Revision as of 21:37, 25 March 2006 editHerschelkrustofsky (talk | contribs)2,877 edits I've fleshed this out a bit for the benefit of the skeptics← Previous edit | Latest revision as of 11:20, 13 December 2024 edit undoWire723 (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users50,748 edits →20th century onwards: Add Girobank to the UK listTag: Visual edit | ||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{short description|Transferring something from the public sphere to the private}} | |||
'''Privatization''' (sometimes '''privatisation''', '''denationalization''', or, especially in ], '''disinvestment''') is the process of transferring ], from ] to ] and/or transferring the management of a service or activity from the government to the private sector. The reverse process is ] or ]. | |||
{{see also| List of privatizations by country }} | |||
{{neoliberalism sidebar|expanded=ideas}} | |||
==Overview== | |||
{{Capitalism sidebar|concepts}} | |||
Privatization is frequently associated with industrial or ] enterprises, such as mining, manufacturing or power generation, but it can also apply to any ], such as ], ], or even rights to ]. In recent years, government services such as ], ], and ] have been particularly targeted for privatization in many countries. | |||
'''Privatization''' (rendered '''privatisation''' in ]) can mean several different things, most commonly referring to moving something from the public sector into the private sector. It is also sometimes used as a synonym for ] when a heavily regulated private company or industry becomes less regulated. Government functions and services may also be privatised (which may also be known as "franchising" or "out-sourcing"); in this case, private entities are tasked with the implementation of government programs or performance of government services that had previously been the purview of state-run agencies. Some examples include revenue collection, ], ], and ].<ref>Chowdhury, F. L. ‘’Corrupt Bureaucracy and Privatisation of Tax Enforcement’’, 2006: Pathak Samabesh, Dhaka.</ref> | |||
Proponents say that privatization helps establish a "]", as well as fostering ] ], which its supporters argue will give the public greater choice at a competitive price. Conversely, free-market detractors view privatization negatively, arguing that entrusting private businesses with control of essential services reduces the public's control over them and leads to excessive cost cutting in order to achieve profit and a resulting poor quality service. Additionally, opponents of privatization often raise concerns about the process of awarding contracts. In some cases, the government will not put a contract up for bids but simply award it to a company of their choosing. Critics point to the potential for campaign financing to be influenced by the awarding of contracts. | |||
Another definition is that privatization is the sale of a ] or ] to private investors; in this case shares may be traded in the public market for the first time, or for the first time since an enterprise's previous ]. This type of privatization can include the ] of a ], ], or ] in order to form a ].<ref name="crisis">{{Cite news |url=http://www.thenews.coop/35044/topic/democracy/musselburgh-co-op-crisis-privatisation-bid-fails/ |title=Musselburgh Co-op in crisis as privatization bid fails. |publisher=] |date=2005-11-01 |access-date=2008-05-21 |archive-date=2017-12-22 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171222053251/https://www.thenews.coop/35044/topic/democracy/musselburgh-co-op-crisis-privatisation-bid-fails/ |url-status=dead }}</ref> | |||
In general, privatization was common during the immediate post-] period, but privatization became a more dominant economic trend (especially within the ] and the ]) during the ] and ]. This trend of privatization has often been characterized as part of a "global wave" of ] policies, and some observers argue that this was greatly influenced by the policies of ] and ]. The term "privatization" was ] in ] and is thought to have been popularized by '']'' during the 1980s. | |||
Separately, privatization can refer to the purchase of all ] of a ] company by ] investors, which is more often called '''"going private"'''. Before and after this process the company is privately owned, but after the buyout its shares are withdrawn from being traded at a public ].<ref name=":0">{{cite web|last=Fernando|first=Jason|title=Going Private Definition|url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/g/going-private.asp|access-date=2021-08-05|website=Investopedia|language=en}}</ref><ref name=":1">{{cite web|last=Dumont|first=Marvin|title=Why Do Public Companies Go Private?|url=https://www.investopedia.com/articles/stocks/08/public-companies-privatize-go-private.asp|access-date=2021-08-05|website=Investopedia|language=en}}</ref> | |||
===Types of privatization=== | |||
In terms of outright privatization (that is, sale of a business), there are three major types: | |||
== Etymology == | |||
* ] issue privatization (SIP) - selling shares on the ] | |||
The term ''privatizing'' first appeared in English, with quotation marks, in the '']'', in April 1923, in a translation of a German speech referring to the potential for German state railroads to be bought by American companies.<ref>{{Cite news |orig-date=7 April 1923 |title=Asserts Americans 'Plot' With French |pages=4 |work=The New York Times |date=7 April 1923 |url=https://www.nytimes.com/1923/04/07/archives/asserts-americans-plot-with-french-german-engineer-calls-ruhr.html}}</ref> In German, the word '']'' has been used since at least the 19th century.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Kämmerer |first=Jörn Axel |title=Privatisierung |publisher=Mohr Siebeck |year=2001 |isbn=978-3-16-147515-3 |location=Tübingen |language=de}}</ref> Ultimately, the word came to German through French from the Latin {{lang|la|privatus}}.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Privatisieren |url=https://www.duden.de/rechtschreibung/privatisieren |website=Duden}}</ref> | |||
* asset sale privatization - selling the entire firm to an investor, usually by ] | |||
* ] - shares of ownership are distributed to all citizens, usually for free or at a very low price. | |||
The term ''reprivatization'', again translated directly from German ({{lang|de|Reprivatisierung}}), was used frequently in the mid-1930s as '']'' reported on Nazi Germany's sale of nationalized banks back to public shareholders following the 1931 economic crisis.<ref name=":3">{{Cite journal |last=Bel |first=Germa |date=Summer 2006 |title=The Coining of "Privatization" and Germany's National Socialist Party |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives |volume=20 |issue=3 |pages=187–194|doi=10.1257/jep.20.3.187 |s2cid=33815402 |doi-access=free }}</ref> | |||
Share issue privatization is the most common type. Voucher privatization has mainly been used in the ] of Central and Eastern Europe - countries such as ], ] and ]. Share issue can broaden and deepen domestic capital markets, boosting ] and potentially ], but if the capital markets are insufficiently developed it may be difficult to find enough buyers, and transaction costs (eg underpricing required) may be higher. Risks (political risk, currency risk) are also higher, deterring foreign portfolio investors. As a result, asset sales are more common in ]. | |||
The word became common in the late 1970s and early 1980s as part of UK prime minister ]. She was drawing on the work of the pro-privatization Member of Parliament ], who was himself drawing on the Austrian-American management expert ]'s 1969 book, ''The Age of Discontinuity''.<ref name=":3" /> | |||
==Arguments for and against == | |||
''See also: arguments for and against ] and the ]'' | |||
== |
== Definition == | ||
The word ''privatization'' may mean different things depending on the context in which it is used. It can mean moving something from the public sphere into the private sphere, but it may also be used to describe something that was always private, but heavily regulated, which becomes less regulated through a process of ]. The term may also be used descriptively for something that has always been private, but could be public in other jurisdictions.<ref>{{Cite journal| volume = 28| issue = 5| page = 1507| last = Beerman| first = Jack| title = Privatization and Political Accountability| journal = Fordham Urban Law Journal| url=https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/ulj/vol28/iss5/2/ |date = 2001-01-01}}</ref> | |||
Advocates of privatization argue that governments run businesses inefficiently for the following reasons: | |||
There are also private entities that may perform public functions. These entities could also be described as privatized. Privatization may mean the government sells state-owned businesses to private interests, but it may also be discussed in the context of the privatization of services or government functions, where private entities are tasked with the implementation of government programs or the performance of government services. ] has written that: "Private entities provide a vast array of social services for the government; administer core aspects of government programs; and perform tasks that appear quintessentially governmental, such as promulgating standards or regulating third-party activities." Metzger mentions an expansion of privatization that includes health and welfare programs, public education, and prisons.<ref name=metzger>{{Cite journal| pages = 1367–1502| last = Metzger| first = Gillian| title = Privatization as Delegation| journal = Colum. L. Rev.| url=https://scholarship.law.columbia.edu/faculty_scholarship/144/ |date = 2003-01-01| volume = 103| issue = 6| doi = 10.2307/3593390| jstor = 3593390}}</ref> | |||
* '''Performance'''. The government may only be interested in improving a company in cases when the performance of the company becomes politically sensitive. | |||
* '''Improvements'''. Conversely, the government may put off improvements due to political sensitivity — even in cases of companies that are run well. | |||
* '''Corruption'''. The company may become prone to ]; company employees may be selected for political reasons rather than business ones. | |||
* '''Goals'''. The government may seek to run a company for social goals rather than business ones (this is conversely seen as a positive effect by critics of privatization). | |||
* '''Capital'''. It is claimed by supporters of privatization, that privately-held companies can more easily raise capital in the financial markets than publicly-owned ones. | |||
* '''Unprofitable companies survive'''. Governments may "bail out" poorly run businesses with money when, economically, it may be better to let the business fold. | |||
* '''Political influence'''. Nationalized industries can be prone to interference from ] for ] or ] reasons. Examples include making an industry buy supplies from local producers (when that may be more expensive than buying from abroad), forcing an industry to freeze its prices/fares to satisfy the electorate or control ], increasing its staffing to reduce ], or moving its operations to ]. It is argued that such measures can cause nationalized industries to become uneconomic and uncompetitive. | |||
* '''Profiteering'''. Private companies make a profit by persuading ]s to buy their products and not the products of their competitors. Proponents of privatization argue that private corporations thus need to serve exactly the needs of their clients; and the more their clients are willing to pay, the better they serve the needs. Proponents also suggest that this means the corporations need to focus on even more marginal groups (who might not get their voice heard through the democratic system, yet still can pay for services). | |||
== History == | |||
In particular, the ''Performance'', ''Goals'', and ''Unprofitable companies survive'' reasons are held to be the most important because money is a ] resource: if government-run companies are losing money, or if they are not as profitable as possible, this money is unavailable to other, more efficient firms. Thus, the efficient firms will have a harder time finding capital, which makes it difficult for them to raise production and create more employment. | |||
{{see also|List of privatizations}} | |||
=== Pre-20th century === | |||
The basic argument given for privatization is that governments have few ] to ensure that the enterprises they own are well run. On the other hand, private owners, it is said, ''do'' have such an incentive: they will lose money if businesses are poorly run. The theory holds that, not only will the enterprise's clients see benefits, but as the privatized enterprise becomes more efficient, the whole economy will benefit. Ideally, privatization propels the establishment of social, organizational and legal infrastructures and institutions that are essential for an effective ]. | |||
The history of privatization dates from ], when governments contracted out almost everything to the private sector.<ref name="handbook">''International Handbook on Privatization'' by David Parker, David S. Saal</ref> In the ] private individuals and companies performed the majority of services including tax collection (]), army supplies (]), religious sacrifices and construction. However, the ] also created ]—for example, much of the grain was eventually produced on estates owned by the Emperor. David Parker and David S. Saal suggest that the cost of bureaucracy was one of the reasons for the ].<ref name="handbook" /> | |||
Perhaps one of the first ideological movements towards privatization came during ]'s golden age of the ]. ] came into prominence for the first time at a state level, and it advocated the ] principle of ] (無為), literally meaning "do nothing".<ref>{{harvnb|Li|Zheng|2001|p=241}}{{full citation needed|date=March 2024}}</ref> The rulers were counseled by the Taoist clergy that a strong ruler was virtually invisible. | |||
Another argument for privatization is that to privatize a company which was non-profitable (or even generated severe losses) when state-owned means taking the burden of financing it off the shoulders and pockets of ], as well as freeing some national budget resources which may be subsequently used for something else. Especially, proponents of the ] will argue, that it is both unethical and inefficient for the state to force taxpayers to fund the business that can't work for itself. Also, they hold that even if the privatized company happens to be worse off, it is due to the normal market process of penalizing businesses that fail to cope with the market reality or that simply are not preferred by the customers. | |||
During the ], most of Europe was still by and large following the ] economic model. By contrast, the ] in ] began once more to practice privatization, especially with regards to their manufacturing industries. This was a reversal of the earlier ] policies, which had themselves overturned earlier policies in favor of more rigorous state control.<ref>Bouye, Thomas M., Manslaughter, markets, and moral economy</ref> | |||
Many privatization plans are organized as ]s where bidders compete to offer the state the highest price, creating monetary income that can be used by the state. | |||
In Britain, the privatization of common lands is referred to as ] (in Scotland as the ] and the ]). Significant privatizations of this nature occurred from 1760 to 1820, preceding the ] in that country. | |||
===Against === | |||
=== 20th century onwards === | |||
Opponents of privatization dispute the claims made by proponents of privatization, especially the ones concerning the alleged lack of incentive for governments to ensure that the enterprises they own are well run, on the basis of the idea that governments must answer to the people. It is argued that a government which runs nationalized enterprises poorly will lose public support and votes, while a government which runs those enterprises well will gain public support and votes. Thus, democratic governments, under this argument, do have an incentive to maximize efficiency in nationalized companies, due to the pressure of future elections. | |||
The first mass privatization of state property occurred in ] between 1933 and 1937: "It is a fact that the government of the National Socialist Party sold off public ownership in several state-owned firms in the middle of the 1930s. The firms belonged to a wide range of sectors: steel, mining, banking, local public utilities, shipyard, ship-lines, railways, etc. In addition to this, delivery of some public services produced by public administrations prior to the 1930s, especially social services and services related to work, was transferred to the private sector, mainly to several organizations within the Nazi Party."<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Bel|first=Germà|date=2010-02-01|title=Against the mainstream: Nazi privatization in 1930s Germany1|journal=The Economic History Review|language=en|volume=63|issue=1|pages=34–55|doi=10.1111/j.1468-0289.2009.00473.x|issn=1468-0289|hdl=2445/11716|s2cid=154486694|url=http://diposit.ub.edu/dspace/bitstream/2445/11716/1/162.pdf|hdl-access=free}}</ref> | |||
] privatized its ] in the 1950s, and the ] government embarked on large-scale privatization, including sale of the ] in ] to small investors in public share offerings in 1961.<ref name="handbook" /> However, it was in the 1980s under ] in the United Kingdom and ] in the United States that privatization gained worldwide momentum. Notable privatizations in the UK included ] (1982), the radioactive-chemicals company ] (1982), ] (1984), ] ferries (1984), ] (gradually privatized between 1979 and 1987), ] (1985 to 1987), ] (1986), ] (1987), ] (formerly ], 1988), ] (1988), ] (1989), and the ] of England and Wales (mostly in 1989). After 1979, ] tenants in the UK were given the ] their homes at a heavily discounted price; one million had purchased their residences by 1986.{{Citation needed|date=December 2024}} | |||
Furthermore, opponents of privatization argue that it is undesirable to let private entrepreneurs own public institutions for the following reasons: | |||
Such efforts culminated in 1993 when ] was privatized under Thatcher's successor, ]. British Rail had been formed by prior ] of private rail companies. The privatization was controversial, and ], as doubling of passenger numbers and investment was balanced by an increase in ].<ref>{{Cite news |url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2013/aug/15/nostalgia-british-rail-trains-better |title=Forget the nostalgia for British Rail – our trains are better than ever|newspaper=]|date=2013-08-15|last1=Birrell|first1=Ian}}</ref> | |||
