 |date=2016-03-10 }} by ] at website of Center for a Stateless Society.</ref> Thus, critics of ''laissez-faire'' as commonly understood argues that a truly ''laissez-faire'' system would be ] and ].<ref>Nick Manley, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210818131348/http://c4ss.org/content/27009 |date=2021-08-18 }}.</ref><ref>Nick Manley, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210516192528/https://c4ss.org/content/27062 |date=2021-05-16 }}.</ref> | |||
=== Welfare capitalism === | |||
] believes that many market failures can be solved not through government regulation of current information but through ] disclosure. Information disclosure would be a requirement of government ] but would not actually seriously regulate how buisnesses operate. Instead the disclosure of information would allow the market to react to their behavior by allowing consumers to vote with their dollars given better information about the companies they do business with. | |||
{{main|Welfare capitalism}} | |||
Welfare capitalism is a capitalist economy that includes public policies favoring extensive provisions for social welfare services. The economic mechanism involves a free market and the predominance of privately owned enterprises in the economy, but public provision of universal welfare services aimed at enhancing individual autonomy and maximizing equality. Examples of contemporary welfare capitalism include the ] of capitalism predominant in Northern Europe.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.iea.org.uk/sites/default/files/publications/files/Sweden%20Paper.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121022170900/http://www.iea.org.uk/sites/default/files/publications/files/Sweden%20Paper.pdf |archive-date=2012-10-22 |url-status=live |title=The surprising ingredients of Swedish success – free markets and social cohesion |date=June 25, 2013 |publisher=] |access-date=January 15, 2014}}</ref> | |||
=== Regional models === | |||
Friedman also argues for pollution permits to solve pollution externalities. By selling permits to the public, the public is now able to demonstrate a price for the harm or benefit caused by pollution. He believes that this type of government "regulation" allows better flowing information rather than the masking of current information to the market. If people really do value ], the information will be felt in the market and companies will react more quickly to be environmentally friendly. | |||
==== Anglo-Saxon model ==== | |||
{{main|Anglo-Saxon model}} | |||
Anglo-Saxon capitalism is the form of capitalism predominant in Anglophone countries and typified by the ]. It is contrasted with European models of capitalism such as the continental ] model and the ]. Anglo-Saxon capitalism refers to a macroeconomic policy regime and capital market structure common to the Anglophone economies. Among these characteristics are low rates of taxation, more open international markets, lower labor market protections and a less generous ] eschewing ] schemes found in the continental and northern European models of capitalism.<ref>''Anglo-Saxon capitalism'', Business Dictionary on BusinessDictionary.com: http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/Anglo-Saxon-capitalism.html {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200927202903/http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/Anglo-Saxon-capitalism.html |date=2020-09-27 }}</ref> | |||
==== East Asian model ==== | |||
Friedman believes governments have a role in fixing market externalities but only if the government is helping solve information transmission problems not masking current information. | |||
{{main|East Asian model}} | |||
The East Asian model of capitalism involves a strong role for state investment and in some instances involves state-owned enterprises. The state takes an active role in promoting economic development through subsidies, the facilitation of "national champions" and an export-based model of growth. The actual practice of this model varies by country. This designation has been applied to the economies of ], ], ], ], and ]. | |||
A related concept in political science is the ]. | |||
==Government intervention== | |||
It is possible for a market economy to have government intervention in the economy. The key difference between market economies and planned economies lies not with the degree of government influence but whether that influence is used to coercively preclude private decision. In a market economy, if the government wants more steel, it collects ]es and then buys the steel at market prices. In a planned economy, a government which wants more steel simply orders it to be produced and sets the price by decree. An economy where both ] and market mechanisms of production and distribution are present is known as a ]. Germany's ] was one of the better functioning mixed economies, as microeconomists note that it had relativily free prices compared to other more socialist countries like the ] for much of the later 20th century. | |||
==== Social market economy ==== | |||
The proper role for government in a market economy remains ]. Most supporters of a market economy believe that government has a ] role in defining and enforcing the basic rules of the market. More controversial is the question of how strong a role the government should have in both guiding the economy and addressing the inequalities the market produces. For example, there is no universal agreement on issues such as ] ]s, ] of ]s, and ] programs. | |||
{{main|Social market economy}} | |||
The social market economy was implemented by ] and ] after ] in ]. The social market economic model, sometimes called ], is based upon the idea of realizing the benefits of a free-market economy, especially economic performance and high supply of goods while avoiding disadvantages such as ], destructive competition, concentration of ] and the socially harmful effects of market processes. The aim of the social market economy is to realize greatest prosperity combined with best possible social security. One difference from the free market economy is that the state is not passive, but instead takes active ] measures.<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20111212140139/http://www.bpb.de/popup/popup_lemmata.html?guid=Y0VZ7J |date=2011-12-12 }} Duden Wirtschaft von A bis Z. Grundlagenwissen für Schule und Studium, Beruf und Alltag. 2. Aufl. Mannheim: Bibliographisches Institut & F.A. Brockhaus 2004. Lizenzausgabe Bonn: Bundeszentrale für politische Bildung 2004.</ref> The social policy objectives include employment, housing and education policies, as well as a socio-politically motivated balancing of the distribution of income growth. Characteristics of social market economies are a strong ] and a ]. The philosophical background is ] or ].<ref>] Wirtschaft von A bis Z. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120829015237/http://www.bpb.de/nachschlagen/lexika/lexikon-der-wirtschaft/20642/soziale-marktwirtschaft |date=2012-08-29 }}.</ref> | |||
== Socialism == | |||
], along with many microeconomists, believes that too much government intervention and regulation can result in hampering or stoping the transmission of information necessary to allow the market to operate, what results, he believes, are very serious government externalities that can lead to inflation, deflation, recesions, and depressions. Milton Friedman believes that the ] was the result of a government created externalities and thus was responsible for the ]. | |||
{{main|Market socialism}} | |||
Market socialism is a form of market economy where the means of production are ]. In a market socialist economy, firms operate according to the rules of supply and demand and operate to maximize profit; the principal difference between market socialism and capitalism being that the profits accrue either directly to the workers of the company or society as a whole as opposed to private owners.<ref>''Comparing Economic Systems in the Twenty-First Century'', 2003, by Gregory and Stuart. {{ISBN|0618261818}}. (p. 142): "It is an economic system that combines social ownership of capital with market allocation of capital...The state owns the means of production, and returns accrue to society at large."</ref> | |||
The distinguishing feature between non-market socialism and market socialism is the existence of a market for ] and the criteria of profitability for enterprises. Profits derived from publicly owned enterprises can variously be used to reinvest in further production, to directly finance government and social services, or be distributed to the public at large through a ] or ] system.<ref name="Social Dividend versus Basic Income Guarantee in Market Socialism, 2004">''Social Dividend versus Basic Income Guarantee in Market Socialism'', by Marangos, John. 2004. International Journal of Political Economy, vol. 34, no. 3, Fall 2004.</ref> | |||
==Market freedom== | |||
] and ] stated that ] is a necessary condition for the creation and sustainability of ] and ]. They believe that this economic freedom can only be achieved in a market oriented economy, specifically a free market economy. They do believe, however, that sufficient economic freedom can be achieved in economies with functioning markets through prices and private property right]]s. They believe that the more economic freedom that is available the more civil and policical freedoms a society will enjoy. | |||
Advocates of market socialism such as ] argue that genuinely free markets are not possible under conditions of private ownership of productive property. Instead, he contends that the class differences and inequalities in income and power that result from private ownership enable the interests of the dominant class to skew the market to their favor, either in the form of monopoly and market power, or by utilizing their wealth and resources to legislate government policies that benefit their specific business interests. Additionally, Vaněk states that workers in a socialist economy based on cooperative and self-managed enterprises have stronger incentives to maximize productivity because they would receive a share of the profits (based on the overall performance of their enterprise) in addition to receiving their fixed wage or salary. The stronger incentives to maximize productivity that he conceives as possible in a socialist economy based on cooperative and self-managed enterprises might be accomplished in a free-market economy if ] were the norm as envisioned by various thinkers including ] and ].<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210817073532/http://www.ru.org/index.php/30-economics/357-cooperative-economics-an-interview-with-jaroslav-vanek |date=2021-08-17 }}. Interview by Albert Perkins. Retrieved March 17, 2011.</ref> | |||
Friedman states: | |||
=== Models of market socialism === | |||
<blockquote> "economic freedom is simply a requisite for political freedom. By enabling people to cooperate with one another without coercion or central direction it reduces the area over which political power is exercised." Friedman, Milton and Rose Friedman, ]: A Personal Statement, Harcort Brace Janovich, 1980, p. 2-3 </blockquote> | |||
Market socialism traces its roots to ] and the works of ], the ] and ] philosophers.<ref>{{cite book|last=McNally|first=David|title=Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the Marxist Critique|publisher=Verso|year=1993|isbn=978-0860916062|page=44|quote=...by the 1820s, 'Smithian' apologists for industrial capitalism confronted 'Smithian' socialists in a vigorous, and often venomous, debate over political economy.}}</ref> | |||
In the 1930s, the economists ] and ] developed a model of socialism that posited that a public body (dubbed the Central Planning Board) could set prices through a trial-and-error approach until they equaled the ] of production in order to achieve ] and ]. In this model of socialism, firms would be state-owned and managed by their employees and the profits would be disbursed among the population in a social dividend. This model came to be referred to as market socialism because it involved the use of money, a ] and simulated capital markets, all of which were absent from traditional non-market socialism. | |||
Studies by the Canadian "conservative" free market oriented ], the American "conservative" free market oriented ], and the ] state that there is a relationship between economic freedom and political and civil freedoms to the extent claimed by Friedrich von Hayek. They agree with Hayek that those countries which restrict economic freedom ultimately restrict civil and political freedoms. | |||
A more contemporary model of market socialism is that put forth by the American economist ], referred to as ]. In this model, ] is achieved through public ownership of equity in a market economy. A Bureau of Public Ownership would own controlling shares in publicly listed firms, so that the profits generated would be used for public finance and the provision of a basic income. | |||
==Criticism of alternatives== | |||
There are generalized criticisms of alternatives to market oriented economicswhich are often applied against any alternative to market oriented economic arrangements that seek to reduce or eliminate prices, wages, and private property such as ], ], or ]. These points are used to not just argue in favor of markets, especially free markets, but as counter points to criticism of market oriented economics. | |||
