Misplaced Pages

Gresham's law: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 23:12, 17 March 2013 edit124.197.41.101 (talk) 'Good' money and 'bad' money← Previous edit Latest revision as of 02:56, 20 December 2024 edit undoSrich32977 (talk | contribs)Autopatrolled, Extended confirmed users, New page reviewers, Pending changes reviewers, Rollbackers299,749 edits Adding/improving reference(s) 
(365 intermediate revisions by more than 100 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Monetary principle – "bad money drives out good"}}
'''Gresham's law''' is an ] principle that states: "When a government compulsorily overvalues one type of money and undervalues another, the undervalued money will leave the country or disappear from circulation into hoards, while the overvalued money will flood into circulation."<ref>], , '']''</ref> It is commonly stated as: "Bad money drives out good", but is more accurately stated: "Bad money drives out good if their exchange rate is set by law."
{{Redirect|Good money|the banking platform|Good Money}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=March 2020}}
]]]


In ], '''Gresham's law''' is a monetary principle stating that "bad money drives out good". For example, if there are two forms of ] in circulation, which are accepted by law as having similar ], the more valuable commodity will gradually disappear from circulation.<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |url=http://www.britannica.com/topic/Greshams-law |title=Gresham's law – economics |publisher=Encyclopædia Britannica |access-date=8 April 2018}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.investopedia.com/terms/g/greshams-law.asp |title=Gresham's Law |author=Investopedia Staff |date=9 February 2010 |website=Investopedia |access-date=8 April 2018}}</ref>
This law applies specifically when there are two forms of ] in circulation which are required by ] laws to be accepted as having similar ]s for economic transactions. The artificially overvalued money tends to drive an artificially undervalued money out of circulation<ref>http://mises.org/money/3s5.asp</ref> and is a consequence of ].


The law was named in 1857 by economist ] after Sir ] (1519–1579), an English ] during the ].<ref>{{cite book |last= Macleod|first= Henry Dunning |author-link = Henry Dunning Macleod |title= The History of Economics |year= 1896 |place= London |publisher= Bliss, Sands and Co.|url= https://archive.org/stream/historyofeconomi00macliala#page/n5/mode/2up |pages= -39; ; – |accessdate= 7 December 2023|via= Internet Archive}}</ref> Gresham had urged Queen Elizabeth to restore confidence in then-] English currency.
The law was named in 1858 by ], after Sir ] (1519–1579), who was an English ] during the ]. However, there are numerous predecessors. The law had been stated forty years earlier by ]; for this reason, it is occasionally known as the '''Copernicus Law''';<ref name="Haski2005">{{cite book|author=Stan Haski|title=The Arrogance of Distance|url=http://books.google.com/books?id=NG0nhM0iWggC&pg=PA317|accessdate=16 March 2013|date=14 November 2005|publisher=iUniverse|isbn=978-0-595-81137-3|pages=317–}}</ref><ref name="Measurement of Co-Circulation of Currencies">{{cite book|title=Measurement of Co-Circulation of Currencies|url=http://books.google.com/books?id=5XvPv3vWdSQC&pg=PT61|accessdate=16 March 2013|publisher=International Monetary Fund|isbn=978-1-4552-9991-1|page=61}}</ref> in the 14th&nbsp;century, by ]<!--who was he and did he do it?-->;{{fact|date=March 2013}} and by jurist and historian ] (1364–1442) in the ]<!--when exactly did he do it?-->;<ref>{{cite book|last=Baeck|first=Louis|title=The Mediterranean Tradition in Economic Thought|year=1994|publisher=Routledge|location=New York, NY|isbn=0-415-09301-5|pages=241|pages=105–106}}</ref> and noted by ] in his play '']'', which dates from around the end of the 5th&nbsp;century BC.{{fact|date=March 2013}}


The concept was thoroughly defined in Renaissance Europe by ] and known centuries earlier in classical Antiquity, the Near East, and China.
==.