* '''Profiteering'''. Private companies do not have any goal other than to maximize profit. In a democratic system, each person gets one equal vote; but on the market, people "vote" with their money, so those with more money get more "votes". Critics of privatization therefore argue that a private company will serve the needs of those who are most willing (and able) to pay, as opposed to the needs of the majority. | |||
* '''Corruption'''. Buyers of public property have often, most notably in ], used insider positions to enrich themselves - and civil servants in the selling positions - grossly. | |||
* '''No public accountability'''. The public does not have any control or oversight of private companies. | |||
* '''Cuts in essential services'''. If a government-owned company providing an essential service (such as water supply) to all citizens is privatized, its new owner(s) could stop providing this service to those who are too poor to pay, or to regions where this service is unprofitable. | |||
* '''Inefficiency'''. A centralized enterprise is generally more cost effective than multiple smaller ones. Therefore splitting up a public company into smaller private chunks will reduce efficiency. | |||
* '''Natural monopolies'''. Privatization will not result in true competition if a ] exists. | |||
* '''Concentration of wealth'''. Profits from successful enterprises end up in private pockets instead of being available for the common good. | |||
* '''Insecurity'''. Nationalized industries are usually guaranteed against ] by the state. They can therefore borrow money at a lower ] to reflect the lower risk of loan default to the lender. This does not apply to private industries. | |||
* '''Downsizing'''. In cases where public services or utilities are privatized, this can create a conflict of interest between profit and maintaining a sufficient service. A private company may be tempted to cut back on maintenance or staff training etc, to maximize profits. | |||
* '''Waste of risk capital'''. Public services are per definition low-risk ventures that don't need scarce risk capital (which is more needed elsewhere). | |||
These privatizations received mixed views from the public and the parliament. Even former Conservative prime minister ] was critical of the policy, likening it to "selling the family silver".<ref>{{Cite web |last= |first= |date= |title=Harold Macmillan |url=http://www.number10.gov.uk/history-and-tour/harold-macmillan-2/ |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110805111345/http://www.number10.gov.uk/history-and-tour/harold-macmillan-2/ |archive-date=5 August 2011 |website=Number10.gov.uk |via=Internet Archive}}</ref> There were around 3 million shareholders in Britain when Thatcher ], but the subsequent sale of state-run firms saw the number of shareholders double by 1985. By the time of her resignation in 1990, there were more than 10 million shareholders in Britain.<ref>{{cite news |url=http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/in_pictures/4446012.stm |work=] |title=Thatcher years in graphics |date=2005-11-18}}</ref> | |||
In practical terms, there are many pitfalls to privatization. Privatization has rarely worked out ideally because it is so intertwined with political concerns, especially in post-] economies or in developing nations where corruption is endemic. Even in nations with advanced market economies like ], where privatization has been popular with governments (if not all of the public) since the Thatcher era, problems center on the fact that privatization programs are very politically sensitive, raising many legitimate political debates. Who decides how to set values on state enterprises? Does the state accept cash or government-provided coupons? Should the state allow the workers or managers of the enterprise to gain control over their own workplace? Should the state allow foreigners to buy privatized enterprises? Which levels of government can privatize which assets and in what quantities? | |||
Privatization in Latin America was extensive in the 1980s and 1990s, as a result of a Western liberal economic policy. Companies providing public services such as ], transportation, and ] were rapidly sold off to the private sector. In the 1990s, privatization revenue from 18 Latin American countries totaled 6% of gross domestic product.<ref name="Nellis">"Privatization in Latin America: The rapid rise, recent fall, and continuing puzzle of a contentious economic policy" by John Nellis, Rachel Menezes, Sarah Lucas. Center for Global Development Policy Brief, Jan 2004, p. 1.</ref> Private investment in infrastructure from 1990 and 2001 reached $360.5 billion, $150 billion more than in the next emerging economy.<ref name="Nellis" /> | |||
In the short-term, privatization can potentially cause tremendous social upheaval, as privatizations are often accompanied by large layoffs. If a small firm is privatized in a large economy, the effect may be negligible. If a single large firm or many small firms are privatized at once and upheaval results, particularly if the state mishandles the privatization process, a whole nation's economy may plunge into despair. For example, in the ], many state industries were not profitable under the new system, with the cost of inputs exceeding the cost of outputs. After privatization, sixteen percent of the workforce became unemployed in both ] and Poland. The social consequences of this process have been staggering, impoverishing millions, but to little social benefit in many post-Communist countries. On the other hand, proponents claim that Poland's and East Germany's economies will fare better in the long term, with positive social consequences that one can already see in those countries. In the process, Russia has gone from having one of the world's most equal distributions of wealth in the Soviet era to one of the least today. There has been a dearth of large-scale investment to modernize Soviet industries and businesses still trade with each other by means of barter. | |||
While economists generally give favorable evaluations of the impact of privatization in Latin America,<ref>"The Distributive Impact of Privatization in Latin America: Evidence from Four Countries" by David McKenzie, Dilip Mookherjee, Gonzalo Castañeda and Jaime Saavedra. Brookings Institution Press, 2008, p. 162.</ref> opinion polls and public protests across the countries suggest that a large segment of the public is dissatisfied with or have negative views of privatization in the region.<ref>"Why is Sector Reform So Unpopular in Latin America?" by Mary Shirley. The Ronald Coase Institute Working Papers, 2004, p. 1.</ref> | |||
In speaking about the transformations in the post-communist countries, however, one must take into account the specifics of the communist and socialist regime which ruled those countries for decades. There are no easy answers regarding those issues. Some argue that it was the cumulation of mismanagement and inattention to the market realities that lead to such fatal consequences, given that most of the assets of those companies had not renovated for decades and their technology was outdated. Further, opening of the markets for import of the products which, in many cases, offered higher quality or lower prices, has given the consumers new array of choices to compete with the old national industries. | |||
In the 1990s, the governments in Eastern and Central Europe engaged in extensive privatization of state-owned enterprises in Eastern and Central Europe and Russia, with assistance from the ], the U.S. Agency for International Development, the German ], and other governmental and ]. | |||
Privatization in the absence of a transparent market system may lead to assets being held by an ] of a few very wealthy people at the expense of the general population. This may discredit the process of economic reform in the opinion of the public and outside observers. This has occurred notably in ], ], and ]. | |||
]'s privatization in 1987 involved the largest share offering in financial history at the time.<ref name="megginson205">The Financial Economics of Privatisation By William L. Megginson, pp. 205–206</ref> 15 of the world's 20 largest public share offerings have been privatizations of telecoms.<ref name="megginson205" /> | |||
Moreover, where free-market economics are rapidly imposed, a country may not have the bureaucratic tools necessary to regulate it. This has been a pertinent problem in Russia and in many ]n countries, although some other Central European countries, such as Poland and the Czech Republic, fared better in this respect, partly through the support of the ]. Paradoxically, while Britain has long had a market economy, it also faced this issue after it privatized utilities in the Thatcher era; Britain's utilities regulator was often criticized as being ineffective. | |||
In 1988, the ] policy of ] started allowing privatization of the centrally planned economy. Large privatization of the Soviet economy occurred over the next few years as the country ]. Other ] countries followed suit after the ] introduced non-communist governments. | |||
Most economists argue that if a privatized company is a ], or exists in a market which is prone to serious market failures, ]s may be worse off when the company is in private hands. This seems to have been the case with ] and in New Zealand; in both countries, public disaffection has led to government intervention. In cases where privatization ''has'' been successful, it is because genuine competition has arisen. A good example of this is long-distance telecommunications in Europe, where the former ]s lost their monopolies, competitors entered the market, and prices for international calls fell dramatically. | |||
'''Freedom House's privatization index, 1998 and 2002'''<br> | |||
British Rail is an example of privatization program that has been deemed a failure and largely abandoned. The track-owning company has been effectively repossessed by the British government, and many of the train-running companies are at risk of having their concession removed on the grounds that they fail to provide adequate services. One of them, ], actually had its franchise cut short in June 2003 by the government for what the Strategic Rail Authority called "poor financial management." In this case, one of the causes for the necessary renationalization was the incomplete nature of the privatization, not leaving enough incentive for the firm to make capital investments. | |||
]'s privatization index rated transition countries from 1 (maximum progress) to 7 (no progress). The table below shows the privatization index for various Eastern European countries in 1998 and 2002:<ref>{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=tiUgEAAAQBAJ&pg=PA45 |title=Norman A. Graham, Folke Lindahl, Timur Kocaoglu, Rowman & Littlefield, Mar 19, 2021, ''Making Russia and Turkey Great Again?: Putin and Erdogan in Search of Lost Empires and Autocratic Power'', p. 45 |isbn=9781793610232 |access-date=October 6, 2022 |archive-date=December 4, 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221204101725/https://books.google.ro/books?id=tiUgEAAAQBAJ&pg=PA45 |url-status=live |last1=Graham |first1=Norman A. |last2=Lindahl |first2=Folke |last3=Kocaoglu |first3=Timur |date=19 March 2021 |publisher=Rowman & Littlefield }}</ref> | |||
{| class="wikitable" | |||
However, in other cases, particularly in poor countries, privatized enterprises cannot be renationalized so easily. These governments do not have the political will to do it, and there is strong pressure exerted by international lending agencies to maintain the privatization. Additionally, investors may be scared away by nationalization programs, fearing that any business they start may be taken from them | |||
!Privatization<br>index | |||
!1998 | |||
!2002 | |||
|- | |||
|'''{{flagcountry|Bulgaria}}''' || 4.0 || 3.0 | |||
|- | |||
|'''{{flagcountry|Czech Republic}}''' || 2.0 || 1.75 | |||
|- | |||
|'''{{flagcountry|Hungary}}''' || 1.5 || 1.5 | |||
|- | |||
|'''{{flagcountry|Poland}}''' || 2.25 || 2.25 | |||
|- | |||
|'''{{flagcountry|Romania}}''' || 4.5 || 3.75 | |||
|- | |||
|'''{{flagcountry|Slovakia}}''' || 3.25 || 2.0 | |||
|- | |||
|'''{{flagcountry|Slovenia}}''' || 2.5 || 2.5 | |||
|- | |||
|'''{{flagcountry|Russian Federation}}''' || 3.0 || 3.5 | |||
|} | |||
The largest public shares offering in France involved ]. | |||
Many have argued that the strategy of privatization in Russia differed from those seen in more successful post-communist economies such as ] and Poland. The defects of the process in Russia, combined with ] liberalization and failure to establish institutional infrastructure, have led to incentives for capital flight, contributing to post-communist economic contraction in Russia. | |||
Egypt undertook widespread privatization under ]. Following his overthrow in the ], most of the public began to call for re-nationalization, citing allegations of the privatized firms practicing ] under the old regime.<ref>Amos, Deborah, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180308231701/https://www.npr.org/2011/04/20/135542498/in-egypt-revolution-moves-into-the-factories |date=2018-03-08 }}, '']'', April 20, 2011. Retrieved 2011-04-20.</ref> | |||
Likewise, countries such as ], which embarked upon far-reaching privatization programs, selling off valuable, profitable industries such as energy companies, have seen the rapid impoverishment of their governments. Revenue streams which could previously be directed towards public spending suddenly dried up, resulting in a severe drop in government services. | |||
==Reasons for privatization== | |||
Privatization can also have a ripple effect on local economies. State-owned enterprises are often required by law to patronize national or local suppliers. Privatized companies, in general, do not have that restriction, and hence will shift purchasing elsewhere. It is also possible that local and national economies may be affected by increases in prices resulting from privatization - especially with services fundamental to business, such as postal, public transport and utility services, without which they cannot survive. ] underwent a rigorous privatization program in the mid 1990s, with disastrous impact on the local economy in the short term. | |||
There are various reasons why a government may decide to privatize; commonly due to economic reasons. The economic factors that influence a government's decision to privatize assume this will lower government debt. Studies have shown that governments are more likely to privatise with higher public debt, typically because governments do not have the needed time to wait for a return.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Ramamurti |first1=Ravi |title=Why Are Developing Countries Privatizing? |journal=Journal of International Business Studies |date=1992 |volume=23 |issue=2 |page=229|doi=10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8490266 }}</ref> Another economic factor that influences this area is the resulting efficiency of SOEs once privatised. Commonly, governments aren’t able to provide the required investments required to ensure profitability for various reasons. These factors may lead to a government deciding to privatize.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Radíc |first1=Mislav |title=Privatization: Implications of a Shift from State to Private Ownership |journal=Journal of Management |date=2021 |volume=47 |issue=6|pages=1596–1629 |doi=10.1177/0149206320988356 |url=http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/108992/2/RavasiRadicMunirJoM2021Pre_print.pdf }}</ref> | |||
The Wall Street Journal has reported that the ], historically a supporter of denationalization in developing countries, has also begun to voice concerns over privatization. It no longer believes that privatization should be recommended in all cases. ] winner ] has written a book on the subject called ''Globalization and its Discontents.'' Mexico's President ] has come under criticism for his plans to privatize Mexico's electrical power generating industry. | |||
== Forms of privatization == | |||
Finally, it has been argued that the ] has illustrated that economic reform can take place in the absence of large-scale privatization, though the Chinese government has been tenderly following limited forms of privatisation since the 1990's. | |||
{{more citations needed section|date=June 2016}} | |||
There are several main methods{{citation needed|date=April 2010}} of privatization: | |||
# ]: shares sale on the ]. | |||
# ]: asset divestiture to a strategic investor, usually by ] or through the ] model. | |||
# ]: distribution of vouchers, which represent part ownership of a corporation, to all citizens, usually for free or at a very low price. | |||
# ]: start of new private businesses in formerly socialist countries. | |||
# ]: purchase of public shares by management of the company, sometimes by borrowing from external lenders | |||
# ]: distribution of shares for free or at a very low price to workers or management of the organization. | |||
The choice of sale method is influenced by the ] and the political and firm-specific factors. Privatization through the stock market is more likely to be the method used when there is an established capital market capable of absorbing the shares. A market with high liquidity can facilitate the privatization. If the capital markets are insufficiently developed, however, it would be difficult to find enough buyers. The shares may have to be underpriced, and the sales may not raise as much capital as would be justified by the fair value of the company being privatized. Many governments, therefore, elect for listings in more sophisticated markets, for example, ], and the ], ] and ] stock exchanges. | |||
The above arguments have centered on whether or not it is practical to apply privatization in the real world, but some reject the profit incentive, the theoretical basis for privatization, itself. Some opponents of privatization argue that because the driving motive of a private company is profit, not public service, the public welfare may be sacrificed to the demands of profitability. There is no definitive answer, but it is very often argued that essential services, such as water, electricity, health, primary education, and so forth, should be left in public hands. This argument, of course, relies on the view on the obligations of the state, regarding what it should or should not be obliged to do. What is seen as desirable by a socialist may not be by a supporter of capitalism, and vice versa. | |||
Governments in ] and ] more often resort to direct asset sales to a few investors, partly because those countries do not yet have a stock market with high capital. | |||
==Outcomes== | |||