Some ] and ] promote a form of market socialism in which enterprises are owned and managed cooperatively by their workforce so that the profits directly remunerate the employee-owners. These cooperative enterprises would compete with each other in the same way private companies compete with each other in a capitalist market. The first major elaboration of this type of market socialism was made by ] and was called mutualism. | |||
Milton Friedman argues that economies need functioning prices and private property in order to function properly and that the more restrictions that are placed on prices and property rights the less well the economy will function. Friedman believes that the elimination of prices, wages, and private property rights will lead to an economy that does not function at all. They believe that without property arrangements, prices, and wages, there is no way to calculate individuals' needs and wants, and hoarding may result. Finally, Friedman believes that any alternative to a market economy and free prices requires coercsion to operate because it requires coercion to eliminate (and maintain an alternative economic arrangement free of) prices, wages, and property. Friedman discusses the role of the market, prices and wages in "]" and "]" A condensed and simplified non-academic oriented version by Dr. Robert Reed can be read online here | |||
Self-managed market socialism was promoted in Yugoslavia by economists ] and ]. In the self-managed model of socialism, firms would be directly owned by their employees and the management board would be elected by employees. These cooperative firms would compete with each other in a market for both capital goods and for selling consumer goods. | |||
===Prices and wages=== | |||
Microeconomists and free market scholars such as Milton Friedman have written extensively criticizing alternative economic arrangements to free market economies. Friedman has argued that it is very difficult and inefficient for central planners to guess or approximate values and demand for goods and services and that it is better to let prices float freely by allowing the market to determine them. Friedman also believes that free floating prices and wages help to best approximate the needs and wants of society and that many alternatives to the market oriented economy have no real way of quantifying "needs". | |||
=== Socialist market economy === | |||
Freidman does believe that workers who take risks deserve more pay than workers who do not, but he also believes that workers are paid based on the ] and skill they provide their company. These microeconomists believe that pay scales based on sacrifice, as well as the elimination of wages or even implementation of maximum wages, are insufficient to provide the necessary ]s toward innovation and ] that occurs in a market oriented economy through the unlimited income rewards for ]s, ]s, entertainers, ]s or other such pursuits. Friedman believes that an inefficient, non-productive and non-innovative economic society would emerge if these incentives are eliminated. | |||
Following the ], China developed what it calls a ] in which most of the economy is under state ownership, with the state enterprises organized as joint-stock companies with various government agencies owning controlling shares through a shareholder system. Prices are set by a largely free-price system and the state-owned enterprises are not subjected to micromanagement by a government planning agency. A similar system called ] has emerged in Vietnam following the {{lang|vi|]}} reforms in 1986. This system is frequently characterized as ] instead of market socialism because there is no meaningful degree of employee self-management in firms, because the state enterprises retain their profits instead of distributing them to the workforce or government and because many function as ''de facto'' private enterprises. The profits neither finance a social dividend to benefit the population at large, nor do they accrue to their employees. In China, this economic model is presented as a ] to explain the dominance of capitalistic management practices and forms of enterprise organization in both the state and non-state sectors. | |||
== In religion == | |||
===Markets and cooperation=== | |||
A wide range of philosophers and theologians have linked market economies to concepts from monotheistic religions. ] described capitalism as being closely related to Catholicism, but ] drew a connection between capitalism and ]. The economist ] has stated that his work was inspired by the healing characteristics of Judaism. ] ] of the ] draws a correlation between modern capitalism and the Jewish image of the ].<ref>Lord Sacks, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171220071711/https://www.huffingtonpost.com/chief-rabbi-lord-sacks/religious-values-market-economy_b_1144469.html |date=2017-12-20 }}, ''HuffPost'', February 11, 2012</ref> | |||
Friedman also believes that the market, especially the free market, provides appropriate incentives toward promoting ], even among strangers. He believes market oriented economies are the most efficient at transmitting information on supply, demand, and the ]s, all of which are necessary to bring diverse people together for the common purpose of producing for consumption. | |||
=== Christianity === | |||
Profits become the motivator for aligning diverse interests and diverse people for a single goal. When included in a competitive economic system where voluntary transactions are the mode of trade, profits become a strong incentive to align capitalists and labor to produce whatever goods or services are demanded by consumers. | |||
In the Christian faith, the ] movement advocated involving the church in labor market capitalism. Many priests and nuns integrated themselves into labor organizations while others moved into the slums to live among the poor. The ] was interpreted as a call for social equality and the elimination of poverty. However, the ] was highly active in his criticism of liberation theology. He was particularly concerned about the increased fusion between ] and ]. He closed Catholic institutions that taught liberation theology and dismissed some of its activists from the church.<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191029113428/http://www.bbc.co.uk/religion/religions/christianity/beliefs/liberationtheology.shtml |date=2019-10-29 }}, ''BBC'', July 18, 2011</ref> | |||
=== |
=== Buddhism === | ||
The Buddhist approach to the market economy was dealt with in ]'s 1966 essay "Buddhist Economics". Schumacher asserted that a market economy guided by Buddhist principles would more successfully meet the needs of its people. He emphasized the importance or pursuing occupations that adhered to Buddhist teachings. The essay would later become required reading for a course that Clair Brown offered at ].<ref>Kathleen Maclay, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200413091318/https://news.berkeley.edu/2014/03/13/buddhist-economics-oxymoron-or-idea-whose-time-has-come/ |date=2020-04-13 }}, ''Berkeley News'', March 13, 2014</ref> | |||
Friedman and Hayek both believe that market economies lead to cooperative transactions between people and between states. The more free the market economy the greater incentive for cooperation. | |||
== Criticism == | |||
Friedman states, "International free trade fosters harmonious relations among nations that differ in culture and institutions" <ref> Friedman, Milton and Rose Friedman, ''Free to Choose a Personal Statement'', pp. 51. </ref> | |||
The economist ] argues that markets suffer from informational inefficiency and the presumed efficiency of markets stems from the faulty assumptions of ] welfare economics, particularly the assumption of perfect and costless information and related incentive problems. Neoclassical economics assumes static equilibrium and efficient markets require that there be no non-], even though nonconvexities are pervasive in modern economies. Stiglitz's critique applies to both existing models of capitalism and to hypothetical models of market socialism. However, Stiglitz does not advocate replacing markets, but instead states that there is a significant role for ] to boost the efficiency of markets and to address the pervasive market failures that exist in contemporary economies.<ref>{{cite book |last= Michie|first= Jonathan | author-link = Jonathan Michie|title= Reader's Guide to the Social Sciences |publisher= Routledge|year=2001|isbn= 978-1579580919|page =1012 |quote=Stiglitz criticizes the first and second welfare theorems for being based on the assumptions of complete markets (including a full set of futures and risk markets) and perfect and costless information, which are simply not true. Incentives are dubious too. Thus, capitalist markets are also not efficient and there is some role for government intervention. The ability to decentralize using the price system requires that there be no nonconvexities, but nonconvexities are pervasive.}}</ref> A fair market economy is in fact a ] or a ] model and for a participant competitor in such a model there is no more than 50% of success chances at any given moment. Due to the ] nature of any fair market and being market participants subject to the law of ] which impose reinvesting an increasing part of profits, the mean statistical chance of bankruptcy within the ] of any participant is also 50%<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Podobnik|first1=Boris|last2=Horvatic|first2=Davor|last3=Petersen|first3=Alexander M.|last4=Urošević|first4=Branko|last5=Stanley|first5=H. Eugene|date=2010-10-26|title=Bankruptcy risk model and empirical tests|journal=Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America|volume=107|issue=43|pages=18325–18330|doi=10.1073/pnas.1011942107|issn=0027-8424|pmc=2972955|pmid=20937903|arxiv=1011.2670|bibcode=2010PNAS..10718325P|doi-access=free}}</ref> and 100% whether an infinite sample of time is considered. | |||
] and ] claim that "markets inherently produce ]".<ref name='Comparison'/> Albert states that even if everyone started out with a ] (doing a mix of roles of varying creativity, responsibility and empowerment) in a market economy, class divisions would arise, arguing: | |||
] discusses the market alternative and its negative effects on cooperation: | |||
<blockquote>Without taking the argument that far, it is evident that in a market system with uneven distribution of empowering work, such as Economic Democracy, some workers will be more able than others to capture the benefits of economic gain. For example, if one worker designs cars and another builds them, the designer will use his cognitive skills more frequently than the builder. In the long term, the designer will become more adept at conceptual work than the builder, giving the former greater bargaining power in a firm over the distribution of income. A conceptual worker who is not satisfied with his income can threaten to work for a company that will pay him more. The effect is a class division between conceptual and manual laborers, and ultimately managers and workers, and a de facto labor market for conceptual workers.<ref name='Comparison'>{{cite news|first=Adam |last=Weiss |title=A Comparison of Economic Democracy and Participatory Economics |date=2005-05-04 |url=http://www.zmag.org/znet/viewArticle/6345 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090402013013/http://www.zmag.org/znet/viewArticle/6345 |url-status=dead |archive-date=2009-04-02 |work=] |access-date=2008-06-26 }}</ref></blockquote> | |||
:"economic planning, conducted independently on a national scale, are bound in the aggregate effect to be harmful even from a purely economic point of view and, in addition to produce serious international friction. That there is little hope of international order or lasting peace so long as every country is free to employ whatever measures it desires in its own immediate interest, however damaging they may be to others…" <ref> Hayek, F.A., (1944). ''The Road to Serfdom'', pp. 240. The ]</ref> | |||
] argues in the ] tradition that the logic of the market inherently produces inequitable outcomes and leads to unequal exchanges, arguing that ]'s moral intent and moral philosophy espousing equal exchange was undermined by the practice of the free markets he championed. The development of the market economy involved coercion, exploitation and violence that Smith's moral philosophy could not countenance. McNally also criticizes market socialists for believing in the possibility of fair markets based on equal exchanges to be achieved by purging parasitical elements from the market economy such as ] of the ]. McNally argues that ] is an oxymoron when ] is defined as an end to ].<ref>{{cite book|last=McNally|first=David|title=Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the Marxist Critique|publisher=Verso|year=1993|isbn=978-0860916062}}{{page needed|date=March 2022}}</ref> | |||
===The role of private property=== | |||