== "Good money" and "bad money" ==
==Examples==
Under Gresham's law, "good money" is money that shows little difference between its nominal value (the face value of the coin) and its ] (the value of the metal of which it is made, often ]s, such as ] or ]).<ref name=":0">{{Cite web |last=Wooldridge |first=Leslie Quander |title=Fiat money: Currencies that derive their value largely through trust in the governments that issue them |url=https://www.businessinsider.com/personal-finance/fiat-money |access-date=2023-10-05 |website=Business Insider |language=en-US}}</ref>
] coins were widely circulated in ] (until 1968) and in the ] (until 1964 for ] and ] and 1969 for ]). However, these countries ] their coins by switching to cheaper metals as the market value of silver rose above that of the face value. The silver coins disappeared from circulation as citizens retained them to capture the higher current or perceived future intrinsic value of the metal content over their face value, using the newer coins in daily transactions. In the late 1970s, the ] attempted to ] the worldwide silver market but failed, temporarily driving the price far above its historic levels and intensifying the extraction of silver coins from circulation.<REF NAME="TEXAS">{{cite journal
| last = Gwynne
| first = S. C.
| title = Bunker HUNT
| journal = Texas Monthly
| volume = 29
| issue = 9
| pages = p78
| publisher = Emmis Communications Corporation
| location = Austin, Texas, United States
| date = September 2001
| url =
| accessdate = }}</ref> The same process occurs today with the copper content of coins such as the pre-1997 ], the pre-1982 ] and the pre-1992 UK copper pennies and two pence.
This also occurred even with coins made of less expensive metals such as ] in India.<ref> "Sharp practice of melting coins" – BBC News (accessed 30 May 2009)</ref>


The ] between ] and commodity value when it is minted is called ]. As some coins do not circulate, remaining in the possession of ], this can increase demand for coinage.
==Theory==
Gresham's law states that any circulating currency consisting of both "good" and "bad" money (both forms required to be accepted at equal value under legal tender law) quickly becomes dominated by the "bad" money. This is because people spending money will hand over the "bad" coins rather than the "good" ones, keeping the "good" ones for themselves.
Legal tender laws act as a form of price control. In such a case, the artificially overvalued money is preferred in exchange, because people prefer to save rather than exchange the artificially demoted one (which they actually value higher).


On the other hand, "bad money" is money that has a commodity value considerably lower than its face value and is in circulation along with good money, where both forms are required to be accepted at equal value as legal tender.
Consider a customer purchasing an item which costs five ], who possesses several silver ] coins. Some of these coins are more debased, while others are less so—but legally, they are all mandated to be of equal value. The customer would prefer to retain the better coins, and so offers the shopkeeper the most debased one. In turn, the shopkeeper must give one penny in change, and has every reason to give the most debased penny. Thus, the coins that circulate in the transaction will tend to be of the most debased sort available to the parties.


In Gresham's day, bad money included any ] that had been debased. ] was often done by the issuing body, where less than the officially specified amount of precious metal was contained in an issue of coinage, usually by ]ing it with a ]. The public could also debase coins, usually by ] or scraping off small portions of the precious metal, also known as "stemming" (] on coins were intended to make clipping evident). Other examples of bad money include ] coins made from base metal. Today virtually all circulating coins are made from base metals, often the cheapest available, durable base metal; collectively these monies are known as ]. While virtually all contemporary coinage is composed solely of base metals, there have been periods during the 21st century in which the market value of some base metals, like copper, have been high enough that at least one common coin (the U.S. ]) still maintained "good money" status.<ref name=":0" />
If "good" coins have a face value below that of their metallic content, individuals may be motivated to melt them down and sell the metal for its higher intrinsic value, even if such destruction is illegal. As an example, consider the 1965 ]s, which contained 40% ]. In previous years, these coins were 90% silver. With the release of the 1965 half dollar, which was legally required to be accepted at the same value as the earlier 90% halves, the older 90% silver coinage quickly disappeared from circulation, while the newer debased coins remained in use. As the price of bullion silver continued to rise above the face value of the coins, many of the older half dollars were melted down. Beginning in 1971, the U.S. government gave up on including any silver in the half dollars, as even the metal value of the 40% silver coins began to exceed their face value.


In the case of clipped, scraped, or counterfeit coins, the commodity value was reduced by fraud. The face value remains at the previous higher level. On the other hand, with a coinage debased by a government issuer, the commodity value of the coinage was often reduced quite openly, while the face value of the debased coins was held at the higher level by legal tender laws.
A similar situation occurred in 2007 in the United States with the rising price of ] and ], which led the U.S. government to ban the melting or mass exportation of ] and ] coins.