Academic studies show that in competitive industries with well-informed consumers, privatization consistently improves efficiency. Such efficiency gains mean a one-off increase in ], but through improved incentives to innovate and reduce costs also tend to raise the rate of ]. The type of industries to which this generally applies include ] and ]. Although typically there are social costs associated with these efficiency gains, many economists argue that these can be dealt with by appropriate government support through ] and perhaps ]. | |||
Voucher privatization occurred mainly in the ] in Central and Eastern Europe, such as ], ], the ], and ]. Additionally, privatization from below had made important contribution to economic growth in transition economies.{{Citation needed|date=December 2023}} | |||
In sectors that are ] or ], the results of privatization are much more mixed. In general, if the performance of the existing public sector operation is sufficiently bad, privatization will tend to improve matters. However, much of this may be due to the imposition of related reforms such as improved accounting systems, ], and increased financing, rather than privatization itself. Indeed, some studies show that the greatest gains from privatization are achieved in the pre-privatization period as reforms are made to prepare for the transfer to private hands. In ] economic theory, a private ] behaves much the same as a public one. | |||
In one study assimilating some of the literature on "privatization" that occurred in Russian and Czech Republic transition economies, the authors identified three methods of privatization: "privatization by sale", "mass privatization", and "mixed privatization". Their calculations showed that "mass privatization" was the most effective method.<ref name="methods" /> | |||
==Alternatives to privatization== | |||
===Sub-contracting=== | |||
It is possible that national services may sub-contract functions to private enterprises. A notable example of this is in the ], where the government is currently debating the possibility of involving the private sector more in the workings of the ], principally by referring patients to private surgeries to ease the load on existing NHS human resources, and covering the cost of this. | |||
However, in economies "characterized by shortages" and maintained by the state bureaucracy, wealth was accumulated and concentrated by "gray/black market" operators. Privatizing industries by sale to these individuals did not mean a transition to "effective private sector owners state assets". Rather than mainly participating in a market economy, these individuals could prefer elevating their personal status or prefer accumulating political power. Instead, outside foreign investment led to the efficient conduct of former state assets in the private sector and market economy.<ref name="methods">{{cite journal |last1=John Bennett, Saul Estrin, and Giovanni Urga |title=Methods of privatization and economic growth in transition economies |journal=Economics of Transition |date=2007 |volume=15 |issue=4 |pages=661–683 |doi=10.1111/j.1468-0351.2007.00300.x |url=https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/140745/1/514551011.pdf |access-date=18 June 2017|hdl=10419/140745 |s2cid=447407 }}</ref> | |||
===Part ownership=== | |||
An enterprise may be privatized, with a number of shares in the company being owned by the state. This is a particularly notable phenomenon in Germany, where the state owns around a third of ]. As of ], the state of ] is also planning to buy shares in the energy company ] in an attempt to control spiraling costs. | |||
Through privatization by direct asset sale or the stock market, bidders compete to offer higher prices, generating more revenue for the state. Voucher privatization, on the other hand, could represent a genuine transfer of assets to the general population, creating a sense of participation and inclusion. A market could be created if the government permits transfer of vouchers among voucher holders. | |||
==Notable privatizations== | |||
''See also: ]'' | |||
=== Secured borrowing === | |||
Privatization programmes have been undertaken in many countries across the world, falling into three major groups. The first is privatization programmes conducted by ] in Central and Eastern Europe after ] in the process of instituting a ]. The second is privatization programmes carried out in ] under the influence of international financial institutions such as the ] and ]. The third is privatization programmes carried out by developed country governments, the most comprehensive probably being those of ] and the ] in the 1980s and 1990s. | |||
Some privatization transactions can be interpreted as a form of a ]<ref name="roin">{{Cite journal |last=Roin |first=Julie |title=Privatization and the Sale of Tax Revenues |ssrn=1880033 |date=2011-07-06 }}</ref><ref>, July 22, 2011, ''Chicago Tribune,'' Ameet Sachdev's Chicago Law, Ameet Sachdev</ref> and are criticized as a "particularly noxious form of governmental debt".<ref name="roin" /> In this interpretation, the upfront payment from the privatization sale corresponds to the ] of the loan, while the proceeds from the underlying asset correspond to secured interest payments—the transaction can be considered substantively the same as a secured loan, though it is structured as a sale.<ref name="roin" /> This interpretation is particularly argued to apply to recent municipal transactions in the United States, particularly for fixed term, such as the 2008 sale of the proceeds from ] for 75 years. It is argued that this is motivated by "politicians' desires to borrow money surreptitiously",<ref name="roin" /> due to legal restrictions on and political resistance to alternative sources of revenue, viz, raising taxes or issuing debt. | |||
== Results of privatization == | |||
===Privatization of national security=== | |||
Privatization had different outcomes around the world. Results of privatization may vary depending on the privatization model employed.<ref>Alen Jugovič, Ante Bistričić & Borna Debelić (2010) Economic Effects | |||
of Privatisation of Public Services Sector in the Republic of Croatia Emphasising MaritimePassenger Traffic, Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja, 23:4, 114–126, DOI: | |||
10.1080/1331677X.2010.11517437</ref> According to ], "it is somewhere between difficult and impossible to separate the effects of privatisation from the effects of such things as trends in the economy".<ref>Stelzer, I. (2000). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180220033519/https://iea.org.uk/publications/research/a-review-of-privatisation-and-regulation-experience-in-britain |date=2018-02-20 }}. Institute of Economic Affairs (IEA), Beesley series. Presentation at London Business School, 7 Nov 2000, Beesley series of lectures on regulation.</ref> | |||
According to research performed by the ]<ref name=nellis_kikeri>{{cite journal |ssrn=636224 |title=Privatisation in Competitive Sectors: The Record to Date, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2860 |journal=John Nellis and Sunita Kikeri |date=June 2002 |last1=Kikeri |first1=Sunita |last2=Nellis |first2=John }}</ref> and ]<ref name=megginson_netter>{{cite news |url=http://faculty-staff.ou.edu/M/William.L.Megginson-1/prvsvpapJLE.pdf |title=From State To Market: A Survey Of Empirical Studies On Privatisation |work=William L. Megginson and Jeffry M. Netter |date=June 2001 |publisher=Journal of Economic Literature |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20051002001503/http://faculty-staff.ou.edu/M/William.L.Megginson-1/prvsvpapJLE.pdf |archive-date=2005-10-02 }}</ref> in the early 2000s, privatization in competitive industries with well-informed consumers, consistently improved efficiency. According to ], the more competitive the industry, the greater the improvement in output, profitability, and efficiency.<ref name=oecd>{{cite web |url=http://www.apec.org.au/docs/10_TP_PFI%204/Privatising%20SOEs.pdf |title=Privatising State-owned Enterprises |access-date=2011-07-11 |date=2010-02-22 |page=9 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110909125124/http://www.apec.org.au/docs/10_TP_PFI%204/Privatising%20SOEs.pdf |archive-date=2011-09-09 |url-status=dead }}</ref> Such efficiency gains mean a one-off increase in ], but through improved incentives to innovate and reduce costs also tend to raise the rate of ].{{Citation needed|date=October 2020}} | |||
In October of ], a conference was held at The Rohatyn Center for International Affairs of ], entitled "The Privatization of National Security." Sponsored by the Rohatyn Center (''see ]'') and the Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs at ], the conference discussed privatization of functions which historically have been considered the sole province of the military and of official intelligence agencies. One participant, ], said that "In fact what we’re seeing is a return to neo-feudalism. If you think about how the East India Company played a role in the rise of the British Empire, there are similar parallels to the rise of the American quasi-empire." Feaver is presently an advisor to the ]. | |||
More recent research and literature review performed by Professor Saul Estrin and Adeline Pelletier concluded that "the literature now reflects a more cautious and nuanced evaluation of privatization" and that "private ownership alone is no longer argued to automatically generate economic gains in developing economies".<ref>{{cite journal| title=Privatization in Developing Countries: What Are the Lessons of Recent Experience?|author=Saul Estrin|author2=Adeline Pelletier|date=22 March 2018|journal=The World Bank Research Observer}}</ref> According to a 2008 study published in ''Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics'', liberalization and privatization have produced mixed results.<ref>{{cite journal|title=Liberalization and privatization of public utilities: origins of the debate, current issues and challenges for the future|journal=Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics|author=Giuseppe Bognetti|author2=Gabriel Obermann|volume=79|pages=461–485|date=11 September 2008|issue=3–4|doi=10.1111/j.1467-8292.2008.00367.x|s2cid=153538881|doi-access=free}}</ref> | |||
In an article which appeared the following month in the '']'' entitled "The Profit Motive goes to War," Rohatyn and Allison Stanger wrote: | |||
Although typically there are many costs associated with these efficiency gains,<ref>{{cite news |url=http://www.cgdev.org/docs/cgd_wp006.pdf |title=Winners and Losers: Assessing the Distributional Impact of Privatisation, CGD Working Paper No 6 |work=Nancy Birdsall & John Nellis |date=March 9, 2006 |publisher=Center for Global Development |access-date=2005-06-23 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20050623081056/http://www.cgdev.org/docs/cgd_wp006.pdf |archive-date=2005-06-23 |url-status=dead }}</ref> | |||
<blockquote>The past decade has witnessed a quiet revolution in the way the US projects its power abroad. In the first Gulf war, the ratio of American troops on the ground to private contractors was 50:1. In the 2003 Iraq war, that ratio was 10:1, as it was for the Clinton administration's interventions in Bosnia and Kosovo. As these figures reflect, key military functions have been outsourced to private companies; both Democratic and Republican presidents alike have steadily privatised crucial aspects of US national security. For a rough sense of the magnitude of this shift, Halliburton's total contracts in Iraq to date are estimated at $11bn-$13bn (£6bn-£7bn), more than twice what the first Gulf war cost the US.</blockquote> | |||
many economists argue{{who|date=October 2020}} that these can be dealt with by appropriate government support through ] and perhaps ].{{citation needed|date=March 2020}} Yet, some empirical literature suggests that privatization could also have very modest effects on efficiency and quite regressive distributive impact. In the first attempt at a social welfare analysis of the British privatization program under the Conservative governments of ] and ] during the 1980s and 1990s, ] points to the absence of any productivity shock resulting strictly from ownership change. Instead, the impact on the previously nationalized companies of the UK productivity leap under the Conservatives varied in different industries. In some cases, it occurred prior to privatization, and in other cases, it occurred upon privatization or several years afterward.<ref>{{Cite journal |jstor = 30032311|last1 = Evenson|first1 = Robert E.|title = Reviewed work: The Great Divestiture: Evaluating the Welfare Impact of the British Privatizations, 1979–1997, Massimo Florio|journal = Journal of Economic Literature|volume = 44|issue = 1|pages = 172–174|last2 = Megginson|first2 = William L.|year = 2006}}</ref> | |||
A 2012 study published by the ] argues that privatisation in Europe had mixed effects on service quality and has achieved only minor productivity gains, driven mainly by lower labour input combined with other cost cutting strategies that led to a deterioration of employment and working conditions.<ref>{{cite book|url=https://op.europa.eu/en/publication-detail/-/publication/0293d6e5-8b71-4001-b065-21641a5ce10a|title=Liberalisation and privatisation in the EU|date=10 November 2012|author=Dominik Sobczak|author2=Elke Loeffler|author3=Frankie Hine-hughes|publisher=Publications Office of the European Union|isbn=978-9279216367}}</ref> Meanwhile, a different study by the commission found that the UK rail network (which was privatized from 1994 to 1997) was most improved out of all the 27 EU nations from 1997 to 2012. The report examined a range of 14 different factors and the UK came top in four of the factors, second and third in another two and fourth in three, coming top overall.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.networkrail.co.uk/news/2013/apr/European-rail-study-report/ |title=European rail study report |access-date=2016-02-01 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151117022327/http://www.networkrail.co.uk/news/2013/apr/European-rail-study-report/ |archive-date=2015-11-17 |url-status=dead }}</ref> Nonetheless, the ] has been the subject of much debate, with the stated benefits including improved customer service, and more investment; and stated drawbacks including higher fares, lower punctuality and increased rail subsidies.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.networkrail.co.uk/about/performance/|title=Performance and punctuality (PPM) – Network Rail|access-date=20 November 2015|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151208114925/http://www.networkrail.co.uk/about/performance/|archive-date=8 December 2015|url-status=dead}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.globalrailwayreview.com/news/4832/92-of-uk-trains-arrive-on-time/|title=92% of UK trains arrive on time|website=Global Railway Review|language=en|access-date=2019-01-16}}</ref><ref name="bbc.co.uk"> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180314152818/http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/magazine-21056703 |date=2018-03-14 }}, ], 22 January 2013</ref> | |||
<blockquote>In the history of warfare, sub-contracting and the deployment of mercenaries are nothing new. The British built an empire with contracted soldiers, developing a citizens' army only in the latter half of the 19th century. But there are two major structural differences between the 19th century British and 21st century US empires. First, publicly quoted companies now conduct private military operations. Second, the market for this force is now genuinely global, which raises new accountability and normative concerns.</blockquote> | |||
Privatizations in Russia and Latin America were accompanied by large-scale corruption during the sale of the state-owned companies. Those with political connections unfairly gained large wealth, which has discredited privatization in these regions. While media have widely reported the grand corruption that accompanied those sales, according to research released by the World Bank there has been increased operating efficiency, daily petty corruption is, or would be, larger without privatization, and that corruption is more prevalent in non-privatized sectors. Furthermore, according to the World Bank extralegal and unofficial activities are more prevalent in countries that privatized less.<ref>Privatisation in Competitive Sectors: The Record to Date. Sunita Kikeri and John Nellis. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2860, June 2002. <!-- dead: http://www.econ.chula.ac.th/about/member/sothitorn/privatisation.pdf --> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110718134340/http://idei.fr/doc/conf/veol/straub_martimort.pdf |date=2011-07-18 }}. David Martimort and Stéphane Straub.</ref>{{full citation needed|date=October 2020}} Other research suggests that privatization in Russia resulted in a dramatic rise in the level of economic inequality and a collapse in GDP and industrial output.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Holmstrom|first=Nancy|author2=Richard Smith|date=February 2000|title=The Necessity of Gangster Capitalism: Primitive Accumulation in Russia and China|journal=Monthly Review|publisher=Monthly Review Foundation|volume=51|issue=9|page=1|doi=10.14452/MR-051-09-2000-02_1|url=http://monthlyreview.org/2000/02/01/the-necessity-of-gangster-capitalism}}</ref> | |||