] critics such as Friedman also argue that private property rights are the staple by which people and society build wealth and that eliminating private property rights eliminates a primary incentive to build and protect wealth. Friedman believes that wealth is not a ] game, as is generally believed by advocates of market alternatives, but a ''positive-sum'' game as wealth is almost always growing; meaning one person may gain a lot while no one else may actually lose. | |||
== The role of supply and demand in a market economy == | |||
===Externalities=== | |||
Supply and demand play an instrumental role in driving market economies by setting both prices and quantities traded in markets. Supply is defined as any increase in price leading to an increase in supply from producers; demand on the other hand means any drop leads to an increase in desired quantities from consumers; these two laws meet at equilibrium when provided quantity equals quantity demanded - known as equilibrium price/quantity equilibrium point.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Jadidzadeh |first1=Ali |last2=Serletis |first2=Apostolos |date=2017-03-01 |title=How does the U.S. natural gas market react to demand and supply shocks in the crude oil market? |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0140988317300166 |journal=Energy Economics |language=en |volume=63 |pages=66–74 |doi=10.1016/j.eneco.2017.01.007 |s2cid=157939150 |issn=0140-9883 |access-date=2023-04-21 |archive-date=2020-06-23 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200623201303/https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0140988317300166 |url-status=live }}</ref> Prices play an extremely vital role in market economies by providing important information about commodity and service availability. When there is strong demand but limited supply, prices increase, signaling to producers that there may be opportunities to increase profits by producing more of that product.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Kiseleva |first=Irina Anatolievna |date=2021-07-10 |title=Simulations of Supply and Demand Forecasting in A Market Economy |url=http://www.revistageintec.net/index.php/revista/article/view/2218 |journal=Revista Gestão Inovação e Tecnologias |volume=11 |issue=4 |pages=1669–1684 |doi=10.47059/revistageintec.v11i4.2218 |s2cid=236467969 |access-date=2023-04-21 |archive-date=2022-01-27 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220127201529/https://www.revistageintec.net/index.php/revista/article/view/2218 |url-status=live }}</ref> Conversely, when there is low demand with increased supply then prices reduce, showing manufacturers they must either reduce output or find methods of cutting costs in order to stay competitive and remain profitable. | |||
Milton Friedman does not deny that there are market externalities and offers many solutions to solving problems such as pollution. For example Friedman advocates the selling of ] via permits to any and all legal persons. This allows the transmission of information of how harmful society believes this pollution to be as private citizens may purchase pollution rights and never use them which forces corporations to innovate and pollute less or face a stiff penalty. He notes that without selling pollution rights to all legal citizens there is no way of transmitting information to solve this externality and that simply regulating pollution away does not solve the pollution externality but only hides it temporarily. Friedman also believes that economic externalities occur in all forms of economic arrangements but are most harmful when they are the result of government intervention as it is very difficult to solve government made externalities. He believes that the elimination of private property, wages, and free floating prices will result in serious government externalities such as shortages, inefficient use of resources and waste. | |||
External factors, including shifting technological standards, new government laws, and natural catastrophes can have a substantial impact on supply and demand. Technological innovations may increase supply, while laws issued by governments could decrease it or even demand. Natural disasters have the ability to severely disrupt supply chains, creating shortages of key items that increase costs while simultaneously decreasing demand. Supply and demand play an indispensable role in any market economy by ensuring prices reflect market forces accurately, adapting accordingly as conditions shift between supply and demand situations, while producers adjust production according to price signals from consumers, fulfilling customers' requests while giving individuals freedom in making purchasing choices based on personal preferences or financial constraints. Thus supply and demand play an instrumental part in shaping and stabilizing economies governed by market forces. | |||
==="Participatory" capitalism=== | |||
Milton Friedman asserts, as would many other microeconomists, that consumers constantly participate in market-oriented capitalism with every purchase they make. By making purchases, they argue, every individual signals to producers in the market what goods are ]d, the quantity of such good to produce, of what quality, what it shall be made of, or other properties that are desired. Friedman asserts that prices and money already generate the appropriate level of consumer participation through every purchase within every transaction. Furthermore, they believe market alternatives would not properly transmit this information to the market and would would occur is very little product ], thus many people would not get what they really wanted or would otherwise be willing to pay for. | |||
== Sustainable market economy == | |||
He believes that no other economic arrangement can signal consumer wants to producers and suppliers better than prices in a market economy. He also believes that floating prices are the most efficient as consumers immediatly input information on the value and demand for a product while prices also immediatly reflect the value, demand, and supply of a particular good or service. This information, he argues, will be difficult to guess for any planner, regardless of the size of the planning board, and what will result is a redistrobution of goods away from their highest valued use resulting in a society whose general welfare has been reduced. Thus some low valued goods will be overproduced and some high valued goods will be underproduced or not produced at all. | |||
A sustainable market economy seeks to balance economic expansion and environmental preservation.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Tomassetti |first=Paolo |date=2018–2019 |title=Labor Law and Environmental Sustainability |url=https://heinonline.org/HOL/Page?handle=hein.journals/cllpj40&id=73&div=&collection= |journal=Comparative Labor Law & Policy Journal |volume=40 |pages=61}}</ref> It acknowledges that sustainable environmental protection and resource management are essential for long-term economic growth. To achieve this balance, implementing sustainable practices across sectors, such as lowering carbon emissions, developing renewable energy sources, and putting circular economy ideas into practice. Tax incentives, carbon trading programs, and environmental requirements are just a few ways government rules and policies encourage enterprises to adopt sustainable practices. | |||
At the same time, consumer demand for eco-friendly goods and services and understanding of these issues may influence market dynamics to favour more sustainable options.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Zhang |first1=Xiaoyun |last2=Dong |first2=Feng |date=January 2020 |title=Why Do Consumers Make Green Purchase Decisions? Insights from a Systematic Review |journal=International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health |language=en |volume=17 |issue=18 |pages=6607 |doi=10.3390/ijerph17186607 |pmid=32932797 |pmc=7559813 |issn=1660-4601 |doi-access=free }}</ref> A sustainable market economy may encourage innovation, provide green employment, and guarantee the welfare of future generations by incorporating environmental factors into economic decision-making. Prioritizing sustainability while preserving economic development needs cooperation between governments, corporations, and people. | |||
===Markets and poverty=== | |||
One of the more major complaints of markets and capitalism is a belief that they create ] of labor and poverty. These critics cite the 19th century and ] as a primary example of how growing markets and capitalism created more poverty. Milton Friedman notes that the 19th century resulted an explosion of wealth for society which created more visible poor not more poor. | |||
== See also == | |||
Poverty is often conflated with capitalism and with marxist notions of class conflict. Free market economists such as Milton Friedman and Hernando De Soto make compelling arguments on how poverty is often created and sustained by government interference and regulation of the economy. Some ways in which governments can promote poverty is through unequal property rights, high transaction costs to property rights, perverse and complex tax codes which provide no incentive for the poor to save or build capital, tariffs and other trade barriers, and labor laws such as minimum wages and work hour limitations; microeconomists argue that such labor laws increase unemployment. | |||
{{Portal|Capitalism|Economics|Law|Libertarianism}} | |||
{{div col|colwidth=22em}} | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
{{div col end}} | |||
== References == | |||
Many non-market oriented alternatives to market arrangements, and even social-market proponents criticize market economies for their income inequality. Friedman and many other microeconomists note that this can be an irrational response as there is nothing unfair about income inequality in a positive sum relationship where people are engaging in voluntary transactions. Friedman argues that the entertainers or sports atheletes are paid high wages for the same reason ]s, ]s, ]s, and ]s are paid high wages: consumers value their service and are willing to pay those wages through multiple voluntary transactions. | |||
{{reflist|2}} | |||
== Further reading == | |||
====Free market solutions to poverty==== | |||
{{Refbegin|30em}} | |||
Free market economists argue that planned economies and welfare will not solve poverty problems but only make them worse. They believe that the only way to solve poverty is not by shuffling and sharing existing wealth through redistributing wealth but by creating new wealth. They believe that this is most efficiently achieved through low levels of government regulation and interference, ], equal property rights, money systems, ]s, and tax reform and reduction, thus converting even the poor members of society into capitalists. Some further extend this criticism to any alternative to free market economies. | |||
* Åslund, Anders. “The Rise of State Capitalism.” Russia's Crony Capitalism: The Path from Market Economy to Kleptocracy, ], 2019, pp. 97–131, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctvgc61tr.8}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Beckert, J. and Aspers, P.|title=The Worth of Goods: Valuation and Pricing in the Economy|isbn=9780191618680|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=4gFREAAAQBAJ|year=2011|publisher=]}} | |||
* {{cite encyclopedia |last=Boudreaux |first=Donald J. |author-link=Donald J. Boudreaux |editor-first=Ronald |editor-last=Hamowy |editor-link=Ronald Hamowy |encyclopedia=The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism |chapter-url=https://sk.sagepub.com/reference/libertarianism/n114.xml |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=yxNgXs3TkJYC |doi=10.4135/9781412965811.n114 |year=2008 |publisher=]; ] |location=Thousand Oaks, CA |isbn=978-1412965804 |oclc=750831024 |lccn=2008009151 |pages=187–189 |title=Free-Market Economy |access-date=2022-03-31 |archive-date=2023-01-09 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230109234738/https://books.google.com/books?id=yxNgXs3TkJYC |url-status=live }} | |||
* Boushey, Heather. “Market Structure.” Unbound: How Inequality Constricts Our Economy and What We Can Do about It, ], 2019, pp. 114–138, {{JSTOR|j.ctv24trb7p.11}}. | |||
* Chari, Anusha. “The International Market for Corporate Control.” Global Goliaths: Multinational Corporations in the 21st Century Economy, edited by C. FRITZ FOLEY et al., ], 2021, pp. 129–182, {{JSTOR|10.7864/j.ctv11hpt7b.7}}. | |||
* Cochoy, Franck. “Another Discipline for the Market Economy: Marketing as a Performative Knowledge and Know-How for Capitalism.” ] 46, no. 1_suppl (May 1998): 194–221. {{doi|10.1111/j.1467-954X.1998.tb03475.x}} | |||
* Cordier, S., Pareschi, L. & Toscani, G. On a Kinetic Model for a Simple Market Economy. ] 120, 253–277 (2005). {{doi|10.1007/s10955-005-5456-0}} | |||
* Corneo, Giacoma and Daniel Steuer. “Market Economy Plus Welfare State.” Is Capitalism Obsolete?: A Journey through Alternative Economic Systems, ], 2017, pp. 225–248, {{JSTOR|j.ctv24w62sr.14}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Cowen, T.|title=In Praise of Commercial Culture|isbn=978-0674029934|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ADydOEGjQQgC|year=2009|publisher=]}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=]|title=The Market as God|isbn=978-0674973152|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=e6nrDAAAQBAJ|year=2016|publisher=]}} | |||