The old saying, "a bad penny always turns up" is a colloquial recognition of Gresham's law.
In addition to being melted down for its bullion value, money that is considered to be "good" tends to leave an economy through international trade. International traders are not bound by legal tender laws as citizens of the issuing country are, so they will offer higher value for good coins than bad ones. The good coins may leave their country of origin to become part of international trade, escaping that country's legal tender laws and leaving the "bad" money behind. This occurred in Britain during the period of the ].


== Theory ==
==History of the concept==
The law states that any circulating currency consisting of both "good" and "bad" money (both forms required to be accepted at equal value under legal tender law) quickly becomes dominated by the "bad" money. This is because people spending money will hand over the "bad" coins rather than the "good" ones, keeping the "good" ones for themselves. Legal tender laws act as a form of price control. In such a case, the intrinsically less valuable money is preferred in exchange, because people prefer to save the intrinsically more valuable money.
The law was named after ], a sixteenth century financial agent of the English Crown in the city of Antwerp, to explain to ] what was happening to the English shilling. Her father, ], had replaced 40 percent of the silver in the coin with base metals, to increase the government’s income without raising taxes. Astute English merchants and even ordinary subjects would save the good shillings from pure silver and circulate the bad ones; hence, the bad money would be used whenever possible, and the good coinage would be saved and disappear from circulation.


Imagine that a customer with several silver ] coins purchases an item which costs five ]. Some of the customer's coins are more debased, while others are less so – but legally, they are all mandated to be of equal value. The customer would prefer to retain the better coins, and so offers the shopkeeper the most debased one. In turn, the shopkeeper must give one penny in change, and has every reason to give the most debased penny. Thus, the coins that circulate in the transaction will tend to be of the most debased sort available to the parties.
Gresham was not the first to state the law which took his name. The phenomenon had been noted much earlier, in the 14th century, by ]. In the year that Gresham was born, 1519, it was described by ] in a ] called '']'': "bad (debased) coinage drives good (un-debased) coinage out of circulation." Copernicus was aware of the practice of exchanging bad coins for good ones and melting down the latter or sending them abroad, and he seems to have drawn up some notes on this subject while he was at ] in 1519. He made them the basis of a report in ] which he presented to the ] held in 1522 at ], attending the session with his friend ] to represent his chapter. Copernicus's ''Monetae cudendae ratio'' was an enlarged, ] version of that report, setting forth a general theory of money for the 1528 diet. He also formulated a version of the quantity theory of money.<ref>Angus Armitage, ''The World of Copernicus'', chapter 24: 'The Diseases of Money', pp. 89-91</ref>


]s (left), which contain 90% silver. In an example of Gresham's law, these coins were quickly hoarded by the public after the ] debased half dollars to contain only 40% silver, and then were debased entirely in 1971 to base ] (right).]]
According to the economist ] in his paper "Gresham's Law":


If "good" coins have a face value below that of their metallic content, individuals may be motivated to melt them down and sell the metal for its higher intrinsic value, even if such destruction is illegal. The 1965 ]s contained 40% silver; in previous years these coins were 90% silver (.900, or ''one nine ]''). With the release of the 1965 half-dollar, which was legally required to be accepted at the same value as the earlier 90% halves, the older 90% silver coinage quickly disappeared from circulation, while the newer debased coins remained in use.{{citation needed|date=May 2014}} As the value of the dollar (Federal Reserve notes) continued to decline, resulting in the value of the silver content exceeding the face value of the coins, many of the older half dollars were melted down{{citation needed|date=May 2014}} or removed from circulation and into private collections and hoards. Beginning in 1971, the U.S. government abandoned including any silver in half dollars. The metal value of the 40% silver coins began to exceed their face value, which resulted in a repeat of the previous event. The 40% silver coins also began to vanish from circulation and into coin hoards.
{{quote|As for Gresham himself, he observed "that good and bad coin cannot circulate together" in a letter written to ] on the occasion of her accession in 1558. The statement was part of Gresham's explanation for the "unexampled state of badness" England's coinage had been left in following the "Great Debasements" of ] and ], which reduced the metallic value of English silver coins to a small fraction of what it had been at the time of ]. It was owing to these debasements, Gresham observed to the Queen, that "all your fine gold was convayed out of this your realm."<ref name="eh.net"> "Gresham's Law" – EH.net (accessed 30 May 2009)</ref>}}