Russian President ]'s ]-backed rapid privatization schemes saw half the Russian population fall into destitution in just several years as unemployment climbed to double digits by the early to mid 1990s.<ref>{{cite book |last=Mattei|first=Clara E.|date=2022 |title=The Capital Order: How Economists Invented Austerity and Paved the Way to Fascism|pages=301–302|url=https://press.uchicago.edu/ucp/books/book/chicago/C/bo181707138.html|location= |publisher=]|isbn=978-0226818399|quote="If, in 1987–1988, 2 percent of the Russian people lived in poverty (i.e., survived on less than $4 a day), by 1993–1995 the number reached 50 percent: in just seven years half the Russian population became destitute}}</ref> A 2009 study published in '']'' medical journal has found that as many as a million working men died as a result of economic shocks associated with mass privatization in the former ] and in ] during the 1990s,<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.ox.ac.uk/media/news_stories/2009/090115.html |title=Death surge linked with mass privatisation |publisher=] |date=2009 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140702113600/http://www.ox.ac.uk/media/news_stories/2009/090115.html |archive-date=2014-07-02 |access-date=2015-06-28 |url-status=dead}}</ref><ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160306005653/http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/health/7828901.stm |date=2016-03-06 }}. ''],'' 15 January 2009. Retrieved 29 June 2014.</ref> although a further study suggested that there were errors in their method and "correlations reported in the original article are simply not robust."<ref>{{cite journal |title=Did mass privatisation really increase post-communist mortality? |doi=10.1016/S0140-6736(10)60159-6 |pmid=20113819 |volume=375 |issue=9712 |pages=372; author reply 372–374 |journal=The Lancet |date=2010-01-30 |last1=Earle |first1=John S. |last2=Gehlbach |first2=Scott |s2cid=35337211 |doi-access=free }}</ref> A subsequent body of scholarship, while still controversial, demonstrates that rapid privatization schemes associated with ] economic reforms did result in poorer health outcomes in former Eastern Bloc countries during the transition to markets economies, with the ] contributing to the debate by stating "IMF economic reform programs are associated with significantly worsened tuberculosis incidence, prevalence, and mortality rates in post-communist Eastern European and former Soviet countries."<ref>{{cite book |last1=Ghodsee|first1=Kristen|last2=Orenstein|first2=Mitchell A.|author-link1=Kristen Ghodsee|date=2021|title=Taking Stock of Shock: Social Consequences of the 1989 Revolutions|url=https://oxford.universitypressscholarship.com/view/10.1093/oso/9780197549230.001.0001/oso-9780197549230|location=New York|publisher=]|page= 84|doi=10.1093/oso/9780197549230.001.0001 |isbn=978-0197549247}}</ref> Historian ], a specialist in ancient history, posits that ] and wealth concentration in the top percentile "had been made possible by the transfer of state assets to private owners."<ref>{{cite book |last=Scheidel |first=Walter |author-link=Walter Scheidel |title=The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century |publisher=] |year=2017 |isbn=978-0691165028 |page=222 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=NgZpDQAAQBAJ&pg=PA222}}</ref> | |||
==Anti-privatization campaigns== | |||
Privatization proposals in key ] sectors such as ] and ] are in many cases strongly opposed by opposition political parties and ] groups. Usually campaigns involve demonstrations and political means; sometimes they may become violent (eg ] in ]; ], Peru, June 2002). Opposition is often strongly supported by ]s. Opposition is usually strongest to ] - as well as Cochabamba (2000), recent examples include ] and ] (2004). In the latter case a civil-society-initiated ] banning water privatization was passed in October 2004. | |||
In Latin America, on the one hand, according to John Nellis's research for ], economic indicators, including firm profitability, productivity, and growth, project positive ] results.<ref name="Nellis" /> On the other hand, however, privatisation has been largely met with a negative criticism and citizen coalitions. This ] criticism highlights the ongoing conflict between varying visions of economic development. ] emphasizes the societal concerns of self-regulating markets through a concept known as a "double movement". In essence, whenever societies move towards increasingly unrestrained, free-market rule, a natural and inevitable societal correction emerges to undermine the contradictions of capitalism.{{Citation needed|date=October 2020}} This was the case in the ].{{Citation needed|date=October 2020}} | |||
==See also== | |||
*] | |||
*] | |||
*] ("]") | |||
*] | |||
*] | |||
*] (see "government securitization") | |||
*] | |||
*] | |||
Privatization in Latin America has invariably experienced increasing push-back from the public. ] from ] suggests that implementing a less efficient but more politically mindful approach could be more sustainable.<ref>"Why is Sector Reform So Unpopular in Latin America?" by Mary Shirley. The Ronald Coase Institute Working Paper, 2004, p. 1.</ref> | |||
==References== | |||
* Clarke, Thomas (ed.) (1994) "International Privatisation: Strategies and Practices" Berlin and New York: Walter de Gruyter, ISBN 3110135698 | |||
* Clarke, Thomas and Pitelis, Christos (eds.) (1995) "The Political Economy of Privatization" London and New York: Routledge, ISBN 041512705X | |||
* Nellis, John and Kikeri, Sunita (2002), (June 2002). World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2860. | |||
* Nancy Birdsall and John Nelllis (2002), , Center for Global Development Working Paper No 6., May 2002 | |||
* William L. Megginson and Jeffry M. Netter (2001), , ''Journal of Economic Literature'' June 2001 | |||
* Juliet D’Souza, William L. Megginson (1999), , ''Journal of Finance'' August 1999 | |||
In India, a survey by the ] (NCPCR) – Utilization of Free Medical Services by Children Belonging to the Economically Weaker Section (EWS) in Private Hospitals in New Delhi, 2011–12: A Rapid Appraisal – indicates under-utilization of the free beds available for EWS category in private hospitals in Delhi, though they were allotted land at subsidized rates.<ref>{{Cite news |title=Private hospitals shun destitute children |date=August 17, 2013 |url=http://www.thehindu.com/news/cities/Delhi/private-hospitals-shun-destitute-children/article5031905.ece |first=Bindu shajan |last=Perappadan |newspaper=The Hindu |access-date=21 August 2013}}</ref> | |||
==External links== | |||
* (pro-privatization) | |||
* | |||
* (privatization research blog) | |||
* The original 1983 Cato/Heritage plan—now almost complete. | |||
* (Non-profit organization committed to challenging the corporatization of culture and the privatization of the commons) | |||
* - Independent documentary film company based in Montréal, Canada that addresses issues related to privatisation | |||
* (World Bank Group) | |||
* | |||
* | |||
* | |||
In Australia a "People's Inquiry into Privatisation" (2016/17) found that the impact of privatisation on communities was negative. The report from the inquiry "Taking Back Control" <ref>{{Cite web |url=https://d3n8a8pro7vhmx.cloudfront.net/cpsu/pages/1573/attachments/original/1508714447/Taking_Back_Control_FINAL.pdf?1508714447 |title=Archived copy |access-date=2018-12-03 |archive-date=2020-01-29 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200129144432/https://d3n8a8pro7vhmx.cloudfront.net/cpsu/pages/1573/attachments/original/1508714447/Taking_Back_Control_FINAL.pdf?1508714447 |url-status=dead }}</ref>{{full citation needed|date=October 2020}} made a range of recommendations to provide accountability and transparency in the process. The report highlighted privatisation in healthcare, aged care, child care, social services, government departments, electricity, prisons and vocational education featuring the voices of workers, community members and academics. | |||
] | |||
Some reports show that the results of privatization are experienced differently between men and women for numerous reasons: when ]s are privatized women are expected to take on the health and social care of ],<ref>{{cite web|url=https://world-psi.org/uncsw/wordpress/wp-content/uploads/2019/03/FactSheetCSW63_Privatisation.pdf|title=Privatisation and Women's Human Rights : Factsheet for CSW63 advocacy|website=World-psi.org|accessdate=5 March 2022}}</ref> women have less access to privatized goods,<ref name=":2">{{Cite journal|last=Prizzia|first=Ross|date=Nov 2005|title=An International Perspective of Privatization and Women Workers|url=https://vc.bridgew.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1422&context=jiws|journal=Journal of International Women's Studies|volume=7|pages=54–68}}</ref> ] employs a larger proportion of women than does the ],<ref>{{cite web|title=Five facts on gender equity in the public sector|url=https://blogs.worldbank.org/governance/five-facts-gender-equity-public-sector|access-date=2021-11-29|website=blogs.worldbank.org|date=27 September 2021 |language=en}}</ref> and the women in the public sector are more likely to be ] than those in the private sector.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Stinson|first=Jane|title=Why Privatization is a Women's Issue|journal=Canadian Women's Studies|volume=23|pages=18–22|citeseerx=10.1.1.925.3111}}</ref> In Chile, women are disproportionately affected by the privatization of the pension system because factors such as "women's longer life expectancy, earlier retirement age, and lower rates of labor-force participation, lower salaries" affect their ability to accumulate funds for retirement which leads to lower pensions.<ref name=":2" /> ] women face an even greater burden; Anjela Taneja, of ] India says "The privatization of public services...implies limited or no access to essential services for women living in poverty, who are often the ones more in need of these services." | |||
] | |||
] | |||
The increase in privatization since the 1980s has been a factor in rising ] and ] inequality in the United States.<ref>{{cite news |last=Picchi |first=Aimee |date=December 7, 2021 |title=The new Gilded Age: 2,750 people have more wealth than half the planet |url=https://www.cbsnews.com/news/wealth-inequality-billionaires-piketty-report/ |work=] |location= |access-date=December 9, 2021}}</ref> | |||
] | |||
] | |||
==Foreign privatization== | |||
] | |||
Due to low levels of native ] in the former Central and Eastern Europe, the rapid privatization preferred by international institutions (], ], ]) and other foreign banks was a ''de facto'' call for international bidding, reflecting the assumption that foreign investment would play a major role.<ref>{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=N6AESa9YazMC&pg=PA116 |title=Mitchell Alexander Orenstein, Stephen R. Bloom, Nicole Lindstrom, University of Pittsburgh Press, 2008, ''Transnational Actors in Central and East European Transitions'', pp. 116–117 |isbn=9780822973447 |access-date=2022-09-28 |archive-date=2022-12-04 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221204101820/https://books.google.ro/books?id=N6AESa9YazMC&pg=PA116 |url-status=live |last1=Orenstein |first1=Mitchell Alexander |last2=Bloom |first2=Stephen R. |last3=Lindstrom |first3=Nicole |year=2008 |publisher=University of Pittsburgh Pre }}</ref> | |||
] | |||
] | |||
===Contrasting cases in Eastern Europe: Romania and East Germany=== | |||
] | |||
In post-] East Germany, by the end of June 1992, the '']'' had privatized 8,175 companies, with 5,950 left on hand (4,340 remaining to be sold and the remainder to be liquidated).<ref>{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=pe6JAgAAQBAJ&pg=PA588 |title=Ian Jeffries, Routledge, May 27, 1993, ''Socialist Economies and the Transition to the Market: A Guide'', p. 588 |isbn=9781134903603 |access-date=September 28, 2022 |archive-date=December 4, 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221204101726/https://books.google.ro/books?id=pe6JAgAAQBAJ&pg=PA588 |url-status=live |last1=Jeffries |first1=Ian |date=27 May 1993 |publisher=Routledge }}</ref> June 1992 was also when the last East German on the board of the ''Treuhand'' left.<ref>{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=n6a4CQAAQBAJ&pg=PA106 |title=Volker Schneider, Burkard Eberlein, Springer, May 26, 2015, ''Complex Democracy: Varieties, Crises, and Transformations'', p. 106 |isbn=9783319158501 |access-date=September 28, 2022 |archive-date=December 4, 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221204101726/https://books.google.ro/books?id=n6a4CQAAQBAJ&pg=PA106 |url-status=live |last1=Schneider |first1=Volker |last2=Eberlein |first2=Burkard |date=26 May 2015 |publisher=Springer }}</ref> By the end of 1994, ''Treuhand'' had sold almost everything, having only 65 firms left to privatize as of December 1994. More than 80% of the privatized businesses were bought by foreigners (chiefly West Germans – 75%).<ref>{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=zXsMgTVgM_QC&pg=PA187 |title=Padma Desai, MIT Press, 1997, ''Going Global: Transition from Plan to Market in the World Economy'', p. 187 |isbn=9780262041614 |access-date=2022-09-28 |archive-date=2022-12-04 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221204101726/https://books.google.ro/books?id=zXsMgTVgM_QC&pg=PA187 |url-status=live |last1=Desai |first1=Padma |year=1997 |publisher=MIT Press }}</ref> | |||
Romania's first privatization took place on 3 August 1992.<ref>{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=-G3qDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA185 |title=Roger East, Jolyon Pontin, Bloomsbury Publishing, Oct 6, 2016, ''Revolution and Change in Central and Eastern Europe: Revised Edition'', p. 185 |isbn=9781474287487 |access-date=September 28, 2022 |archive-date=December 4, 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221204101726/https://books.google.ro/books?id=-G3qDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA185 |url-status=live |last1=East |first1=Roger |last2=Pontin |first2=Jolyon |date=6 October 2016 |publisher=Bloomsbury }}</ref> There was "very little" privatization during 1992: only 22 state-owned enterprises were privatized. The pace picked up throughout the following year, with more than 260 companies privatized.<ref>{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=3ml1NgjOJs8C&pg=PA95 |title=Stephen D. Roper, Routledge, Aug 2, 2004, ''Romania: The Unfinished Revolution'', p. 95 |isbn=9781135287580 |access-date=September 28, 2022 |archive-date=December 4, 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221204101727/https://books.google.ro/books?id=3ml1NgjOJs8C&pg=PA95 |url-status=live |last1=Roper |first1=Stephen D. |date=2 August 2004 |publisher=Routledge }}</ref> Four of the 22 enterprises privatized in 1992 were sold to foreign investors.<ref>{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=v_co0exeiMYC&pg=PA88 |title=Liliana Pop, Manchester University Press, Sep 19, 2006, ''Democratising Capitalism?: The Political Economy of Post-Communist Transformations in Romania, 1989–2001'', p. 88 |isbn=9780719070945 |access-date=September 28, 2022 |archive-date=December 4, 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221204101800/https://books.google.ro/books?id=v_co0exeiMYC&pg=PA88 |url-status=live |last1=Pop |first1=Liliana |date=19 September 2006 |publisher=Manchester University Press }}</ref> In 1993, 265 companies were privatized, followed by 604 in 1994. Two companies were sold to foreign investors during this period, one each in 1993 and 1994. At the start of 1999, 4,330 companies were left to be privatized, with 5,476 having been sold during 1993–1998.<ref>{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=JKfWAgAAQBAJ&pg=PA64 |title=OECD, OECD Publishing, Oct 29, 2002, ''OECD Economic Surveys: Romania 2002'', p. 64 |date=29 October 2002 |publisher=OECD |isbn=9789264194120 |access-date=September 28, 2022 |archive-date=December 4, 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221204101727/https://books.google.ro/books?id=JKfWAgAAQBAJ&pg=PA64 |url-status=live }}</ref> At the end of 1998, only 2.4% of privatized companies had foreign participation.<ref>{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=SyOzJaYLxN0C&pg=PA94 |title=Roderick Martin, OUP Oxford, Mar 28, 2013, ''Constructing Capitalisms: Transforming Business Systems in Central and Eastern Europe'', p. 94 |isbn=978-0-19-965766-7 |access-date=September 28, 2022 |archive-date=December 4, 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221204101727/https://books.google.ro/books?id=SyOzJaYLxN0C&pg=PA94 |url-status=live |last1=Martin |first1=Roderick |date=28 March 2013 |publisher=OUP Oxford }}</ref> | |||
== Opinion == | |||
{{more citations needed section|date=July 2011}} | |||
Arguments for and against the controversial subject of privatization are presented here. | |||
=== Support === | |||
Proponents of privatization argue that, over time, this can lead to lower prices, improved quality, more choices, less corruption, less ], and/or quicker delivery. Many proponents do not argue that everything should be privatized. According to them, ]s and ] could be problematic. However, ] prefer that every function of the state be privatized, including ] and ].<ref name="libertarianpapers"> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20181001010127/http://libertarianpapers.org/articles/2011/lp-3-3.pdf |date=2018-10-01 }} Libertarian Papers Vol. 3, ART. NO. 3 (2011)</ref> | |||
Proponents of privatization make the following arguments: | |||
* Performance: state-run industries tend to be ]. A political government may only be motivated to improve a function when its poor performance becomes politically sensitive. | |||
* Increased efficiency: private companies and firms have a greater incentive to produce goods and services more efficiently to increase profits. | |||
* Specialization: a private ] has the ability to focus all relevant human and financial resources onto specific functions. A state-owned firm does not have the necessary resources to ] its goods and services as a result of the general products provided to the greatest number of people in the ]. | |||
* Improvements: conversely, the government may put off improvements due to political sensitivity and special interests—even in cases of companies that are run well and better serve their customers' needs. | |||
* Corruption: a state-monopolized function is prone to ]; decisions are made primarily for political reasons, personal gain of the decision-maker (i.e. "graft"), rather than economic ones. Corruption (or ] issues) in a state-run corporation affects the ongoing asset stream and company performance, whereas any corruption that may occur during the privatization process is a one-time event and does not affect ongoing cash flow or performance of the company. | |||
* Accountability: managers of privately owned companies are accountable to their owners/shareholders and to the consumer, and can only exist and thrive where needs are met. Managers of publicly owned companies are required to be more accountable to the broader community and to political "stakeholders". This can reduce their ability to directly and specifically serve the needs of their customers, and can bias investment decisions away from otherwise profitable areas. | |||
* Civil-liberty concerns: a company controlled by the state may have access to information or assets which may be used against dissidents or any individuals who disagree with their policies. | |||
* Goals: a political government tends to run an industry or company for ] goals rather than ] ones. | |||
* Capital: a privately held companies can sometimes more easily raise investment capital in the financial markets when such local markets exist and are suitably liquid. While interest rates for private companies are often higher than for government debt, this can serve as a useful constraint to promote efficient investments by private companies, instead of cross-subsidizing them with the overall credit-risk of the country. Investment decisions are then governed by market interest rates. State-owned industries have to compete with demands from other government departments and special interests. In either case, for smaller markets, ] may add substantially to the cost of capital. | |||