* Cronin, James E. “Market Rules and the International Economy.” Global Rules: America, Britain and a Disordered World, ], 2014, pp. 121–147, {{JSTOR|j.ctt1bhkp54.8}}. | |||
* Cyndecka, Małgorzata Agnieszka. “The Applicability and Application of the Market Economy Investor Principle: Lessons Learnt from the Financial Crisis.” European State Aid Law Quarterly, vol. 16, no. 4, Lexxion Verlagsgesellschaft mbH, 2017, pp. 512–526, {{JSTOR|stable/26694186}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Doti, J. and Lee, D.|title=The Market Economy: A Reader|isbn=978-0195332582|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=0gABGQAACAAJ|year=1991|publisher=Oxford University Press}} | |||
* Ebner, Alexander. “Continuity and Change in Germany's Social Market Economy: A Matter of Economic Style?” Contesting Deregulation: Debates, Practices and Developments in the West since the 1970s, edited by Knud Andresen and Stefan Müller, 1st ed., vol. 31, ], 2017, pp. 41–56, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctvw04gps.7}}. | |||
Many ] attribute poverty to insufficient protection or recognition of property rights. | |||
* Finn, Daniel k. “What Can Be Done about Market Injustice?” Consumer Ethics in a Global Economy: How Buying Here Causes Injustice There, ], 2019, pp. 143–153, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctvswx7rz.14}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D.|title=Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage|isbn=978-0191647703|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=EU02HzYJeFsC|year=2001|publisher=]}} | |||
* Hirschfeld, Mary L. “Toward a Humane Economy: A Pragmatic Approach.” Aquinas and the Market: Toward a Humane Economy, ], 2018, pp. 191–218, {{JSTOR|j.ctvsf1p3x.10}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Isachsen, A.J. and Gylfason, T. and Hamilton, C. and Hamilton, P.E.I.I.E.S.C.B. and Isachsen, P.I.E.A.J.|title=Understanding the Market Economy|isbn=978-0198773573|lccn=lc92024790|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=6sq8QgAACAAJ|year=1992|publisher=]}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=Johansson, P.O.|title=An Introduction to Modern Welfare Economics|isbn=978-0521356954|lccn=90020420|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=T2x5PaEnXI0C|year=1991|publisher=]}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. and Pencavel, J.|title=Market Structure and Innovation|isbn=978-0521293853|lccn=81012254|series=Cambridge Surveys of Economic Literature|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=8GWfOQd8pGAC|year=1982|publisher=]}} | |||
* Kratz, Agatha, et al. Time's Up: China's Coming Battle for Market Economy Status. ], 2016, {{JSTOR|resrep21581}}. | |||
] argues that poverty is sustained by ] that generates high costs to property ownership through ] and ]. He argues that many of the poor in the ] are unable to develop their property or own property because this regulation is too costly to overcome. As a result, they argue they are unable to generate wealth in a legal market that is full of regulation and are forced to resort to operate in an extralegal market that hampers wealth creation, thus hampering their ability to be pulled out of poverty. | |||
* Kunde, Meg. “Making the Free Market Moral: Ronald Reagan's Covenantal Economy.” Rhetoric and Public Affairs, vol. 22, no. 2, ], 2019, pp. 217–252, {{doi|10.14321/rhetpublaffa.22.2.0217}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Lavigne, M.|title=The Economics of Transition: From Socialist Economy to Market Economy|isbn=978-1349273133|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=VE5dDwAAQBAJ|year=1999|publisher=]}}{{Dead link|date=February 2024 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }} | |||
* {{cite book|author=]|title=Business Organization and the Myth of the Market Economy|isbn=978-0521447881|lccn=91008865|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=g6S9wYN7|year=1993|publisher=]}}{{Dead link|date=February 2024 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }} | |||
* Leshem, Dotan. “From Ecclesiastical to Market Economy.” The Origins of Neoliberalism: Modeling the Economy from Jesus to Foucault, ], 2016, pp. 153–182, {{JSTOR|10.7312/lesh17776.11}}. | |||
* Lothian, Tamara. “The Democratized Market Economy in Latin America (and Elsewhere): An Exercise in Institutional Thinking Within Law and Political Economy.” Law and the Wealth of Nations: Finance, Prosperity, and Democracy, ], 2017, pp. 138–196, {{JSTOR|10.7312/loth17466.8}}. | |||
* Lothian, Tamara. “The Democratized Market Economy.” Law and the Wealth of Nations: Finance, Prosperity, and Democracy, ], 2017, pp. 113–137, {{JSTOR|10.7312/loth17466.7}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=] and ]|title=Development Strategy and Management of the Market Economy|number=v. 1|isbn=978-0199241347|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Sc4RVcV9ZQEC|year=2000|publisher=]}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=Malloy, R.P.|title=Law and Market Economy: Reinterpreting the Values of Law and Economics|isbn=978-0521787314|lccn=00711747|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=NalFmN3njLEC|year=2000|publisher=]}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=McKinnie, M.|title=Theatre in Market Economies|isbn=978-1107000391|lccn=2020039520|series=Theatre and Performance Theory|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ATQTEAAAQBAJ|year=2021|publisher=Cambridge University Press}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=]|title=The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to a Market Economy|isbn=978-0801847431|lccn=93021886|series=The Johns Hopkins Studies in Development|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=fy1YaZTCpdAC|year=1993|orig-date=1991|publisher=]|doi=10.1257/jep.5.4.107}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=Mirowski, P. and Plehwe, D.|title=The Road from Mont Pèlerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective, With a New Preface|isbn=978-0674088344|lccn=2016303988|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=4lWHCwAAQBAJ|year=2015|publisher=]}} | |||
* Mittermaier, Karl and Isabella Mittermaier. “Free-Market Dogmatism and Pragmatism.” In The Hand Behind the Invisible Hand: Dogmatic and Pragmatic Views on Free Markets and the State of Economic Theory, 1st ed., 23–26. ], 2020. {{doi|10.2307/j.ctv186grks.10}} | |||
* ], ], ], The Transition to a Market Economy: Pitfalls of Partial Reform, ], Volume 107, Issue 3, August 1992, pp. 889–906, {{doi|10.2307/2118367}} | |||
* ]. “The Role of the State in Making a Market Economy.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE) / Zeitschrift Für Die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft, vol. 156, no. 1, Mohr Siebeck GmbH & Co. KG, 2000, pp. 64–88, {{JSTOR|40752185}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=Nee, V. and Opper, S.|title=Capitalism from Below: Markets and Institutional Change in China|isbn=978-0674065390|lccn=2011042367|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=kUX2H1EDs-8C|year=2012|publisher=]}} | |||
* {{cite journal|author = ]|title = The market economy, and the scientific commons|journal = ]|volume = 33|number = 3|pages = 455–471|year = 2004|issn = 0048-7333|doi = 10.1016/j.respol.2003.09.008|url = https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0048733303001513|hdl = 10419/89454|hdl-access = free}} | |||
Economists such as Milton Friedman argue that ]s, ]es, ]es, ] and tax on investments all provide perverse incentives toward wealth creation that hurt the poor the most. He further argues that some of these arrangements are also wealth transfers from poor to rich; such as tariffs and social security. He argues that these regressive tax burdons encourage low productivity and little savings and investment that would otherwise lift the poor out of poverty. | |||
* Ngo, Tak-Wing. “Asia and the Historicity of the Market Economy.” Verge: Studies in Global Asias, vol. 1, no. 1, ], 2015, pp. 44–50, {{doi|10.5749/vergstudglobasia.1.1.0044}}. | |||
Others have argued that welfare] perpetuates poverty by providing incentives counter to wealth creation. Proponents of the ] and economists such as Milton Friedman favor eliminating welfare programs that prevent benefits from those earning above a certain income. They believe that these income caps as eligibility to receive benefits provide an incentive for laborers to earn less than they actually could in order to gain free benefits from government programs. | |||
* Pomeranz, Kenneth. “Market Economies in Europe and Asia.” The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy, NED-New edition, vol. 117, ], 2021, pp. 69–108, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctv161f3dr.7}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Ramanna, K.|title=Political Standards: Corporate Interest, Ideology, and Leadership in the Shaping of Accounting Rules for the Market Economy|isbn=978-0226210742|lccn=2015011503|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=x9UpCwAAQBAJ|year=2015|publisher=]}} | |||
* Robin, Ron. “Castrophobia and the Free Market: The Wohlstetters’ Moral Economy.” The Cold World They Made: The Strategic Legacy of Roberta and Albert Wohlstetter, ], 2016, pp. 118–138, {{JSTOR|j.ctv253f7gh.8}}. | |||
* Rodgers, Daniel T. “Moralizing the Market Economy.” As a City on a Hill: The Story of America's Most Famous Lay Sermon, ], 2018, pp. 96–106, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctvc778b0.10}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Root, H.L.|title=Networking History: East vs. West in a Complex Systems Perspective|isbn=978-1108488990|lccn=2019033289|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=NFjPDwAAQBAJ|year=2020|publisher=]}} | |||
* {{cite book|author1=Rosser, J.B.|author2=Rosser, M.V.|title=Comparative Economics in a Transforming World Economy|isbn=978-0262182348|lccn=2003059363|series=The MIT Press|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=y3Mr6TgalqMC|year=2004|publisher=]|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208160845/https://books.google.com/books?id=y3Mr6TgalqMC|url-status=live}} | |||
====Social market solutions to poverty==== | |||
Advocates of the third way believe that there is a legimate role the government can play in fighting poverty. They believe this can be achieved through the creation of social safety nets such as ]. Examples include welfare, in terms of direct payments to the needy, as well as ] and ]. | |||
* Schebesta, Martin. Climate Change, Digitisation and Globalisation — Does the Social Market Economy Need Renewal? ], 2020, {{JSTOR|resrep25282}}. | |||
==Markets and communist states== | |||
* {{cite book|author=Sedgwick, P.H.|title=The Market Economy and Christian Ethics|isbn=978-1107112483|series=New studies in Christian ethics|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=dmNdzgEACAAJ|year=1999|publisher=]|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208160748/https://books.google.com/books?id=dmNdzgEACAAJ|url-status=live}} | |||
In the 1980s, most of the planned economies in the world attempted to transform themselves into market economies, for various reasons and with varying degrees of success. In the ], this process was known as ] while in ] the creation of a "]" was one element of ]. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Shapiro, C. and Varian, H.R.|title=Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy|isbn=978-1422154625|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=z0hQ12PrERMC|year=1998|publisher=]|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208160803/https://books.google.com/books?id=z0hQ12PrERMC|url-status=live}} | |||
Contrary to communist theory proposed by Marx and Engles and later adapted by Lenin, Stalin, Mao the ]; the largest country whose ruling party refers to itself as communist, runs ] dedicated to capitalist enterprise, free from central government control. After opening up trade to the world under ], the People's Republic of China runs some of the most economically free regions in the world, including ], which is regarded by the Hoover Institute and the Wall Street Journal as the world's freest economy . | |||
* {{cite book|author=Skidelsky, R.|title=Money and Government: The Past and Future of Economics|isbn=978-0300244243|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=WTVxDwAAQBAJ|year=2018|publisher=]|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208160754/https://books.google.com/books?id=WTVxDwAAQBAJ|url-status=live}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=]|title=Whither Socialism?|isbn=978-0262691826|lccn=lc93043188|series=Wicksell Lectures|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Bpyq1CK2HgAC|year=1996|publisher=MIT Press|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208160802/https://books.google.com/books?id=Bpyq1CK2HgAC|url-status=live}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=Sumner, S.|title=The Money Illusion: Market Monetarism, the Great Recession, and the Future of Monetary Policy|isbn=978-0226773681|lccn=2020056573|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=4kQ6EAAAQBAJ|year=2021|publisher=]|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208160735/https://books.google.com/books?id=4kQ6EAAAQBAJ|url-status=live}} | |||