* Security: governments have had the tendency to "bail out" poorly run businesses, often due to the sensitivity of job losses, when economically, it may be better to let the business fold. | |||
* Lack of market discipline: poorly managed state companies are insulated from the same discipline as private companies, which could go bankrupt, have their management removed, or be taken over by competitors. Private companies are also able to take greater risks and then seek bankruptcy protection against creditors if those risks turn sour. | |||
* Natural monopolies: the existence of ] does not mean that these sectors must be state owned. Governments can enact or are armed with ] and bodies to deal with anti-competitive behavior of all companies public or private. | |||
* Concentration of wealth: ownership of and profits from successful enterprises tend to be dispersed and diversified—particularly in voucher privatization. The availability of more investment vehicles stimulates capital markets and promotes liquidity and job creation. | |||
* Political influence: nationalized industries are prone to interference from ] for ] or ] reasons. Examples include making an industry buy supplies from local producers (when that may be more expensive than buying from abroad), forcing an industry to freeze its prices/fares to satisfy the electorate or control ], increasing its staffing to reduce ], or moving its operations to ]. | |||
* Profits: corporations exist to generate profits for their shareholders. Private companies make a profit by enticing ]s to buy their products in preference to their competitors' (or by increasing ] for their products, or by reducing costs). Private corporations typically profit more if they serve the needs of their clients well. Corporations of different sizes may target different market niches in order to focus on marginal groups and satisfy their demand. A company with good ] will therefore be incentivized to meet the needs of its customers efficiently. | |||
* Job gains: as the economy becomes more efficient, more profits are obtained and no government subsidies and less taxes are needed, there will be more private money available for investments and consumption and more profitable and better-paid jobs will be created than in the case of a more regulated economy.<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20091018193244/http://www.heritage.org/Research/Europe/HL352.cfm |date=2009-10-18 }}, Heritage Lecture #352</ref>{{Unreliable source?|date=July 2010}} | |||
=== Opposition === | |||
Opponents of privatization in general—or of certain privatizations in particular—believe that ] should remain primarily in the hands of government in order to ensure that everyone in society has access to them (such as law enforcement, basic ], and basic ]). There is a ] when the government provides society at large with public goods and services such as ] and disease control. Some national constitutions in effect define their governments' "core businesses" as being the provision of such things as justice, tranquility, defense, and general welfare. These governments' direct provision of security, stability, and safety, is intended to be done for the common good (in the public interest) with a long-term (for posterity) perspective. As for ], opponents of privatization claim that they aren't subject to fair competition, and better administrated by the state. | |||
Although private companies may provide a similar good or service alongside the government,{{according to whom|date=July 2021}} opponents of privatization are critical about completely transferring the provision of public goods, services and assets into private hands for the following reasons: | |||
* Performance: a democratically elected government is accountable to the people through a legislature, Congress or ], and is motivated to safeguarding the assets of the nation. The profit motive may be subordinated to social objectives. | |||
* Improvements: the government is motivated to performance improvements as well run businesses contribute to the State's revenues. | |||
* Corruption: government ministers and civil servants are bound to uphold the highest ethical standards, and standards of probity are guaranteed through codes of conduct and declarations of interest. However, the selling process could lack transparency, allowing the purchaser and civil servants controlling the sale to gain personally. | |||
* Accountability: the public has less control and oversight of private companies although these remain answerable to various stakeholders, including shareholders, clients, suppliers, regulators, employees and collaborators. | |||
* Civil-liberty concerns: a democratically elected government is accountable to the people through a ], and can intervene when civil liberties are threatened. | |||
* Goals: the government may seek to use state companies as instruments to further social goals for the benefit of the nation as a whole. | |||
* Capital: governments can raise money in the financial markets most cheaply to re-lend to state-owned enterprises, although this preferential access to capital markets risks undermining financial discipline because of the assurance of a bailout from the government. | |||
* Cuts in essential services: if a government-owned company providing an essential service (such as the water supply) to all citizens is privatized, its new owner(s) could lead to the abandoning of the social obligation to those who are less able to pay, or to regions where this service is unprofitable. | |||
* Natural monopolies: privatization will not result in true competition if a ] exists. | |||
* Concentration of wealth: profits from successful enterprises end up in private hands instead of being available for public use. | |||
* Political influence: governments may more easily exert pressure on state-owned firms to help implement government policy. | |||
* Profit: private companies do not have any goal other than to maximize profits. | |||
* Privatization and poverty: it is acknowledged by many studies that there are winners and losers with privatization. The number of losers—which may add up to the size and severity of poverty—can be unexpectedly large if the method and process of privatization and how it is implemented are seriously flawed (e.g. lack of transparency leading to state-owned assets being appropriated at minuscule amounts by those with political connections, absence of regulatory institutions leading to transfer of monopoly rents from public to private sector, improper design and inadequate control of the privatization process leading to ]).<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Dagdeviren |year=2006 |title=Revisiting privatisation in the context of poverty alleviation |journal=Journal of International Development |volume=18 |issue= 4|pages=469–488 |doi=10.1002/jid.1244}}</ref> | |||
* Job loss: due to the additional financial burden placed on privatized companies to succeed without any government help, unlike the public companies, jobs could be lost to keep more money in the company. | |||
* Reduced wages and benefits: a 2014 report by In the Public Interest, a resource center on privatization,<ref>David Moberg (6 June 2014). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140625103322/http://inthesetimes.com/working/entry/16811/privatization_IPTI_report |date=2014-06-25 }}. ''].'' Retrieved 28 June 2014.</ref> argues that "outsourcing public services sets off a downward spiral in which reduced worker wages and benefits can hurt the local economy and overall stability of middle and working class communities."<ref> {{webarchive|url=http://webarchive.loc.gov/all/20140604184737/http%3A//www.inthepublicinterest.org/RaceToTheBottom |date=2014-06-04 }}. In the Public Interest, 3 June 2014. Retrieved 7 June 2014.</ref> | |||
* Inferior quality products: private, for-profit companies cut corners on providing quality goods and services in order to maximize profit.<ref>Joshua Holland (17 July 2014). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140723140523/http://billmoyers.com/2014/07/17/how-a-bogus-industry-funded-study-helped-spur-a-privatization-disaster-in-michigan/ |date=2014-07-23 }}. ''].'' Retrieved 20 July 2014.</ref> | |||
== Economic theory == | |||
In economic theory, privatization has been studied in the field of ]. When contracts are complete, institutions such as (private or public) property are difficult to explain, since every desired incentive structure can be achieved with sufficiently complex contractual arrangements, regardless of the institutional structure. All that matters is who are the decision makers and what is their available information. In contrast, when contracts are incomplete, institutions matter. A leading application of the incomplete contract paradigm in the context of privatization is the model by ], ], and ] (1997).<ref>{{cite journal |title=The Proper Scope of Government: Theory and an Application to Prisons |journal=The Quarterly Journal of Economics |date=1997 |issn=0033-5533 |pages=1127–1161 |volume=112 |issue=4 |doi=10.1162/003355300555448 |language=en |first1=Oliver |last1=Hart |first2=Andrei |last2=Shleifer |first3=Robert W. |last3=Vishny|citeseerx=10.1.1.318.7133 |s2cid=16270301 |url=http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:30727607 }}</ref> In their model, a manager can make investments to increase quality (but they may also increase costs) and investments to decrease costs (but they may also reduce quality). It turns out that it depends on the particular situation whether private ownership or public ownership is desirable. The Hart-Shleifer-Vishny model has been further developed in various directions, e.g. to allow for mixed public-private ownership and endogenous assignments of the investment tasks.<ref>{{Cite journal |title=Public versus private ownership: Quantity contracts and the allocation of investment tasks |journal=Journal of Public Economics |date=2010 |pages=258–268 |volume=94 |issue=3–4 |doi=10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.009 |first1=Eva I. |last1=Hoppe |first2=Patrick W. |last2=Schmitz}}</ref> | |||
== Privatization of private companies == | |||
Privatization can also refer to the purchase of all ] of a ] private company by ] investors, which is more often called "going private". The buyout withdraws the company's shares from being traded at a public ].<ref name=":0" /><ref name=":1" /> Depending on the involvement of internal and external investors, it may occur through a ] or a ], ], or ].<ref name=":0" /> | |||
== See also == | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
== Notes == | |||
<references /> | |||
== References == | |||
* {{cite journal |last1=Alexander |first1=Jason |title=Contracting Through the Lens of Classical Pragmatism: An Exploration of Local Government Contracting |url=http://ecommons.txstate.edu/arp/288/ |journal=An Applied Research Project Submitted to the Department of Political Science, Texas State University-San Marcos, in Partial Fulfillment for the Requirements for the Degree of Masters of Public Administration, Spring 2009 |publisher=Texas State University |access-date=31 October 2018 |date=2009 |archive-date=21 June 2010 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100621122134/http://ecommons.txstate.edu/arp/288/ |url-status=dead }} | |||
* {{cite journal |last1=Dovalina |first1=Jessica |title=Assessing the Ethical Issues Found in the Contracting Out Process |url=http://ecommons.txstate.edu/arp/108/ |journal=An Applied Research Project Submitted to the Department of Political Science, Texas State University–San Marcos, in Partial Fulfillment for the Requirements for the Degree of Masters of Public Administration, Spring 2006 |publisher=Texas State University |access-date=31 October 2018 |date=2006 |archive-date=25 June 2010 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100625140633/http://ecommons.txstate.edu/arp/108/ |url-status=dead }} | |||
* {{cite web |last1=Segerfeldt |first1=Fredrik |title=Water for sale: how business and the market can resolve the world's water crisis |url=http://www.stockholm-network.org/downloads/events/d41d8cd9-Amigo%20Segerfeldt.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110716155421/http://www.stockholm-network.org/downloads/events/d41d8cd9-Amigo%20Segerfeldt.pdf |url-status=dead |archive-date=2011-07-16 |website=Stockholm Network |access-date=31 October 2018 |date=2006 }} | |||
* {{cite journal |last1=Black |first1=Bernard |display-authors=etal|title=Russian Privatization and Corporate Governance: What Went Wrong? |journal=Stanford Law Review |date=2000 |volume=52 |issue=6 |pages=1731–1808 |language=en|doi=10.2307/1229501 |jstor=1229501 |hdl=2027.42/41203 |hdl-access=free }} | |||
* {{cite book |last1=Feghali |first1=Khalil |title=La privatisation au Liban : allocation des ressources et efficacité de la gestion |date=2013 |publisher=L'Harmattan |location=Paris |isbn=978-2-343-00839-4 }} | |||
* {{cite journal |last1=Hoppe |first1=Eva I. |last2=Schmitz |first2=Patrick W. |year=2010 |title=Public versus private ownership: quantity contracts and the allocation of investment tasks |journal=Journal of Public Economics |volume=94 |issue= 3–4|pages=258–268 |doi=10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.009}} | |||
* {{cite book |last1=Kemp |first1=Roger L. |title=Privatization: The Provision of Public Services by the Private Sector |date=2007 |publisher=McFarland & Co., Inc., Publishers |location=Jefferson City, NC and London|isbn=978-0-7864-3250-9 }} | |||
; Unindexed | |||
* {{cite book |author1=Beito, David T. |author2= Peter Gordon|author3=Alexander Tabarrok |author4= Paul Johnson |title=The voluntary city: choice, community, and civil society |publisher=University of Michigan Press/The Independent Institute |location=Ann Arbor |year=2002 |isbn=978-0-472-08837-9 |url-access=registration |url=https://archive.org/details/volunta_xxx_2002_00_9922|id=editors and forward }} | |||
* {{cite journal |last1=Bel |first1=Germà |year=2006 |title=The coining of 'privatisation´and Germany's National Socialist Party |url=http://www.ub.es/graap/JEP.pdf |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives |volume=20 |issue=3 |pages=187–194 |doi=10.1257/jep.20.3.187|doi-access=free }} | |||
* Clarke, Thomas (ed.) (1994) "International Privatisation: Strategies and Practices" Berlin and New York: Walter de Gruyter, {{ISBN|3-11-013569-8}} | |||
* Clarke, Thomas and Pitelis, Christos (eds.) (1995) "The Political Economy of Privatisation" London and New York: Routledge, {{ISBN|0-415-12705-X}} | |||
* {{cite journal |last1=D'Souza |first1=Juliet |last2=Megginson |first2=William L. |title=The Financial and Operating Performance of Privatised Firms during the 1990s |journal=Journal of Finance |date=August 1999 |volume=1999 |url=http://faculty-staff.ou.edu/M/William.L.Megginson-1/prv90pap.pdf |access-date=31 October 2018 |language=en |archive-date=2 October 2005 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20051002001501/http://faculty-staff.ou.edu/M/William.L.Megginson-1/prv90pap.pdf |url-status=dead }} | |||
* von Hayek, Friedrich, (1960) '']''{{ISBN?}} | |||
* Kosar, Kevin R. (2006), , ''Report from the Congressional Research Service'' | |||
* Mayer, Florian (2006) ''Vom Niedergang des unternehmerisch tätigen Staates: Privatisierungspolitik in Großbritannien, Frankreich, Italien und Deutschland'', VS Verlag, Wiesbaden, {{ISBN|3-531-14918-0}} | |||
* Megginson and Netter, From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization, ] 39(2), June 2001, 321–389. | |||
* {{cite book |author=Onses, Richard|title=Benchmarking Privatization: the building of privatization index using fuzzy logic |publisher=International Conference on Modeling and Simulation |location=Valladolid |year=2004 |isbn=978-84-688-7867-6|title-link=fuzzy logic }} | |||
* {{cite book |author=Onses, Richard|title=The privatization leaders guide |publisher=e-privatization.com publication |year=2004 |isbn=978-84-607-9613-8}} | |||
* ] (2002), ''Economia pubblica rimossa'', Milan, Giuffrè {{ISBN|88-14-10088-8}} | |||
* {{cite encyclopedia|last=Poole|first=Robert W.|author-link=|editor-first=Ronald |editor-last=Hamowy |editor-link=Ronald Hamowy |encyclopedia=The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism |chapter=Privatization|chapter-url=https://sk.sagepub.com/reference/libertarianism/n244.xml|url= https://books.google.com/books?id=yxNgXs3TkJYC |doi=10.4135/9781412965811.n244 |year=2008 |publisher= ]; ] |location= Thousand Oaks, CA |isbn= 978-1412965804 |oclc=750831024| <!-- lccn = 2008009151 | -->pages=143–144}} | |||
* Smith, Adam (1776) '']'' | |||
* Sprague, Jeb 2007. . Inter Press Service. | |||
* ] '']'' | |||
* von Weizsäcker, Ernst, Oran Young, and Matthias Finger (editors): ''Limits to Privatisation''. Earthscan, London 2005 {{ISBN|1-84407-177-4}} | |||
* {{cite book|author=Wolin, Sheldon|author-link=Sheldon Wolin|year=2008|title=Democracy Incorporated: Managed Democracy and the Specter of Inverted Totalitarianism|publisher=Princeton University Press|isbn=978-0-691-13566-3}} ('''Trad. esp.''': ''Democracia S. A.'', Buenos Aires/Madrid, Katz editores S.A, 2008, {{ISBN|978-84-96859-46-3}}) | |||
* Zullo, Roland. (2009). . Governance 22.3 (July): 459–481. | |||
== External links == | |||
{{Wikiquote}} | |||
{{Wiktionary}} | |||
* from the | |||
* Research database with many articles on the effects of privatization | |||
* {{cite journal |title=Privatisation ten years on : a critical analysis of its rationale and results |author=Parker, David |publisher=Cranfield University, School of Management|year=1991 |hdl = 1826/606|journal=Cranfield CERES}} | |||
{{aspects of capitalism}} | |||
{{property navbox}} | |||
{{authority control}} | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] | |||
] |
Latest revision as of 11:20, 13 December 2024
Transferring something from the public sphere to the private See also: List of privatizations by countryPrivatization (rendered privatisation in British English) can mean several different things, most commonly referring to moving something from the public sector into the private sector. It is also sometimes used as a synonym for deregulation when a heavily regulated private company or industry becomes less regulated. Government functions and services may also be privatised (which may also be known as "franchising" or "out-sourcing"); in this case, private entities are tasked with the implementation of government programs or performance of government services that had previously been the purview of state-run agencies. Some examples include revenue collection, law enforcement, water supply, and prison management.
Another definition is that privatization is the sale of a state-owned enterprise or municipally owned corporation to private investors; in this case shares may be traded in the public market for the first time, or for the first time since an enterprise's previous nationalization. This type of privatization can include the demutualization of a mutual organization, cooperative, or public-private partnership in order to form a joint-stock company.
Separately, privatization can refer to the purchase of all outstanding shares of a publicly traded company by private equity investors, which is more often called "going private". Before and after this process the company is privately owned, but after the buyout its shares are withdrawn from being traded at a public stock exchange.
Etymology
The term privatizing first appeared in English, with quotation marks, in the New York Times, in April 1923, in a translation of a German speech referring to the potential for German state railroads to be bought by American companies. In German, the word Privatisierung has been used since at least the 19th century. Ultimately, the word came to German through French from the Latin privatus.
The term reprivatization, again translated directly from German (Reprivatisierung), was used frequently in the mid-1930s as The Economist reported on Nazi Germany's sale of nationalized banks back to public shareholders following the 1931 economic crisis.
The word became common in the late 1970s and early 1980s as part of UK prime minister Margaret Thatcher's economic policies. She was drawing on the work of the pro-privatization Member of Parliament David Howell, who was himself drawing on the Austrian-American management expert Peter Drucker's 1969 book, The Age of Discontinuity.
Definition
The word privatization may mean different things depending on the context in which it is used. It can mean moving something from the public sphere into the private sphere, but it may also be used to describe something that was always private, but heavily regulated, which becomes less regulated through a process of deregulation. The term may also be used descriptively for something that has always been private, but could be public in other jurisdictions.
There are also private entities that may perform public functions. These entities could also be described as privatized. Privatization may mean the government sells state-owned businesses to private interests, but it may also be discussed in the context of the privatization of services or government functions, where private entities are tasked with the implementation of government programs or the performance of government services. Gillian E. Metzger has written that: "Private entities provide a vast array of social services for the government; administer core aspects of government programs; and perform tasks that appear quintessentially governmental, such as promulgating standards or regulating third-party activities." Metzger mentions an expansion of privatization that includes health and welfare programs, public education, and prisons.
History
See also: List of privatizationsPre-20th century
The history of privatization dates from Ancient Greece, when governments contracted out almost everything to the private sector. In the Roman Republic private individuals and companies performed the majority of services including tax collection (tax farming), army supplies (military contractors), religious sacrifices and construction. However, the Roman Empire also created state-owned enterprises—for example, much of the grain was eventually produced on estates owned by the Emperor. David Parker and David S. Saal suggest that the cost of bureaucracy was one of the reasons for the fall of the Roman Empire.
Perhaps one of the first ideological movements towards privatization came during China's golden age of the Han dynasty. Taoism came into prominence for the first time at a state level, and it advocated the laissez-faire principle of Wu wei (無為), literally meaning "do nothing". The rulers were counseled by the Taoist clergy that a strong ruler was virtually invisible.
During the Renaissance, most of Europe was still by and large following the feudal economic model. By contrast, the Ming dynasty in China began once more to practice privatization, especially with regards to their manufacturing industries. This was a reversal of the earlier Song dynasty policies, which had themselves overturned earlier policies in favor of more rigorous state control.
In Britain, the privatization of common lands is referred to as enclosure (in Scotland as the Lowland Clearances and the Highland Clearances). Significant privatizations of this nature occurred from 1760 to 1820, preceding the Industrial Revolution in that country.
20th century onwards
The first mass privatization of state property occurred in Nazi Germany between 1933 and 1937: "It is a fact that the government of the National Socialist Party sold off public ownership in several state-owned firms in the middle of the 1930s. The firms belonged to a wide range of sectors: steel, mining, banking, local public utilities, shipyard, ship-lines, railways, etc. In addition to this, delivery of some public services produced by public administrations prior to the 1930s, especially social services and services related to work, was transferred to the private sector, mainly to several organizations within the Nazi Party."
Great Britain privatized its steel industry in the 1950s, and the West German government embarked on large-scale privatization, including sale of the majority stake in Volkswagen to small investors in public share offerings in 1961. However, it was in the 1980s under Margaret Thatcher in the United Kingdom and Ronald Reagan in the United States that privatization gained worldwide momentum. Notable privatizations in the UK included Britoil (1982), the radioactive-chemicals company Amersham International (1982), British Telecom (1984), Sealink ferries (1984), British Petroleum (gradually privatized between 1979 and 1987), British Aerospace (1985 to 1987), British Gas (1986), Rolls-Royce (1987), Rover Group (formerly British Leyland, 1988), British Steel Corporation (1988), Girobank (1989), and the regional water authorities of England and Wales (mostly in 1989). After 1979, council house tenants in the UK were given the right to buy their homes at a heavily discounted price; one million had purchased their residences by 1986.
Such efforts culminated in 1993 when British Rail was privatized under Thatcher's successor, John Major. British Rail had been formed by prior nationalization of private rail companies. The privatization was controversial, and its impact is still debated today, as doubling of passenger numbers and investment was balanced by an increase in rail subsidy.
These privatizations received mixed views from the public and the parliament. Even former Conservative prime minister Harold Macmillan was critical of the policy, likening it to "selling the family silver". There were around 3 million shareholders in Britain when Thatcher took office in 1979, but the subsequent sale of state-run firms saw the number of shareholders double by 1985. By the time of her resignation in 1990, there were more than 10 million shareholders in Britain.
Privatization in Latin America was extensive in the 1980s and 1990s, as a result of a Western liberal economic policy. Companies providing public services such as water management, transportation, and telecommunications were rapidly sold off to the private sector. In the 1990s, privatization revenue from 18 Latin American countries totaled 6% of gross domestic product. Private investment in infrastructure from 1990 and 2001 reached $360.5 billion, $150 billion more than in the next emerging economy.
While economists generally give favorable evaluations of the impact of privatization in Latin America, opinion polls and public protests across the countries suggest that a large segment of the public is dissatisfied with or have negative views of privatization in the region.
In the 1990s, the governments in Eastern and Central Europe engaged in extensive privatization of state-owned enterprises in Eastern and Central Europe and Russia, with assistance from the World Bank, the U.S. Agency for International Development, the German Treuhand, and other governmental and non-governmental organization.
Nippon Telegraph and Telephone's privatization in 1987 involved the largest share offering in financial history at the time. 15 of the world's 20 largest public share offerings have been privatizations of telecoms.
In 1988, the perestroika policy of Mikhail Gorbachev started allowing privatization of the centrally planned economy. Large privatization of the Soviet economy occurred over the next few years as the country dissolved. Other Eastern Bloc countries followed suit after the Revolutions of 1989 introduced non-communist governments.
Freedom House's privatization index, 1998 and 2002
Freedom House's privatization index rated transition countries from 1 (maximum progress) to 7 (no progress). The table below shows the privatization index for various Eastern European countries in 1998 and 2002:
Privatization index |
1998 | 2002 |
---|---|---|
Bulgaria | 4.0 | 3.0 |
Czech Republic | 2.0 | 1.75 |
Hungary | 1.5 | 1.5 |
Poland | 2.25 | 2.25 |
Romania | 4.5 | 3.75 |
Slovakia | 3.25 | 2.0 |
Slovenia | 2.5 | 2.5 |
Russia | 3.0 | 3.5 |
The largest public shares offering in France involved France Télécom.
Egypt undertook widespread privatization under Hosni Mubarak. Following his overthrow in the 2011 revolution, most of the public began to call for re-nationalization, citing allegations of the privatized firms practicing crony capitalism under the old regime.
Reasons for privatization
There are various reasons why a government may decide to privatize; commonly due to economic reasons. The economic factors that influence a government's decision to privatize assume this will lower government debt. Studies have shown that governments are more likely to privatise with higher public debt, typically because governments do not have the needed time to wait for a return. Another economic factor that influences this area is the resulting efficiency of SOEs once privatised. Commonly, governments aren’t able to provide the required investments required to ensure profitability for various reasons. These factors may lead to a government deciding to privatize.
Forms of privatization
This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (June 2016) (Learn how and when to remove this message) |
There are several main methods of privatization:
- Share issue privatization: shares sale on the stock market.
- Asset sale privatization: asset divestiture to a strategic investor, usually by auction or through the Treuhand model.
- Voucher privatization: distribution of vouchers, which represent part ownership of a corporation, to all citizens, usually for free or at a very low price.
- Privatization from below: start of new private businesses in formerly socialist countries.
- Management buyout: purchase of public shares by management of the company, sometimes by borrowing from external lenders
- Employee buyout: distribution of shares for free or at a very low price to workers or management of the organization.
The choice of sale method is influenced by the capital market and the political and firm-specific factors. Privatization through the stock market is more likely to be the method used when there is an established capital market capable of absorbing the shares. A market with high liquidity can facilitate the privatization. If the capital markets are insufficiently developed, however, it would be difficult to find enough buyers. The shares may have to be underpriced, and the sales may not raise as much capital as would be justified by the fair value of the company being privatized. Many governments, therefore, elect for listings in more sophisticated markets, for example, Euronext, and the London, New York and Hong Kong stock exchanges.
Governments in developing countries and transition countries more often resort to direct asset sales to a few investors, partly because those countries do not yet have a stock market with high capital.
Voucher privatization occurred mainly in the transition economies in Central and Eastern Europe, such as Russia, Poland, the Czech Republic, and Slovakia. Additionally, privatization from below had made important contribution to economic growth in transition economies.
In one study assimilating some of the literature on "privatization" that occurred in Russian and Czech Republic transition economies, the authors identified three methods of privatization: "privatization by sale", "mass privatization", and "mixed privatization". Their calculations showed that "mass privatization" was the most effective method.
However, in economies "characterized by shortages" and maintained by the state bureaucracy, wealth was accumulated and concentrated by "gray/black market" operators. Privatizing industries by sale to these individuals did not mean a transition to "effective private sector owners state assets". Rather than mainly participating in a market economy, these individuals could prefer elevating their personal status or prefer accumulating political power. Instead, outside foreign investment led to the efficient conduct of former state assets in the private sector and market economy.
Through privatization by direct asset sale or the stock market, bidders compete to offer higher prices, generating more revenue for the state. Voucher privatization, on the other hand, could represent a genuine transfer of assets to the general population, creating a sense of participation and inclusion. A market could be created if the government permits transfer of vouchers among voucher holders.
Secured borrowing
Some privatization transactions can be interpreted as a form of a secured loan and are criticized as a "particularly noxious form of governmental debt". In this interpretation, the upfront payment from the privatization sale corresponds to the principal amount of the loan, while the proceeds from the underlying asset correspond to secured interest payments—the transaction can be considered substantively the same as a secured loan, though it is structured as a sale. This interpretation is particularly argued to apply to recent municipal transactions in the United States, particularly for fixed term, such as the 2008 sale of the proceeds from Chicago parking meters for 75 years. It is argued that this is motivated by "politicians' desires to borrow money surreptitiously", due to legal restrictions on and political resistance to alternative sources of revenue, viz, raising taxes or issuing debt.
Results of privatization
Privatization had different outcomes around the world. Results of privatization may vary depending on the privatization model employed. According to Irwin Stelzer, "it is somewhere between difficult and impossible to separate the effects of privatisation from the effects of such things as trends in the economy".
According to research performed by the World Bank and William L. Megginson in the early 2000s, privatization in competitive industries with well-informed consumers, consistently improved efficiency. According to APEC, the more competitive the industry, the greater the improvement in output, profitability, and efficiency. Such efficiency gains mean a one-off increase in GDP, but through improved incentives to innovate and reduce costs also tend to raise the rate of economic growth.
More recent research and literature review performed by Professor Saul Estrin and Adeline Pelletier concluded that "the literature now reflects a more cautious and nuanced evaluation of privatization" and that "private ownership alone is no longer argued to automatically generate economic gains in developing economies". According to a 2008 study published in Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, liberalization and privatization have produced mixed results.
Although typically there are many costs associated with these efficiency gains, many economists argue that these can be dealt with by appropriate government support through redistribution and perhaps retraining. Yet, some empirical literature suggests that privatization could also have very modest effects on efficiency and quite regressive distributive impact. In the first attempt at a social welfare analysis of the British privatization program under the Conservative governments of Margaret Thatcher and John Major during the 1980s and 1990s, Massimo Florio points to the absence of any productivity shock resulting strictly from ownership change. Instead, the impact on the previously nationalized companies of the UK productivity leap under the Conservatives varied in different industries. In some cases, it occurred prior to privatization, and in other cases, it occurred upon privatization or several years afterward.
A 2012 study published by the European Commission argues that privatisation in Europe had mixed effects on service quality and has achieved only minor productivity gains, driven mainly by lower labour input combined with other cost cutting strategies that led to a deterioration of employment and working conditions. Meanwhile, a different study by the commission found that the UK rail network (which was privatized from 1994 to 1997) was most improved out of all the 27 EU nations from 1997 to 2012. The report examined a range of 14 different factors and the UK came top in four of the factors, second and third in another two and fourth in three, coming top overall. Nonetheless, the impact of the privatisation of British Rail has been the subject of much debate, with the stated benefits including improved customer service, and more investment; and stated drawbacks including higher fares, lower punctuality and increased rail subsidies.
Privatizations in Russia and Latin America were accompanied by large-scale corruption during the sale of the state-owned companies. Those with political connections unfairly gained large wealth, which has discredited privatization in these regions. While media have widely reported the grand corruption that accompanied those sales, according to research released by the World Bank there has been increased operating efficiency, daily petty corruption is, or would be, larger without privatization, and that corruption is more prevalent in non-privatized sectors. Furthermore, according to the World Bank extralegal and unofficial activities are more prevalent in countries that privatized less. Other research suggests that privatization in Russia resulted in a dramatic rise in the level of economic inequality and a collapse in GDP and industrial output.
Russian President Boris Yeltsin's IMF-backed rapid privatization schemes saw half the Russian population fall into destitution in just several years as unemployment climbed to double digits by the early to mid 1990s. A 2009 study published in The Lancet medical journal has found that as many as a million working men died as a result of economic shocks associated with mass privatization in the former Soviet Union and in Eastern Europe during the 1990s, although a further study suggested that there were errors in their method and "correlations reported in the original article are simply not robust." A subsequent body of scholarship, while still controversial, demonstrates that rapid privatization schemes associated with neoliberal economic reforms did result in poorer health outcomes in former Eastern Bloc countries during the transition to markets economies, with the World Health Organization contributing to the debate by stating "IMF economic reform programs are associated with significantly worsened tuberculosis incidence, prevalence, and mortality rates in post-communist Eastern European and former Soviet countries." Historian Walter Scheidel, a specialist in ancient history, posits that economic inequality and wealth concentration in the top percentile "had been made possible by the transfer of state assets to private owners."
In Latin America, on the one hand, according to John Nellis's research for Center for Global Development, economic indicators, including firm profitability, productivity, and growth, project positive microeconomic results. On the other hand, however, privatisation has been largely met with a negative criticism and citizen coalitions. This neoliberal criticism highlights the ongoing conflict between varying visions of economic development. Karl Polanyi emphasizes the societal concerns of self-regulating markets through a concept known as a "double movement". In essence, whenever societies move towards increasingly unrestrained, free-market rule, a natural and inevitable societal correction emerges to undermine the contradictions of capitalism. This was the case in the 2000 Cochabamba protests.