* Sundararajan, Arun. “The Sharing Economy, Market Economies, and Gift Economies.” The Sharing Economy: The End of Employment and the Rise of Crowd-Based Capitalism, ], 2016, pp. 23–46, {{JSTOR|j.ctt1c2cqh3.5}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Tanzi, V.|title=Government versus Markets: The Changing Economic Role of the State|isbn=978-1139499736|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=0|year=2011|publisher=]}}{{Dead link|date=February 2024 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }} | |||
* Temin, Peter. “The Labor Market.” The Roman Market Economy, ], 2013, pp. 114–138, {{JSTOR|j.ctt1r2g35.11}}. | |||
* Tomlinson, Jim. “The Failures of Neoliberalism in Britain since the 1970s: The Limits on ‘Market Forces’ in a Deindustrialising Economy and a ‘New Speenhamland.’” The Neoliberal Age?: Britain since the 1970s, edited by Aled Davies et al., ], 2021, pp. 94–111, {{JSTOR|j.ctv1smjwgq.12}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Ulrich, P. and Fearns, J.|title=Integrative Economic Ethics: Foundations of a Civilized Market Economy|isbn=978-0521172424|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=DNLOSAAACAAJ|year=2010|publisher=Cambridge University Press|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208160724/https://books.google.com/books?id=DNLOSAAACAAJ|url-status=live}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=von Stackelberg, H. and Von, S.H. and Peacock, A.T.|title=The Theory of the Market Economy|lccn=52004949|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=o3ceAAAAIAAJ|year=1952|publisher=]|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208160724/https://books.google.com/books?id=o3ceAAAAIAAJ|url-status=live}} | |||
* Weiss, Hadas. “Capital's Fidelity: Financialization in the German Social Market Economy.” Financialization: Relational Approaches, edited by Chris Hann and Don Kalb, 1st ed., vol. 6, ], 2020, pp. 177–195, {{doi|10.2307/j.ctv21hrft2.12}}. | |||
* Widerquist, Karl and Grant S. McCall. “The Negative Freedom Argument for the Market Economy.” The Prehistory of Private Property: Implications for Modern Political Theory, ], 2021, pp. 79–99, {{JSTOR|10.3366/j.ctv1hm8h0j.9}}. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Wolf, M.|title=Why Globalization Works|isbn=978-0300251739|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ppKsDwAAQBAJ|year=2005|publisher=]|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208161337/https://books.google.com/books?id=ppKsDwAAQBAJ|url-status=live}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=Yeazell, S.C.|title=Lawsuits in a Market Economy: The Evolution of Civil Litigation|isbn=978-0226546421|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=YKJRDwAAQBAJ|year=2018|publisher=]|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208161248/https://books.google.com/books?id=YKJRDwAAQBAJ|url-status=live}} | |||
These ] have few restrictions upon businesses, industries, imports and exports, including the elimination of duties, and a free price system. Since the opening of the Free Trade Zones China has maintained a growth rate of over 8%, and originally saw growth rates around 12%. These Special Economic Zones are different than the ], as practiced in the Soviet Union, because the SEZs allow for capitalists to build and expand their industries and private property, free from the control of the central government. SEZ's operate under market economy rather than the state capitalist top down ] approach. | |||
* {{cite book|author=Zakim, M.|title=Accounting for Capitalism: The World the Clerk Made|isbn=978-0226545899|lccn=2017035753|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=0OdRDwAAQBAJ|year=2018|publisher=]|access-date=2022-03-11|archive-date=2024-02-08|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240208161334/https://books.google.com/books?id=0OdRDwAAQBAJ|url-status=live}} | |||
{{Refend}} | |||
According to China.org "After opening Shenzhen and other three coastal cities in South China as special economic regions and then dozens of economic and technological development zones in the 1980s, the country introduced free trade zones in the early 1990s in 15 coast cities, including Shanghai, Guangzhou, Shenzhen and Tianjin." | |||
In addition, China has recently declared private property to be a right and as also allowed the opening of foreign capitalist enterprises such as Wal-Mart to operate shopping centers in the Special Economic Zones. | |||
Several other countries ruled by Communist Parties, such as Vietnam, have also made pro-market reforms in the last few decades. | |||
==Criticism of market economy== | |||
{{Sectstub}} | |||
==References== | |||
<references/> | |||
==Further reading== | |||
* | |||
* De Soto, Hernando. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere else, Basic Books, 2000. | |||
* | |||
* Friedman, Milton. Capitalism and Freedom, University of Chicago Press, 1962. | |||
* Friedman, Milton and Rose Friedman. Free to Choose: A Personal Statement, Harcort Brace Janovich, 1980. | |||
* Hayek, F.A., The Road to Serfdom, University of Chicago Press, 1944. | |||
* Hayek, F.A. The Constitution of Liberty, University of Chicago Press, 1960. | |||
* Lindsey, Brink. Against the Dead Hand: The Uncertain Struggle for Global Capitalism, Wiley, 2001. | |||
* Przeworski, Adam. Democracy and the Market (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1991. | |||
* Reed, Robert, Max Schanzenbach, | |||
* Schumpeter, Joseph. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper Perennial, 1962. | |||
* Smith, Adam. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 1776. | |||
* Yergin, Daniel, and Joseph Stanislaw. The Commanding Heights: the Battle for the World Economy, Simon and Schuster, 1998 | |||
==See also== | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
==External links== | |||
] | |||
*{{Commonscatinline|Market economy}} | |||
* at '']'' Online. | |||
{{Aspects of capitalism}} | |||
] | |||
{{Economic liberalism}} | |||
] | |||
{{Liberalism}} | |||
] | |||
{{Authority control}} | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
{{DEFAULTSORT:Market Economy}} | |||
- Motivation to manufacture goods at least cost could lead to business firms making production decisions with little regard for safety of workers or the quality of environment. | |||
] | |||
- Reduction in Quality of products: The quality of products can fall down as the producers have to reduce cost. | |||
] | |||
- It does not guarantee full employment for workers. As to reduce cost the company can fire off workers anything they want according to their self made rules of temporary employment. | |||
] | |||
- Growing social and economic inequality (the rich get richer and everyone else gets poorer). Because those with more money also start a disproportional political influence, which they use to make still more money. | |||
] | |||
- Reduction in social benefits and welfare. As there are no social safety, for jobs etc. People feel unsecured about their future. | |||
] | |||
- Good are produced in excess as the poor workers are not paid well due to market competition. So they don’t have the power of money to buy commodities in a large number. | |||
] | |||
] |
Latest revision as of 20:13, 12 December 2024
Type of economic systemThis article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. Find sources: "Market economy" – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (November 2021) (Learn how and when to remove this message) |
Part of a series on |
Economic systems |
---|
Major types |
By ideology |
By coordination |
By regional model
|
Sectors |
Property types |
Transition |
Coordination |
Other types |
A market economy is an economic system in which the decisions regarding investment, production, and distribution to the consumers are guided by the price signals created by the forces of supply and demand. The major characteristic of a market economy is the existence of factor markets that play a dominant role in the allocation of capital and the factors of production.
Market economies range from minimally regulated free market and laissez-faire systems where state activity is restricted to providing public goods and services and safeguarding private ownership, to interventionist forms where the government plays an active role in correcting market failures and promoting social welfare. State-directed or dirigist economies are those where the state plays a directive role in guiding the overall development of the market through industrial policies or indicative planning—which guides yet does not substitute the market for economic planning—a form sometimes referred to as a mixed economy.
Market economies are contrasted with planned economies where investment and production decisions are embodied in an integrated economy-wide economic plan. In a centrally planned economy, economic planning is the principal allocation mechanism between firms rather than markets, with the economy's means of production being owned and operated by a single organizational body.
Characteristics
Property rights
For market economies to function efficiently, governments must establish clearly defined and enforceable property rights for assets and capital goods. However, property rights do not specifically mean private property rights and market economies do not logically presuppose the existence of private ownership of the means of production. Market economies can and often do include various types of cooperatives or autonomous state-owned enterprises that acquire capital goods and raw materials in capital markets. These enterprises utilize a market-determined free price system to allocate capital goods and labor. In addition, there are many variations of market socialism where the majority of capital assets are socially owned with markets allocating resources between socially owned firms. These models range from systems based on employee-owned enterprises based on self-management to a combination of public ownership of the means of production with factor markets.
Supply and demand
Supply and demand supposedly work in tandem. The economic theory is that supply slopes upwards as people buy more and demand drops as prices rise and people buy less.
Market economies rely upon a price system to signal market actors to adjust production and investment. Price formation relies on the interaction of supply and demand to reach or approximate an equilibrium where the unit price for a particular good or service is at a point where the quantity demanded equals the quantity supplied.
The price data point where the supply and demand lines intersect is called the market-clearing price.
Governments can intervene by establishing price ceilings or price floors in specific markets (such as minimum wage laws in the labor market), or use fiscal policy to discourage certain consumer behavior or to address market externalities generated by certain transactions (Pigovian taxes). Different perspectives exist on the role of government in both regulating and guiding market economies and in addressing social inequalities produced by markets. Fundamentally, a market economy requires that a price system affected by supply and demand exists as the primary mechanism for allocating resources irrespective of the level of regulation.
Capitalism
Main article: CapitalismCapitalism is an economic system where the means of production are largely or entirely privately owned and operated for a profit, structured on the process of capital accumulation. In general, in capitalist systems investment, distribution, income and prices are determined by markets, whether regulated or unregulated.
There are different variations of capitalism with different relationships to markets. In laissez-faire and free-market variations of capitalism, markets are utilized most extensively with minimal or no state intervention and minimal or no regulation over prices and the supply of goods and services. In interventionist, welfare capitalism and mixed economies, markets continue to play a dominant role, but they are regulated to some extent by the government in order to correct market failures or to promote social welfare. In state capitalist systems, markets are relied upon the least, with the state relying heavily on either indicative planning and/or state-owned enterprises to accumulate capital.
Capitalism has been dominant in the Western world since the end of mercantilism. However, it is argued that the term mixed economies more precisely describes most contemporary economies due to their containing both private-owned and state-owned enterprises. In capitalism, prices determine the demand-supply scale. Higher demand for certain goods and services leads to higher prices and lower demand for certain goods lead to lower prices, in relation to supply.
Free-market capitalism
See also: Free marketA capitalist free-market economy is an economic system where prices for goods and services are set freely by the forces of supply and demand and are expected by its supporters to reach their point of equilibrium without intervention by government policy. It typically entails support for highly competitive markets, private ownership of productive enterprises. Laissez-faire is a more extensive form of free-market economy where the role of the state is limited to protecting property rights and enforcing contracts.
Laissez-faire
Main article: Laissez-faire See also: Economic liberalismLaissez-faire is synonymous with what was referred to as strict free-market economy during the early and mid-19th century as a classical liberal ideal to achieve. It is generally understood that the necessary components for the functioning of an idealized free market include the complete absence of government regulation, subsidies, artificial price pressures and government-granted monopolies (usually classified as coercive monopoly by free market advocates) and no taxes or tariffs other than what is necessary for the government to provide protection from coercion and theft, maintaining peace and property rights and providing for basic public goods. Right-libertarian advocates of anarcho-capitalism see the state as morally illegitimate and economically unnecessary and destructive. Although laissez-faire has been commonly associated with capitalism, there is a similar left-wing laissez-faire system called free-market anarchism, also known as free-market anti-capitalism and free-market socialism to distinguish it from laissez-faire capitalism. Thus, critics of laissez-faire as commonly understood argues that a truly laissez-faire system would be anti-capitalist and socialist.
Welfare capitalism
Main article: Welfare capitalismWelfare capitalism is a capitalist economy that includes public policies favoring extensive provisions for social welfare services. The economic mechanism involves a free market and the predominance of privately owned enterprises in the economy, but public provision of universal welfare services aimed at enhancing individual autonomy and maximizing equality. Examples of contemporary welfare capitalism include the Nordic model of capitalism predominant in Northern Europe.
Regional models
Anglo-Saxon model
Main article: Anglo-Saxon modelAnglo-Saxon capitalism is the form of capitalism predominant in Anglophone countries and typified by the economy of the United States. It is contrasted with European models of capitalism such as the continental social market model and the Nordic model. Anglo-Saxon capitalism refers to a macroeconomic policy regime and capital market structure common to the Anglophone economies. Among these characteristics are low rates of taxation, more open international markets, lower labor market protections and a less generous welfare state eschewing collective bargaining schemes found in the continental and northern European models of capitalism.
East Asian model
Main article: East Asian modelThe East Asian model of capitalism involves a strong role for state investment and in some instances involves state-owned enterprises. The state takes an active role in promoting economic development through subsidies, the facilitation of "national champions" and an export-based model of growth. The actual practice of this model varies by country. This designation has been applied to the economies of China, Japan, Singapore, South Korea, and Vietnam.
A related concept in political science is the developmental state.
Social market economy
Main article: Social market economyThe social market economy was implemented by Alfred Müller-Armack and Ludwig Erhard after World War II in West Germany. The social market economic model, sometimes called Rhine capitalism, is based upon the idea of realizing the benefits of a free-market economy, especially economic performance and high supply of goods while avoiding disadvantages such as market failure, destructive competition, concentration of economic power and the socially harmful effects of market processes. The aim of the social market economy is to realize greatest prosperity combined with best possible social security. One difference from the free market economy is that the state is not passive, but instead takes active regulatory measures. The social policy objectives include employment, housing and education policies, as well as a socio-politically motivated balancing of the distribution of income growth. Characteristics of social market economies are a strong competition policy and a contractionary monetary policy. The philosophical background is neoliberalism or ordoliberalism.
Socialism
Main article: Market socialismMarket socialism is a form of market economy where the means of production are socially owned. In a market socialist economy, firms operate according to the rules of supply and demand and operate to maximize profit; the principal difference between market socialism and capitalism being that the profits accrue either directly to the workers of the company or society as a whole as opposed to private owners.
The distinguishing feature between non-market socialism and market socialism is the existence of a market for factors of production and the criteria of profitability for enterprises. Profits derived from publicly owned enterprises can variously be used to reinvest in further production, to directly finance government and social services, or be distributed to the public at large through a social dividend or basic income system.
Advocates of market socialism such as Jaroslav Vaněk argue that genuinely free markets are not possible under conditions of private ownership of productive property. Instead, he contends that the class differences and inequalities in income and power that result from private ownership enable the interests of the dominant class to skew the market to their favor, either in the form of monopoly and market power, or by utilizing their wealth and resources to legislate government policies that benefit their specific business interests. Additionally, Vaněk states that workers in a socialist economy based on cooperative and self-managed enterprises have stronger incentives to maximize productivity because they would receive a share of the profits (based on the overall performance of their enterprise) in addition to receiving their fixed wage or salary. The stronger incentives to maximize productivity that he conceives as possible in a socialist economy based on cooperative and self-managed enterprises might be accomplished in a free-market economy if cooperatives were the norm as envisioned by various thinkers including Louis O. Kelso and James S. Albus.
Models of market socialism
Market socialism traces its roots to classical economics and the works of Adam Smith, the Ricardian socialists and mutualist philosophers.
In the 1930s, the economists Oskar Lange and Abba Lerner developed a model of socialism that posited that a public body (dubbed the Central Planning Board) could set prices through a trial-and-error approach until they equaled the marginal cost of production in order to achieve perfect competition and pareto optimality. In this model of socialism, firms would be state-owned and managed by their employees and the profits would be disbursed among the population in a social dividend. This model came to be referred to as market socialism because it involved the use of money, a price system and simulated capital markets, all of which were absent from traditional non-market socialism.
A more contemporary model of market socialism is that put forth by the American economist John Roemer, referred to as economic democracy. In this model, social ownership is achieved through public ownership of equity in a market economy. A Bureau of Public Ownership would own controlling shares in publicly listed firms, so that the profits generated would be used for public finance and the provision of a basic income.
Some anarchists and libertarian socialists promote a form of market socialism in which enterprises are owned and managed cooperatively by their workforce so that the profits directly remunerate the employee-owners. These cooperative enterprises would compete with each other in the same way private companies compete with each other in a capitalist market. The first major elaboration of this type of market socialism was made by Pierre-Joseph Proudhon and was called mutualism.
Self-managed market socialism was promoted in Yugoslavia by economists Branko Horvat and Jaroslav Vaněk. In the self-managed model of socialism, firms would be directly owned by their employees and the management board would be elected by employees. These cooperative firms would compete with each other in a market for both capital goods and for selling consumer goods.
Socialist market economy
Following the 1978 reforms, China developed what it calls a socialist market economy in which most of the economy is under state ownership, with the state enterprises organized as joint-stock companies with various government agencies owning controlling shares through a shareholder system. Prices are set by a largely free-price system and the state-owned enterprises are not subjected to micromanagement by a government planning agency. A similar system called socialist-oriented market economy has emerged in Vietnam following the Đổi Mới reforms in 1986. This system is frequently characterized as state capitalism instead of market socialism because there is no meaningful degree of employee self-management in firms, because the state enterprises retain their profits instead of distributing them to the workforce or government and because many function as de facto private enterprises. The profits neither finance a social dividend to benefit the population at large, nor do they accrue to their employees. In China, this economic model is presented as a preliminary stage of socialism to explain the dominance of capitalistic management practices and forms of enterprise organization in both the state and non-state sectors.
In religion
A wide range of philosophers and theologians have linked market economies to concepts from monotheistic religions. Michael Novak described capitalism as being closely related to Catholicism, but Max Weber drew a connection between capitalism and Protestantism. The economist Jeffrey Sachs has stated that his work was inspired by the healing characteristics of Judaism. Chief Rabbi Lord Sacks of the United Synagogue draws a correlation between modern capitalism and the Jewish image of the Golden Calf.
Christianity
In the Christian faith, the liberation theology movement advocated involving the church in labor market capitalism. Many priests and nuns integrated themselves into labor organizations while others moved into the slums to live among the poor. The Holy Trinity was interpreted as a call for social equality and the elimination of poverty. However, the Pope John Paul II was highly active in his criticism of liberation theology. He was particularly concerned about the increased fusion between Christianity and Marxism. He closed Catholic institutions that taught liberation theology and dismissed some of its activists from the church.
Buddhism
The Buddhist approach to the market economy was dealt with in E. F. Schumacher's 1966 essay "Buddhist Economics". Schumacher asserted that a market economy guided by Buddhist principles would more successfully meet the needs of its people. He emphasized the importance or pursuing occupations that adhered to Buddhist teachings. The essay would later become required reading for a course that Clair Brown offered at University of California, Berkeley.
Criticism
The economist Joseph Stiglitz argues that markets suffer from informational inefficiency and the presumed efficiency of markets stems from the faulty assumptions of neoclassical welfare economics, particularly the assumption of perfect and costless information and related incentive problems. Neoclassical economics assumes static equilibrium and efficient markets require that there be no non-convexities, even though nonconvexities are pervasive in modern economies. Stiglitz's critique applies to both existing models of capitalism and to hypothetical models of market socialism. However, Stiglitz does not advocate replacing markets, but instead states that there is a significant role for government intervention to boost the efficiency of markets and to address the pervasive market failures that exist in contemporary economies. A fair market economy is in fact a martingale or a Brownian motion model and for a participant competitor in such a model there is no more than 50% of success chances at any given moment. Due to the fractal nature of any fair market and being market participants subject to the law of competition which impose reinvesting an increasing part of profits, the mean statistical chance of bankruptcy within the half life of any participant is also 50% and 100% whether an infinite sample of time is considered.
Robin Hahnel and Michael Albert claim that "markets inherently produce class division". Albert states that even if everyone started out with a balanced job complex (doing a mix of roles of varying creativity, responsibility and empowerment) in a market economy, class divisions would arise, arguing:
Without taking the argument that far, it is evident that in a market system with uneven distribution of empowering work, such as Economic Democracy, some workers will be more able than others to capture the benefits of economic gain. For example, if one worker designs cars and another builds them, the designer will use his cognitive skills more frequently than the builder. In the long term, the designer will become more adept at conceptual work than the builder, giving the former greater bargaining power in a firm over the distribution of income. A conceptual worker who is not satisfied with his income can threaten to work for a company that will pay him more. The effect is a class division between conceptual and manual laborers, and ultimately managers and workers, and a de facto labor market for conceptual workers.
David McNally argues in the Marxist tradition that the logic of the market inherently produces inequitable outcomes and leads to unequal exchanges, arguing that Adam Smith's moral intent and moral philosophy espousing equal exchange was undermined by the practice of the free markets he championed. The development of the market economy involved coercion, exploitation and violence that Smith's moral philosophy could not countenance. McNally also criticizes market socialists for believing in the possibility of fair markets based on equal exchanges to be achieved by purging parasitical elements from the market economy such as private ownership of the means of production. McNally argues that market socialism is an oxymoron when socialism is defined as an end to wage-based labor.