Privatization in Latin America has invariably experienced increasing push-back from the public. Mary Shirley from The Ronald Coase Institute suggests that implementing a less efficient but more politically mindful approach could be more sustainable.
In India, a survey by the National Commission for Protection of Child Rights (NCPCR) – Utilization of Free Medical Services by Children Belonging to the Economically Weaker Section (EWS) in Private Hospitals in New Delhi, 2011–12: A Rapid Appraisal – indicates under-utilization of the free beds available for EWS category in private hospitals in Delhi, though they were allotted land at subsidized rates.
In Australia a "People's Inquiry into Privatisation" (2016/17) found that the impact of privatisation on communities was negative. The report from the inquiry "Taking Back Control" made a range of recommendations to provide accountability and transparency in the process. The report highlighted privatisation in healthcare, aged care, child care, social services, government departments, electricity, prisons and vocational education featuring the voices of workers, community members and academics.
Some reports show that the results of privatization are experienced differently between men and women for numerous reasons: when public services are privatized women are expected to take on the health and social care of dependents, women have less access to privatized goods, public sector employs a larger proportion of women than does the private sector, and the women in the public sector are more likely to be unionized than those in the private sector. In Chile, women are disproportionately affected by the privatization of the pension system because factors such as "women's longer life expectancy, earlier retirement age, and lower rates of labor-force participation, lower salaries" affect their ability to accumulate funds for retirement which leads to lower pensions. Low-income women face an even greater burden; Anjela Taneja, of Oxfam India says "The privatization of public services...implies limited or no access to essential services for women living in poverty, who are often the ones more in need of these services."
The increase in privatization since the 1980s has been a factor in rising income and wealth inequality in the United States.
Foreign privatization
Due to low levels of native capital accumulation in the former Central and Eastern Europe, the rapid privatization preferred by international institutions (EBRD, IMF, World Bank) and other foreign banks was a de facto call for international bidding, reflecting the assumption that foreign investment would play a major role.
Contrasting cases in Eastern Europe: Romania and East Germany
In post-reunification East Germany, by the end of June 1992, the Treuhandanstalt had privatized 8,175 companies, with 5,950 left on hand (4,340 remaining to be sold and the remainder to be liquidated). June 1992 was also when the last East German on the board of the Treuhand left. By the end of 1994, Treuhand had sold almost everything, having only 65 firms left to privatize as of December 1994. More than 80% of the privatized businesses were bought by foreigners (chiefly West Germans – 75%).
Romania's first privatization took place on 3 August 1992. There was "very little" privatization during 1992: only 22 state-owned enterprises were privatized. The pace picked up throughout the following year, with more than 260 companies privatized. Four of the 22 enterprises privatized in 1992 were sold to foreign investors. In 1993, 265 companies were privatized, followed by 604 in 1994. Two companies were sold to foreign investors during this period, one each in 1993 and 1994. At the start of 1999, 4,330 companies were left to be privatized, with 5,476 having been sold during 1993–1998. At the end of 1998, only 2.4% of privatized companies had foreign participation.
Opinion
This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (July 2011) (Learn how and when to remove this message) |
Arguments for and against the controversial subject of privatization are presented here.
Support
Proponents of privatization argue that, over time, this can lead to lower prices, improved quality, more choices, less corruption, less red tape, and/or quicker delivery. Many proponents do not argue that everything should be privatized. According to them, market failures and natural monopolies could be problematic. However, anarcho-capitalists prefer that every function of the state be privatized, including defense and dispute resolution.
Proponents of privatization make the following arguments:
- Performance: state-run industries tend to be bureaucratic. A political government may only be motivated to improve a function when its poor performance becomes politically sensitive.
- Increased efficiency: private companies and firms have a greater incentive to produce goods and services more efficiently to increase profits.
- Specialization: a private business has the ability to focus all relevant human and financial resources onto specific functions. A state-owned firm does not have the necessary resources to specialize its goods and services as a result of the general products provided to the greatest number of people in the population.
- Improvements: conversely, the government may put off improvements due to political sensitivity and special interests—even in cases of companies that are run well and better serve their customers' needs.
- Corruption: a state-monopolized function is prone to corruption; decisions are made primarily for political reasons, personal gain of the decision-maker (i.e. "graft"), rather than economic ones. Corruption (or principal–agent issues) in a state-run corporation affects the ongoing asset stream and company performance, whereas any corruption that may occur during the privatization process is a one-time event and does not affect ongoing cash flow or performance of the company.
- Accountability: managers of privately owned companies are accountable to their owners/shareholders and to the consumer, and can only exist and thrive where needs are met. Managers of publicly owned companies are required to be more accountable to the broader community and to political "stakeholders". This can reduce their ability to directly and specifically serve the needs of their customers, and can bias investment decisions away from otherwise profitable areas.
- Civil-liberty concerns: a company controlled by the state may have access to information or assets which may be used against dissidents or any individuals who disagree with their policies.
- Goals: a political government tends to run an industry or company for political goals rather than economic ones.
- Capital: a privately held companies can sometimes more easily raise investment capital in the financial markets when such local markets exist and are suitably liquid. While interest rates for private companies are often higher than for government debt, this can serve as a useful constraint to promote efficient investments by private companies, instead of cross-subsidizing them with the overall credit-risk of the country. Investment decisions are then governed by market interest rates. State-owned industries have to compete with demands from other government departments and special interests. In either case, for smaller markets, political risk may add substantially to the cost of capital.
- Security: governments have had the tendency to "bail out" poorly run businesses, often due to the sensitivity of job losses, when economically, it may be better to let the business fold.
- Lack of market discipline: poorly managed state companies are insulated from the same discipline as private companies, which could go bankrupt, have their management removed, or be taken over by competitors. Private companies are also able to take greater risks and then seek bankruptcy protection against creditors if those risks turn sour.
- Natural monopolies: the existence of natural monopolies does not mean that these sectors must be state owned. Governments can enact or are armed with anti-trust legislation and bodies to deal with anti-competitive behavior of all companies public or private.
- Concentration of wealth: ownership of and profits from successful enterprises tend to be dispersed and diversified—particularly in voucher privatization. The availability of more investment vehicles stimulates capital markets and promotes liquidity and job creation.
- Political influence: nationalized industries are prone to interference from politicians for political or populist reasons. Examples include making an industry buy supplies from local producers (when that may be more expensive than buying from abroad), forcing an industry to freeze its prices/fares to satisfy the electorate or control inflation, increasing its staffing to reduce unemployment, or moving its operations to marginal constituencies.
- Profits: corporations exist to generate profits for their shareholders. Private companies make a profit by enticing consumers to buy their products in preference to their competitors' (or by increasing primary demand for their products, or by reducing costs). Private corporations typically profit more if they serve the needs of their clients well. Corporations of different sizes may target different market niches in order to focus on marginal groups and satisfy their demand. A company with good corporate governance will therefore be incentivized to meet the needs of its customers efficiently.
- Job gains: as the economy becomes more efficient, more profits are obtained and no government subsidies and less taxes are needed, there will be more private money available for investments and consumption and more profitable and better-paid jobs will be created than in the case of a more regulated economy.
Opposition
Opponents of privatization in general—or of certain privatizations in particular—believe that public goods and services should remain primarily in the hands of government in order to ensure that everyone in society has access to them (such as law enforcement, basic health care, and basic education). There is a positive externality when the government provides society at large with public goods and services such as defense and disease control. Some national constitutions in effect define their governments' "core businesses" as being the provision of such things as justice, tranquility, defense, and general welfare. These governments' direct provision of security, stability, and safety, is intended to be done for the common good (in the public interest) with a long-term (for posterity) perspective. As for natural monopolies, opponents of privatization claim that they aren't subject to fair competition, and better administrated by the state.
Although private companies may provide a similar good or service alongside the government, opponents of privatization are critical about completely transferring the provision of public goods, services and assets into private hands for the following reasons:
- Performance: a democratically elected government is accountable to the people through a legislature, Congress or Parliament, and is motivated to safeguarding the assets of the nation. The profit motive may be subordinated to social objectives.
- Improvements: the government is motivated to performance improvements as well run businesses contribute to the State's revenues.
- Corruption: government ministers and civil servants are bound to uphold the highest ethical standards, and standards of probity are guaranteed through codes of conduct and declarations of interest. However, the selling process could lack transparency, allowing the purchaser and civil servants controlling the sale to gain personally.
- Accountability: the public has less control and oversight of private companies although these remain answerable to various stakeholders, including shareholders, clients, suppliers, regulators, employees and collaborators.
- Civil-liberty concerns: a democratically elected government is accountable to the people through a parliament, and can intervene when civil liberties are threatened.
- Goals: the government may seek to use state companies as instruments to further social goals for the benefit of the nation as a whole.
- Capital: governments can raise money in the financial markets most cheaply to re-lend to state-owned enterprises, although this preferential access to capital markets risks undermining financial discipline because of the assurance of a bailout from the government.
- Cuts in essential services: if a government-owned company providing an essential service (such as the water supply) to all citizens is privatized, its new owner(s) could lead to the abandoning of the social obligation to those who are less able to pay, or to regions where this service is unprofitable.
- Natural monopolies: privatization will not result in true competition if a natural monopoly exists.
- Concentration of wealth: profits from successful enterprises end up in private hands instead of being available for public use.
- Political influence: governments may more easily exert pressure on state-owned firms to help implement government policy.
- Profit: private companies do not have any goal other than to maximize profits.
- Privatization and poverty: it is acknowledged by many studies that there are winners and losers with privatization. The number of losers—which may add up to the size and severity of poverty—can be unexpectedly large if the method and process of privatization and how it is implemented are seriously flawed (e.g. lack of transparency leading to state-owned assets being appropriated at minuscule amounts by those with political connections, absence of regulatory institutions leading to transfer of monopoly rents from public to private sector, improper design and inadequate control of the privatization process leading to asset stripping).
- Job loss: due to the additional financial burden placed on privatized companies to succeed without any government help, unlike the public companies, jobs could be lost to keep more money in the company.
- Reduced wages and benefits: a 2014 report by In the Public Interest, a resource center on privatization, argues that "outsourcing public services sets off a downward spiral in which reduced worker wages and benefits can hurt the local economy and overall stability of middle and working class communities."
- Inferior quality products: private, for-profit companies cut corners on providing quality goods and services in order to maximize profit.
Economic theory
In economic theory, privatization has been studied in the field of contract theory. When contracts are complete, institutions such as (private or public) property are difficult to explain, since every desired incentive structure can be achieved with sufficiently complex contractual arrangements, regardless of the institutional structure. All that matters is who are the decision makers and what is their available information. In contrast, when contracts are incomplete, institutions matter. A leading application of the incomplete contract paradigm in the context of privatization is the model by Hart, Shleifer, and Vishny (1997). In their model, a manager can make investments to increase quality (but they may also increase costs) and investments to decrease costs (but they may also reduce quality). It turns out that it depends on the particular situation whether private ownership or public ownership is desirable. The Hart-Shleifer-Vishny model has been further developed in various directions, e.g. to allow for mixed public-private ownership and endogenous assignments of the investment tasks.
Privatization of private companies
Privatization can also refer to the purchase of all outstanding shares of a publicly traded private company by private equity investors, which is more often called "going private". The buyout withdraws the company's shares from being traded at a public stock exchange. Depending on the involvement of internal and external investors, it may occur through a leveraged buyout or a management buyout, tender offer, or hostile takeover.
See also
- Commodification
- Corporatization
- Deregulation
- Equitisation
- Kibbutz
- List of nationalizations by country
- List of privatizations by country
- Marketization
- Nationalization
- Private prison
- Private sector development
- Privately owned public space
- Structural adjustment
Notes
- Chowdhury, F. L. ‘’Corrupt Bureaucracy and Privatisation of Tax Enforcement’’, 2006: Pathak Samabesh, Dhaka.
- "Musselburgh Co-op in crisis as privatization bid fails". Co-operative News. 2005-11-01. Archived from the original on 2017-12-22. Retrieved 2008-05-21.
- ^ Fernando, Jason. "Going Private Definition". Investopedia. Retrieved 2021-08-05.
- ^ Dumont, Marvin. "Why Do Public Companies Go Private?". Investopedia. Retrieved 2021-08-05.
- "Asserts Americans 'Plot' With French". The New York Times. 7 April 1923 . p. 4.
- Kämmerer, Jörn Axel (2001). Privatisierung (in German). Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck. ISBN 978-3-16-147515-3.
- "Privatisieren". Duden.
- ^ Bel, Germa (Summer 2006). "The Coining of "Privatization" and Germany's National Socialist Party". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 20 (3): 187–194. doi:10.1257/jep.20.3.187. S2CID 33815402.
- Beerman, Jack (2001-01-01). "Privatization and Political Accountability". Fordham Urban Law Journal. 28 (5): 1507.
- Metzger, Gillian (2003-01-01). "Privatization as Delegation". Colum. L. Rev. 103 (6): 1367–1502. doi:10.2307/3593390. JSTOR 3593390.
- ^ International Handbook on Privatization by David Parker, David S. Saal
- Li & Zheng 2001, p. 241 harvnb error: no target: CITEREFLiZheng2001 (help)
- Bouye, Thomas M., Manslaughter, markets, and moral economy
- Bel, Germà (2010-02-01). "Against the mainstream: Nazi privatization in 1930s Germany1" (PDF). The Economic History Review. 63 (1): 34–55. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0289.2009.00473.x. hdl:2445/11716. ISSN 1468-0289. S2CID 154486694.
- Birrell, Ian (2013-08-15). "Forget the nostalgia for British Rail – our trains are better than ever". The Guardian.
- "Harold Macmillan". Number10.gov.uk. Archived from the original on 5 August 2011 – via Internet Archive.
- "Thatcher years in graphics". BBC News. 2005-11-18.
- ^ "Privatization in Latin America: The rapid rise, recent fall, and continuing puzzle of a contentious economic policy" by John Nellis, Rachel Menezes, Sarah Lucas. Center for Global Development Policy Brief, Jan 2004, p. 1.
- "The Distributive Impact of Privatization in Latin America: Evidence from Four Countries" by David McKenzie, Dilip Mookherjee, Gonzalo Castañeda and Jaime Saavedra. Brookings Institution Press, 2008, p. 162.
- "Why is Sector Reform So Unpopular in Latin America?" by Mary Shirley. The Ronald Coase Institute Working Papers, 2004, p. 1.
- ^ The Financial Economics of Privatisation By William L. Megginson, pp. 205–206
- Graham, Norman A.; Lindahl, Folke; Kocaoglu, Timur (19 March 2021). Norman A. Graham, Folke Lindahl, Timur Kocaoglu, Rowman & Littlefield, Mar 19, 2021, Making Russia and Turkey Great Again?: Putin and Erdogan in Search of Lost Empires and Autocratic Power, p. 45. Rowman & Littlefield. ISBN 9781793610232. Archived from the original on December 4, 2022. Retrieved October 6, 2022.
- Amos, Deborah, "In Egypt, Revolution Moves Into The Factories" Archived 2018-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, NPR, April 20, 2011. Retrieved 2011-04-20.
- Ramamurti, Ravi (1992). "Why Are Developing Countries Privatizing?". Journal of International Business Studies. 23 (2): 229. doi:10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8490266.
- Radíc, Mislav (2021). "Privatization: Implications of a Shift from State to Private Ownership" (PDF). Journal of Management. 47 (6): 1596–1629. doi:10.1177/0149206320988356.