The role of supply and demand in a market economy
Supply and demand play an instrumental role in driving market economies by setting both prices and quantities traded in markets. Supply is defined as any increase in price leading to an increase in supply from producers; demand on the other hand means any drop leads to an increase in desired quantities from consumers; these two laws meet at equilibrium when provided quantity equals quantity demanded - known as equilibrium price/quantity equilibrium point. Prices play an extremely vital role in market economies by providing important information about commodity and service availability. When there is strong demand but limited supply, prices increase, signaling to producers that there may be opportunities to increase profits by producing more of that product. Conversely, when there is low demand with increased supply then prices reduce, showing manufacturers they must either reduce output or find methods of cutting costs in order to stay competitive and remain profitable.
External factors, including shifting technological standards, new government laws, and natural catastrophes can have a substantial impact on supply and demand. Technological innovations may increase supply, while laws issued by governments could decrease it or even demand. Natural disasters have the ability to severely disrupt supply chains, creating shortages of key items that increase costs while simultaneously decreasing demand. Supply and demand play an indispensable role in any market economy by ensuring prices reflect market forces accurately, adapting accordingly as conditions shift between supply and demand situations, while producers adjust production according to price signals from consumers, fulfilling customers' requests while giving individuals freedom in making purchasing choices based on personal preferences or financial constraints. Thus supply and demand play an instrumental part in shaping and stabilizing economies governed by market forces.
Sustainable market economy
A sustainable market economy seeks to balance economic expansion and environmental preservation. It acknowledges that sustainable environmental protection and resource management are essential for long-term economic growth. To achieve this balance, implementing sustainable practices across sectors, such as lowering carbon emissions, developing renewable energy sources, and putting circular economy ideas into practice. Tax incentives, carbon trading programs, and environmental requirements are just a few ways government rules and policies encourage enterprises to adopt sustainable practices.
At the same time, consumer demand for eco-friendly goods and services and understanding of these issues may influence market dynamics to favour more sustainable options. A sustainable market economy may encourage innovation, provide green employment, and guarantee the welfare of future generations by incorporating environmental factors into economic decision-making. Prioritizing sustainability while preserving economic development needs cooperation between governments, corporations, and people.
See also
- Crony capitalism
- Corporatism
- Co-determination
- Economic freedom
- Gift economy
- Grey market
- Keynesian economics
- Market failure
- Market structure
- Monopoly
- Neoclassical economics
- Planned economy
- Regulated market
References
- Gregory and Stuart, Paul & Robert (2004). Comparing Economic Systems in the Twenty-First Century (7th ed.). George Hoffman. p. 538. ISBN 0618261818.
Market Economy: Economy in which fundamentals of supply and demand provide signals regarding resource utilization.
- Altvater, E. (1993). The Future of the Market: An Essay on the Regulation of Money and Nature After the Collapse of "Actually Existing Socialism. Verso. p. 57.
- Yu-Shan Wu (1995). Comparative Economic Transformations: Mainland China, Hungary, the Soviet Union, and Taiwan. Stanford University Press. p. 8.
In laissez-faire capitalism, the state restricts itself to providing public goods and services that the economy cannot generate by itself and to safeguarding private ownership and the smooth operation of the self-regulating market.
- Altvater, E. (1993). The Future of the Market: An Essay on the Regulation of Money and Nature After the Collapse of "Actually Existing Socialism. Verso. pp. 237–238.
- Tucker, Irvin B. p 491. Macroeconomics for Today. West Publishing. p. 491
- Paul M. Johnson (2005). "A Glossary of Political Economy Terms, Market economy". Auburn University. Archived from the original on 27 December 2012. Retrieved 28 December 2012.
- Bock man, Johanna (2011). Markets in the name of Socialism: The Left-Wing origins of Neoliberalism. Stanford University Press. ISBN 978-0804775663.
- ^ "Supply and Demand: Why Markets Tick". IMF. Retrieved 2024-09-22.
- Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia
- "It introduces an eye-opening approach to radical social thought, rooted equally in libertarian socialism and market anarchism." Chartier, Gary; Johnson, Charles W. (2011). Markets Not Capitalism: Individualist Anarchism Against Bosses, Inequality, Corporate Power, and Structural Poverty. Brooklyn, NY: Minor Compositions/Autonomedia. p. back cover.
- "But there has always been a market-oriented strand of libertarian socialism that emphasizes voluntary cooperation between producers. And markets, properly understood, have always been about cooperation. As a commenter at Reason magazine's Hit&Run blog, remarking on Jesse Walker's link to the Kelly article, put it: "every trade is a cooperative act." In fact, it's a fairly common observation among market anarchists that genuinely free markets have the most legitimate claim to the label "socialism." "Socialism: A Perfectly Good Word Rehabilitated" Archived 2016-03-10 at the Wayback Machine by Kevin Carson at website of Center for a Stateless Society.
- Nick Manley, "Brief Introduction To Left-Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part One" Archived 2021-08-18 at the Wayback Machine.
- Nick Manley, "Brief Introduction To Left-Wing Laissez Faire Economic Theory: Part Two" Archived 2021-05-16 at the Wayback Machine.
- "The surprising ingredients of Swedish success – free markets and social cohesion" (PDF). Institute of Economic Affairs. June 25, 2013. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2012-10-22. Retrieved January 15, 2014.
- Anglo-Saxon capitalism, Business Dictionary on BusinessDictionary.com: http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/Anglo-Saxon-capitalism.html Archived 2020-09-27 at the Wayback Machine
- keyword "social market economy" = “Soziale Marktwirtschaft” Archived 2011-12-12 at the Wayback Machine Duden Wirtschaft von A bis Z. Grundlagenwissen für Schule und Studium, Beruf und Alltag. 2. Aufl. Mannheim: Bibliographisches Institut & F.A. Brockhaus 2004. Lizenzausgabe Bonn: Bundeszentrale für politische Bildung 2004.
- Duden Wirtschaft von A bis Z. "Eintrag: keyword "social market economy" = Soziale Marktwirtschaft" Archived 2012-08-29 at the Wayback Machine.
- Comparing Economic Systems in the Twenty-First Century, 2003, by Gregory and Stuart. ISBN 0618261818. (p. 142): "It is an economic system that combines social ownership of capital with market allocation of capital...The state owns the means of production, and returns accrue to society at large."
- Social Dividend versus Basic Income Guarantee in Market Socialism, by Marangos, John. 2004. International Journal of Political Economy, vol. 34, no. 3, Fall 2004.
- "Cooperative Economics: An Interview with Jaroslav Vanek" Archived 2021-08-17 at the Wayback Machine. Interview by Albert Perkins. Retrieved March 17, 2011.
- McNally, David (1993). Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the Marxist Critique. Verso. p. 44. ISBN 978-0860916062.
...by the 1820s, 'Smithian' apologists for industrial capitalism confronted 'Smithian' socialists in a vigorous, and often venomous, debate over political economy.
- Lord Sacks, "Rediscovering Religious Values in the Market Economy" Archived 2017-12-20 at the Wayback Machine, HuffPost, February 11, 2012
- "Liberation theology" Archived 2019-10-29 at the Wayback Machine, BBC, July 18, 2011
- Kathleen Maclay, "Buddhist economics: oxymoron or idea whose time has come?" Archived 2020-04-13 at the Wayback Machine, Berkeley News, March 13, 2014
- Michie, Jonathan (2001). Reader's Guide to the Social Sciences. Routledge. p. 1012. ISBN 978-1579580919.
Stiglitz criticizes the first and second welfare theorems for being based on the assumptions of complete markets (including a full set of futures and risk markets) and perfect and costless information, which are simply not true. Incentives are dubious too. Thus, capitalist markets are also not efficient and there is some role for government intervention. The ability to decentralize using the price system requires that there be no nonconvexities, but nonconvexities are pervasive.
- Podobnik, Boris; Horvatic, Davor; Petersen, Alexander M.; Urošević, Branko; Stanley, H. Eugene (2010-10-26). "Bankruptcy risk model and empirical tests". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America. 107 (43): 18325–18330. arXiv:1011.2670. Bibcode:2010PNAS..10718325P. doi:10.1073/pnas.1011942107. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 2972955. PMID 20937903.
- ^ Weiss, Adam (2005-05-04). "A Comparison of Economic Democracy and Participatory Economics". ZMag. Archived from the original on 2009-04-02. Retrieved 2008-06-26.
- McNally, David (1993). Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the Marxist Critique. Verso. ISBN 978-0860916062.
- Jadidzadeh, Ali; Serletis, Apostolos (2017-03-01). "How does the U.S. natural gas market react to demand and supply shocks in the crude oil market?". Energy Economics. 63: 66–74. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2017.01.007. ISSN 0140-9883. S2CID 157939150. Archived from the original on 2020-06-23. Retrieved 2023-04-21.
- Kiseleva, Irina Anatolievna (2021-07-10). "Simulations of Supply and Demand Forecasting in A Market Economy". Revista Gestão Inovação e Tecnologias. 11 (4): 1669–1684. doi:10.47059/revistageintec.v11i4.2218. S2CID 236467969. Archived from the original on 2022-01-27. Retrieved 2023-04-21.
- Tomassetti, Paolo (2018–2019). "Labor Law and Environmental Sustainability". Comparative Labor Law & Policy Journal. 40: 61.
- Zhang, Xiaoyun; Dong, Feng (January 2020). "Why Do Consumers Make Green Purchase Decisions? Insights from a Systematic Review". International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 17 (18): 6607. doi:10.3390/ijerph17186607. ISSN 1660-4601. PMC 7559813. PMID 32932797.
Further reading
- Åslund, Anders. “The Rise of State Capitalism.” Russia's Crony Capitalism: The Path from Market Economy to Kleptocracy, Yale University Press, 2019, pp. 97–131, doi:10.2307/j.ctvgc61tr.8.
- Beckert, J. and Aspers, P. (2011). The Worth of Goods: Valuation and Pricing in the Economy. Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780191618680.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - Boudreaux, Donald J. (2008). "Free-Market Economy". In Hamowy, Ronald (ed.). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage; Cato Institute. pp. 187–189. doi:10.4135/9781412965811.n114. ISBN 978-1412965804. LCCN 2008009151. OCLC 750831024. Archived from the original on 2023-01-09. Retrieved 2022-03-31.
- Boushey, Heather. “Market Structure.” Unbound: How Inequality Constricts Our Economy and What We Can Do about It, Harvard University Press, 2019, pp. 114–138, JSTOR j.ctv24trb7p.11.
- Chari, Anusha. “The International Market for Corporate Control.” Global Goliaths: Multinational Corporations in the 21st Century Economy, edited by C. FRITZ FOLEY et al., Brookings Institution Press, 2021, pp. 129–182, JSTOR 10.7864/j.ctv11hpt7b.7.
- Cochoy, Franck. “Another Discipline for the Market Economy: Marketing as a Performative Knowledge and Know-How for Capitalism.” The Sociological Review 46, no. 1_suppl (May 1998): 194–221. doi:10.1111/j.1467-954X.1998.tb03475.x
- Cordier, S., Pareschi, L. & Toscani, G. On a Kinetic Model for a Simple Market Economy. Journal of Statistical Physics 120, 253–277 (2005). doi:10.1007/s10955-005-5456-0
- Corneo, Giacoma and Daniel Steuer. “Market Economy Plus Welfare State.” Is Capitalism Obsolete?: A Journey through Alternative Economic Systems, Harvard University Press, 2017, pp. 225–248, JSTOR j.ctv24w62sr.14.
- Cowen, T. (2009). In Praise of Commercial Culture. Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0674029934.
- Cox, H. (2016). The Market as God. Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0674973152.
- Cronin, James E. “Market Rules and the International Economy.” Global Rules: America, Britain and a Disordered World, Yale University Press, 2014, pp. 121–147, JSTOR j.ctt1bhkp54.8.
- Cyndecka, Małgorzata Agnieszka. “The Applicability and Application of the Market Economy Investor Principle: Lessons Learnt from the Financial Crisis.” European State Aid Law Quarterly, vol. 16, no. 4, Lexxion Verlagsgesellschaft mbH, 2017, pp. 512–526, JSTOR stable/26694186.
- Doti, J. and Lee, D. (1991). The Market Economy: A Reader. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0195332582.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
- Ebner, Alexander. “Continuity and Change in Germany's Social Market Economy: A Matter of Economic Style?” Contesting Deregulation: Debates, Practices and Developments in the West since the 1970s, edited by Knud Andresen and Stefan Müller, 1st ed., vol. 31, Berghahn Books, 2017, pp. 41–56, doi:10.2307/j.ctvw04gps.7.
- Finn, Daniel k. “What Can Be Done about Market Injustice?” Consumer Ethics in a Global Economy: How Buying Here Causes Injustice There, Georgetown University Press, 2019, pp. 143–153, doi:10.2307/j.ctvswx7rz.14.
- Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001). Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0191647703.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - Hirschfeld, Mary L. “Toward a Humane Economy: A Pragmatic Approach.” Aquinas and the Market: Toward a Humane Economy, Harvard University Press, 2018, pp. 191–218, JSTOR j.ctvsf1p3x.10.
- Isachsen, A.J. and Gylfason, T. and Hamilton, C. and Hamilton, P.E.I.I.E.S.C.B. and Isachsen, P.I.E.A.J. (1992). Understanding the Market Economy. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0198773573. LCCN lc92024790.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - Johansson, P.O. (1991). An Introduction to Modern Welfare Economics. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521356954. LCCN 90020420.
- Kamien, M.I. and Schwartz, N.L. and Pencavel, J. (1982). Market Structure and Innovation. Cambridge Surveys of Economic Literature. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521293853. LCCN 81012254.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
- Kratz, Agatha, et al. Time's Up: China's Coming Battle for Market Economy Status. European Council on Foreign Relations, 2016, JSTOR resrep21581.
- Kunde, Meg. “Making the Free Market Moral: Ronald Reagan's Covenantal Economy.” Rhetoric and Public Affairs, vol. 22, no. 2, Michigan State University Press, 2019, pp. 217–252, doi:10.14321/rhetpublaffa.22.2.0217.
- Lavigne, M. (1999). The Economics of Transition: From Socialist Economy to Market Economy. Macmillan Education. ISBN 978-1349273133.
- Lazonick, W. (1993). Business Organization and the Myth of the Market Economy. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521447881. LCCN 91008865.
- Leshem, Dotan. “From Ecclesiastical to Market Economy.” The Origins of Neoliberalism: Modeling the Economy from Jesus to Foucault, Columbia University Press, 2016, pp. 153–182, JSTOR 10.7312/lesh17776.11.
- Lothian, Tamara. “The Democratized Market Economy in Latin America (and Elsewhere): An Exercise in Institutional Thinking Within Law and Political Economy.” Law and the Wealth of Nations: Finance, Prosperity, and Democracy, Columbia University Press, 2017, pp. 138–196, JSTOR 10.7312/loth17466.8.
- Lothian, Tamara. “The Democratized Market Economy.” Law and the Wealth of Nations: Finance, Prosperity, and Democracy, Columbia University Press, 2017, pp. 113–137, JSTOR 10.7312/loth17466.7.
- Malinvaud, E. and United Nations (2000). Development Strategy and Management of the Market Economy. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0199241347.
- Malloy, R.P. (2000). Law and Market Economy: Reinterpreting the Values of Law and Economics. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521787314. LCCN 00711747.
- McKinnie, M. (2021). Theatre in Market Economies. Theatre and Performance Theory. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-1107000391. LCCN 2020039520.
- McKinnon, R.I. (1993) . The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to a Market Economy. The Johns Hopkins Studies in Development. Johns Hopkins University Press. doi:10.1257/jep.5.4.107. ISBN 978-0801847431. LCCN 93021886.
- Mirowski, P. and Plehwe, D. (2015). The Road from Mont Pèlerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective, With a New Preface. Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0674088344. LCCN 2016303988.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - Mittermaier, Karl and Isabella Mittermaier. “Free-Market Dogmatism and Pragmatism.” In The Hand Behind the Invisible Hand: Dogmatic and Pragmatic Views on Free Markets and the State of Economic Theory, 1st ed., 23–26. Bristol University Press, 2020. doi:10.2307/j.ctv186grks.10
- Murphy, Kevin M, Andrei Shleifer, Robert W. Vishny, The Transition to a Market Economy: Pitfalls of Partial Reform, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Volume 107, Issue 3, August 1992, pp. 889–906, doi:10.2307/2118367
- Nee, Victor. “The Role of the State in Making a Market Economy.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE) / Zeitschrift Für Die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft, vol. 156, no. 1, Mohr Siebeck GmbH & Co. KG, 2000, pp. 64–88, JSTOR 40752185
- Nee, V. and Opper, S. (2012). Capitalism from Below: Markets and Institutional Change in China. Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0674065390. LCCN 2011042367.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
- Nelson, Richard B. (2004). "The market economy, and the scientific commons". Research Policy. 33 (3): 455–471. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2003.09.008. hdl:10419/89454. ISSN 0048-7333.
- Ngo, Tak-Wing. “Asia and the Historicity of the Market Economy.” Verge: Studies in Global Asias, vol. 1, no. 1, University of Minnesota Press, 2015, pp. 44–50, doi:10.5749/vergstudglobasia.1.1.0044.
- Pomeranz, Kenneth. “Market Economies in Europe and Asia.” The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy, NED-New edition, vol. 117, Princeton University Press, 2021, pp. 69–108, doi:10.2307/j.ctv161f3dr.7.
- Ramanna, K. (2015). Political Standards: Corporate Interest, Ideology, and Leadership in the Shaping of Accounting Rules for the Market Economy. University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0226210742. LCCN 2015011503.
- Robin, Ron. “Castrophobia and the Free Market: The Wohlstetters’ Moral Economy.” The Cold World They Made: The Strategic Legacy of Roberta and Albert Wohlstetter, Harvard University Press, 2016, pp. 118–138, JSTOR j.ctv253f7gh.8.
- Rodgers, Daniel T. “Moralizing the Market Economy.” As a City on a Hill: The Story of America's Most Famous Lay Sermon, Princeton University Press, 2018, pp. 96–106, doi:10.2307/j.ctvc778b0.10.
- Root, H.L. (2020). Networking History: East vs. West in a Complex Systems Perspective. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-1108488990. LCCN 2019033289.
- Rosser, J.B.; Rosser, M.V. (2004). Comparative Economics in a Transforming World Economy. The MIT Press. MIT Press. ISBN 978-0262182348. LCCN 2003059363. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
- Schebesta, Martin. Climate Change, Digitisation and Globalisation — Does the Social Market Economy Need Renewal? Konrad Adenauer Stiftung, 2020, JSTOR resrep25282.
- Sedgwick, P.H. (1999). The Market Economy and Christian Ethics. New studies in Christian ethics. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-1107112483. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
- Shapiro, C. and Varian, H.R. (1998). Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy. Harvard Business Review Press. ISBN 978-1422154625. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - Skidelsky, R. (2018). Money and Government: The Past and Future of Economics. Yale University Press. ISBN 978-0300244243. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
- Stiglitz, J.E. (1996). Whither Socialism?. Wicksell Lectures. MIT Press. ISBN 978-0262691826. LCCN lc93043188. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
- Sumner, S. (2021). The Money Illusion: Market Monetarism, the Great Recession, and the Future of Monetary Policy. University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0226773681. LCCN 2020056573. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
- Sundararajan, Arun. “The Sharing Economy, Market Economies, and Gift Economies.” The Sharing Economy: The End of Employment and the Rise of Crowd-Based Capitalism, The MIT Press, 2016, pp. 23–46, JSTOR j.ctt1c2cqh3.5.
- Tanzi, V. (2011). Government versus Markets: The Changing Economic Role of the State. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-1139499736.
- Temin, Peter. “The Labor Market.” The Roman Market Economy, Princeton University Press, 2013, pp. 114–138, JSTOR j.ctt1r2g35.11.
- Tomlinson, Jim. “The Failures of Neoliberalism in Britain since the 1970s: The Limits on ‘Market Forces’ in a Deindustrialising Economy and a ‘New Speenhamland.’” The Neoliberal Age?: Britain since the 1970s, edited by Aled Davies et al., UCL Press, 2021, pp. 94–111, JSTOR j.ctv1smjwgq.12.
- Ulrich, P. and Fearns, J. (2010). Integrative Economic Ethics: Foundations of a Civilized Market Economy. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521172424. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - von Stackelberg, H. and Von, S.H. and Peacock, A.T. (1952). The Theory of the Market Economy. Oxford University Press. LCCN 52004949. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - Weiss, Hadas. “Capital's Fidelity: Financialization in the German Social Market Economy.” Financialization: Relational Approaches, edited by Chris Hann and Don Kalb, 1st ed., vol. 6, Berghahn Books, 2020, pp. 177–195, doi:10.2307/j.ctv21hrft2.12.
- Widerquist, Karl and Grant S. McCall. “The Negative Freedom Argument for the Market Economy.” The Prehistory of Private Property: Implications for Modern Political Theory, Edinburgh University Press, 2021, pp. 79–99, JSTOR 10.3366/j.ctv1hm8h0j.9.
- Wolf, M. (2005). Why Globalization Works. Yale University Press. ISBN 978-0300251739. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
- Yeazell, S.C. (2018). Lawsuits in a Market Economy: The Evolution of Civil Litigation. University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0226546421. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
- Zakim, M. (2018). Accounting for Capitalism: The World the Clerk Made. University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0226545899. LCCN 2017035753. Archived from the original on 2024-02-08. Retrieved 2022-03-11.
External links
- Media related to Market economy at Wikimedia Commons
- Market Systems at Encyclopædia Britannica Online.