- ^ John Bennett, Saul Estrin, and Giovanni Urga (2007). "Methods of privatization and economic growth in transition economies" (PDF). Economics of Transition. 15 (4): 661–683. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0351.2007.00300.x. hdl:10419/140745. S2CID 447407. Retrieved 18 June 2017.
{{cite journal}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - ^ Roin, Julie (2011-07-06). "Privatization and the Sale of Tax Revenues". SSRN 1880033.
{{cite journal}}
: Cite journal requires|journal=
(help) - U. of C. professor argues privatization of public assets just like borrowing money, July 22, 2011, Chicago Tribune, Ameet Sachdev's Chicago Law, Ameet Sachdev
- Alen Jugovič, Ante Bistričić & Borna Debelić (2010) Economic Effects of Privatisation of Public Services Sector in the Republic of Croatia Emphasising MaritimePassenger Traffic, Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja, 23:4, 114–126, DOI: 10.1080/1331677X.2010.11517437
- Stelzer, I. (2000). A review of privatisation and regulation experience in Britain Archived 2018-02-20 at the Wayback Machine. Institute of Economic Affairs (IEA), Beesley series. Presentation at London Business School, 7 Nov 2000, Beesley series of lectures on regulation.
- Kikeri, Sunita; Nellis, John (June 2002). "Privatisation in Competitive Sectors: The Record to Date, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2860". John Nellis and Sunita Kikeri. SSRN 636224.
- "From State To Market: A Survey Of Empirical Studies On Privatisation" (PDF). William L. Megginson and Jeffry M. Netter. Journal of Economic Literature. June 2001. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2005-10-02.
- "Privatising State-owned Enterprises" (PDF). 2010-02-22. p. 9. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2011-09-09. Retrieved 2011-07-11.
- Saul Estrin; Adeline Pelletier (22 March 2018). "Privatization in Developing Countries: What Are the Lessons of Recent Experience?". The World Bank Research Observer.
- Giuseppe Bognetti; Gabriel Obermann (11 September 2008). "Liberalization and privatization of public utilities: origins of the debate, current issues and challenges for the future". Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics. 79 (3–4): 461–485. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8292.2008.00367.x. S2CID 153538881.
- "Winners and Losers: Assessing the Distributional Impact of Privatisation, CGD Working Paper No 6" (PDF). Nancy Birdsall & John Nellis. Center for Global Development. March 9, 2006. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2005-06-23. Retrieved 2005-06-23.
- Evenson, Robert E.; Megginson, William L. (2006). "Reviewed work: The Great Divestiture: Evaluating the Welfare Impact of the British Privatizations, 1979–1997, Massimo Florio". Journal of Economic Literature. 44 (1): 172–174. JSTOR 30032311.
- Dominik Sobczak; Elke Loeffler; Frankie Hine-hughes (10 November 2012). Liberalisation and privatisation in the EU. Publications Office of the European Union. ISBN 978-9279216367.
- "European rail study report". Archived from the original on 2015-11-17. Retrieved 2016-02-01.
- "Performance and punctuality (PPM) – Network Rail". Archived from the original on 8 December 2015. Retrieved 20 November 2015.
- "92% of UK trains arrive on time". Global Railway Review. Retrieved 2019-01-16.
- Have train fares gone up or down since British Rail? Archived 2018-03-14 at the Wayback Machine, BBC News, 22 January 2013
- Privatisation in Competitive Sectors: The Record to Date. Sunita Kikeri and John Nellis. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2860, June 2002. Privatisation and Corruption Archived 2011-07-18 at the Wayback Machine. David Martimort and Stéphane Straub.
- Holmstrom, Nancy; Richard Smith (February 2000). "The Necessity of Gangster Capitalism: Primitive Accumulation in Russia and China". Monthly Review. 51 (9). Monthly Review Foundation: 1. doi:10.14452/MR-051-09-2000-02_1.
- Mattei, Clara E. (2022). The Capital Order: How Economists Invented Austerity and Paved the Way to Fascism. University of Chicago Press. pp. 301–302. ISBN 978-0226818399.
"If, in 1987–1988, 2 percent of the Russian people lived in poverty (i.e., survived on less than $4 a day), by 1993–1995 the number reached 50 percent: in just seven years half the Russian population became destitute
- "Death surge linked with mass privatisation". University of Oxford. 2009. Archived from the original on 2014-07-02. Retrieved 2015-06-28.
- Privatisation 'raised death rate' Archived 2016-03-06 at the Wayback Machine. BBC, 15 January 2009. Retrieved 29 June 2014.
- Earle, John S.; Gehlbach, Scott (2010-01-30). "Did mass privatisation really increase post-communist mortality?". The Lancet. 375 (9712): 372, author reply 372–374. doi:10.1016/S0140-6736(10)60159-6. PMID 20113819. S2CID 35337211.
- Ghodsee, Kristen; Orenstein, Mitchell A. (2021). Taking Stock of Shock: Social Consequences of the 1989 Revolutions. New York: Oxford University Press. p. 84. doi:10.1093/oso/9780197549230.001.0001. ISBN 978-0197549247.
- Scheidel, Walter (2017). The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century. Princeton University Press. p. 222. ISBN 978-0691165028.
- "Why is Sector Reform So Unpopular in Latin America?" by Mary Shirley. The Ronald Coase Institute Working Paper, 2004, p. 1.
- Perappadan, Bindu shajan (August 17, 2013). "Private hospitals shun destitute children". The Hindu. Retrieved 21 August 2013.
- "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2020-01-29. Retrieved 2018-12-03.
{{cite web}}
: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link) - "Privatisation and Women's Human Rights : Factsheet for CSW63 advocacy" (PDF). World-psi.org. Retrieved 5 March 2022.
- ^ Prizzia, Ross (Nov 2005). "An International Perspective of Privatization and Women Workers". Journal of International Women's Studies. 7: 54–68.
- "Five facts on gender equity in the public sector". blogs.worldbank.org. 27 September 2021. Retrieved 2021-11-29.
- Stinson, Jane. "Why Privatization is a Women's Issue". Canadian Women's Studies. 23: 18–22. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.925.3111.
- Picchi, Aimee (December 7, 2021). "The new Gilded Age: 2,750 people have more wealth than half the planet". CBS News. Retrieved December 9, 2021.
- Orenstein, Mitchell Alexander; Bloom, Stephen R.; Lindstrom, Nicole (2008). Mitchell Alexander Orenstein, Stephen R. Bloom, Nicole Lindstrom, University of Pittsburgh Press, 2008, Transnational Actors in Central and East European Transitions, pp. 116–117. University of Pittsburgh Pre. ISBN 9780822973447. Archived from the original on 2022-12-04. Retrieved 2022-09-28.
- Jeffries, Ian (27 May 1993). Ian Jeffries, Routledge, May 27, 1993, Socialist Economies and the Transition to the Market: A Guide, p. 588. Routledge. ISBN 9781134903603. Archived from the original on December 4, 2022. Retrieved September 28, 2022.
- Schneider, Volker; Eberlein, Burkard (26 May 2015). Volker Schneider, Burkard Eberlein, Springer, May 26, 2015, Complex Democracy: Varieties, Crises, and Transformations, p. 106. Springer. ISBN 9783319158501. Archived from the original on December 4, 2022. Retrieved September 28, 2022.
- Desai, Padma (1997). Padma Desai, MIT Press, 1997, Going Global: Transition from Plan to Market in the World Economy, p. 187. MIT Press. ISBN 9780262041614. Archived from the original on 2022-12-04. Retrieved 2022-09-28.
- East, Roger; Pontin, Jolyon (6 October 2016). Roger East, Jolyon Pontin, Bloomsbury Publishing, Oct 6, 2016, Revolution and Change in Central and Eastern Europe: Revised Edition, p. 185. Bloomsbury. ISBN 9781474287487. Archived from the original on December 4, 2022. Retrieved September 28, 2022.
- Roper, Stephen D. (2 August 2004). Stephen D. Roper, Routledge, Aug 2, 2004, Romania: The Unfinished Revolution, p. 95. Routledge. ISBN 9781135287580. Archived from the original on December 4, 2022. Retrieved September 28, 2022.
- Pop, Liliana (19 September 2006). Liliana Pop, Manchester University Press, Sep 19, 2006, Democratising Capitalism?: The Political Economy of Post-Communist Transformations in Romania, 1989–2001, p. 88. Manchester University Press. ISBN 9780719070945. Archived from the original on December 4, 2022. Retrieved September 28, 2022.
- OECD, OECD Publishing, Oct 29, 2002, OECD Economic Surveys: Romania 2002, p. 64. OECD. 29 October 2002. ISBN 9789264194120. Archived from the original on December 4, 2022. Retrieved September 28, 2022.
- Martin, Roderick (28 March 2013). Roderick Martin, OUP Oxford, Mar 28, 2013, Constructing Capitalisms: Transforming Business Systems in Central and Eastern Europe, p. 94. OUP Oxford. ISBN 978-0-19-965766-7. Archived from the original on December 4, 2022. Retrieved September 28, 2022.
- "Review of Kosanke's Instead of Politics – Don Stacy" Archived 2018-10-01 at the Wayback Machine Libertarian Papers Vol. 3, ART. NO. 3 (2011)
- Central Europe's Mass-Production Privatization Archived 2009-10-18 at the Wayback Machine, Heritage Lecture #352
- Dagdeviren (2006). "Revisiting privatisation in the context of poverty alleviation". Journal of International Development. 18 (4): 469–488. doi:10.1002/jid.1244.
- David Moberg (6 June 2014). Privatizing Government Services Doesn’t Only Hurt Public Workers Archived 2014-06-25 at the Wayback Machine. In These Times. Retrieved 28 June 2014.
- Race to the Bottom: How Outsourcing Public Services Rewards Corporations and Punishes the Middle Class Archived 2014-06-04 at the Library of Congress Web Archives. In the Public Interest, 3 June 2014. Retrieved 7 June 2014.
- Joshua Holland (17 July 2014). How a Bogus, Industry-Funded Study Helped Spur a Privatization Disaster in Michigan Archived 2014-07-23 at the Wayback Machine. Moyers & Company. Retrieved 20 July 2014.
- Hart, Oliver; Shleifer, Andrei; Vishny, Robert W. (1997). "The Proper Scope of Government: Theory and an Application to Prisons". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112 (4): 1127–1161. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.318.7133. doi:10.1162/003355300555448. ISSN 0033-5533. S2CID 16270301.
- Hoppe, Eva I.; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2010). "Public versus private ownership: Quantity contracts and the allocation of investment tasks". Journal of Public Economics. 94 (3–4): 258–268. doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.009.
References
- Alexander, Jason (2009). "Contracting Through the Lens of Classical Pragmatism: An Exploration of Local Government Contracting". An Applied Research Project Submitted to the Department of Political Science, Texas State University-San Marcos, in Partial Fulfillment for the Requirements for the Degree of Masters of Public Administration, Spring 2009. Texas State University. Archived from the original on 21 June 2010. Retrieved 31 October 2018.
- Dovalina, Jessica (2006). "Assessing the Ethical Issues Found in the Contracting Out Process". An Applied Research Project Submitted to the Department of Political Science, Texas State University–San Marcos, in Partial Fulfillment for the Requirements for the Degree of Masters of Public Administration, Spring 2006. Texas State University. Archived from the original on 25 June 2010. Retrieved 31 October 2018.
- Segerfeldt, Fredrik (2006). "Water for sale: how business and the market can resolve the world's water crisis" (PDF). Stockholm Network. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2011-07-16. Retrieved 31 October 2018.
- Black, Bernard; et al. (2000). "Russian Privatization and Corporate Governance: What Went Wrong?". Stanford Law Review. 52 (6): 1731–1808. doi:10.2307/1229501. hdl:2027.42/41203. JSTOR 1229501.
- Feghali, Khalil (2013). La privatisation au Liban : allocation des ressources et efficacité de la gestion. Paris: L'Harmattan. ISBN 978-2-343-00839-4.
- Hoppe, Eva I.; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2010). "Public versus private ownership: quantity contracts and the allocation of investment tasks". Journal of Public Economics. 94 (3–4): 258–268. doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.009.
- Kemp, Roger L. (2007). Privatization: The Provision of Public Services by the Private Sector. Jefferson City, NC and London: McFarland & Co., Inc., Publishers. ISBN 978-0-7864-3250-9.
- Unindexed
- Beito, David T.; Peter Gordon; Alexander Tabarrok; Paul Johnson (2002). The voluntary city: choice, community, and civil society. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press/The Independent Institute. ISBN 978-0-472-08837-9. editors and forward.
- Bel, Germà (2006). "The coining of 'privatisation´and Germany's National Socialist Party" (PDF). Journal of Economic Perspectives. 20 (3): 187–194. doi:10.1257/jep.20.3.187.
- Clarke, Thomas (ed.) (1994) "International Privatisation: Strategies and Practices" Berlin and New York: Walter de Gruyter, ISBN 3-11-013569-8
- Clarke, Thomas and Pitelis, Christos (eds.) (1995) "The Political Economy of Privatisation" London and New York: Routledge, ISBN 0-415-12705-X
- D'Souza, Juliet; Megginson, William L. (August 1999). "The Financial and Operating Performance of Privatised Firms during the 1990s" (PDF). Journal of Finance. 1999. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2 October 2005. Retrieved 31 October 2018.
- von Hayek, Friedrich, (1960) The Constitution of Liberty
- Kosar, Kevin R. (2006), "Privatisation and the Federal Government: An Introduction", Report from the Congressional Research Service
- Mayer, Florian (2006) Vom Niedergang des unternehmerisch tätigen Staates: Privatisierungspolitik in Großbritannien, Frankreich, Italien und Deutschland, VS Verlag, Wiesbaden, ISBN 3-531-14918-0
- Megginson and Netter, From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization, Journal of Economic Literature 39(2), June 2001, 321–389.
- Onses, Richard (2004). Benchmarking Privatization: the building of privatization index using fuzzy logic. Valladolid: International Conference on Modeling and Simulation. ISBN 978-84-688-7867-6.
- Onses, Richard (2004). The privatization leaders guide. e-privatization.com publication. ISBN 978-84-607-9613-8.
- Nico Perrone (2002), Economia pubblica rimossa, Milan, Giuffrè ISBN 88-14-10088-8
- Poole, Robert W. (2008). "Privatization". In Hamowy, Ronald (ed.). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage; Cato Institute. pp. 143–144. doi:10.4135/9781412965811.n244. ISBN 978-1412965804. OCLC 750831024.
- Smith, Adam (1776) The Wealth of Nations
- Sprague, Jeb 2007. Haiti: Workers Protest Privatisation Layoffs. Inter Press Service.
- Stiglitz, Joseph Globalization and Its Discontents
- von Weizsäcker, Ernst, Oran Young, and Matthias Finger (editors): Limits to Privatisation. Earthscan, London 2005 ISBN 1-84407-177-4
- Wolin, Sheldon (2008). Democracy Incorporated: Managed Democracy and the Specter of Inverted Totalitarianism. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-13566-3. (Trad. esp.: Democracia S. A., Buenos Aires/Madrid, Katz editores S.A, 2008, ISBN 978-84-96859-46-3)
- Zullo, Roland. (2009). Does Fiscal Stress Induce Privatization? Correlates of Private and Intermunicipal Contracting, 1992–2002. Governance 22.3 (July): 459–481.
External links
- Privatization's Rise from the Dean Peter Krogh Foreign Affairs Digital Archives
- Reports of the Public Services International Research Unit at the University of Greenwich Research database with many articles on the effects of privatization
- Parker, David (1991). "Privatisation ten years on : a critical analysis of its rationale and results". Cranfield CERES. Cranfield University, School of Management. hdl:1826/606.
Property | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
By owner | |||||
By nature | |||||
Commons | |||||
Theory | |||||
Applications |
| ||||
Disposession/ redistribution | |||||
Scholars (key work) | |||||
|