A similar situation occurred in 2007 in the United States with the rising price of ], ], and ], which led the U.S. government to ban the melting or mass exportation of ] and ] coins.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.usmint.gov/pressroom/index.cfm?flash=yes&action=press_release&ID=771 |title=News – U.S. Mint |website=www.usmint.gov |access-date=8 April 2018 |archive-date=12 September 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160912231117/http://www.usmint.gov/pressroom/index.cfm?flash=yes&action=press_release&ID=771 |url-status=dead }}</ref>
This notion was also developed during the time of the Mamluk Empire, as noted above.{{Citation needed|date=November 2012}}


In addition to being melted down for its bullion value, money that is considered to be "good" tends to leave an economy through international trade. International traders are not bound by legal tender laws as citizens of the issuing country are, so they will offer higher value for good coins than bad ones. The good coins may leave their country of origin to become part of international trade, escaping that country's legal tender laws and leaving the "bad" money behind. This occurred in Britain during the period of adoption of the ]: In 1717 ], then Master of the Mint, declared the gold guinea to be worth 21 silver shillings. This overvalued the gold guinea in Britain, making it "bad", and encouraged people to send "good" silver shillings abroad, where it could buy more gold than at home. This gold was then minted as currency, which bought silver shillings, which were sent abroad for gold, and so on. For a century hardly any silver coins were minted in Britain, and Britain moved onto a ''de facto'' gold standard.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Fray |first=C R |date=1935 |title=Newton and the Gold Standard |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/3020836 |journal=Cambridge Historical Journal |volume=5 |issue=1 |pages=109–117 |doi=10.1017/S1474691300001256 |jstor=3020836 }}</ref>
Gresham made his observations of good and bad money while in the service of Queen Elizabeth, with respect only to the observed poor quality of British coinage. The earlier monarchs, Henry VIII and Edward VI, had forced the people to accept debased coinage by means of their legal tender laws. Gresham also made his comparison of good and bad money where the precious metal in the money was the same metal, but of different weight. He did not compare silver to gold, or gold to paper.


] ] said that "so-called Gresham's law" only applies under certain conditions, largely a result of governmental interventionist policies. In his 2021 book, '']'' Hoppe states:<blockquote>You might have heard about the so-called Gresham's law, which states that bad money drives out good money, but this law only holds if there are price controls in effect, only if the exchange ratios of different monies are fixed and no longer reflect market forces. Is it the case that bad money drives out good money under normal circumstances without any interference? No, for money holds to exactly the same law that holds for every other good. Good goods drive out bad goods. Good money drives out bad money, so this ] was for something like 800 years considered to be the best money available and was preferred by merchants from India to Rome to the Baltic Sea.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Hoppe |first=Hans-Hermann |title=Economy, Society, and History |publisher=Mises Institute |year=2021 |isbn=978-1-61016-734-5 |location=Auburn, AL |page=49}}</ref></blockquote>
===Origin of the name===
In his "Gresham's Law" article, Selgin also offers the following comments regarding the origin of the name:


== History of the concept ==
{{quote|The expression "Gresham's Law" dates back only to 1858, when British economist ] (1858, p. 476–8) decided to name the tendency for bad money to drive good money out of circulation after Sir Thomas Gresham (1519–1579). However, references to such a tendency, sometimes accompanied by discussion of conditions promoting it, occur in various medieval writings, most notably Nicholas Oresme's (c. 1357) ''Treatise on money''. The concept can be traced to ancient works, including ]' ''The Frogs'', where the prevalence of bad politicians is attributed to forces similar to those favoring bad money over good.<ref name="eh.net"/>}}
Gresham was not the first to state the law which took his name. The phenomenon had been noted by ] in his play '']'', which dates from around the end of the 5th century ]. The referenced passage from '']'' is as follows (usually dated at 405 BCE):<ref name="frogs">{{cite book |author1=Aristophanes |title=The Frogs (tr. Gilbert Murray) |year=1908 |page= |url=https://archive.org/details/frogstranslatedi00arisuoft |access-date=17 April 2019 |publisher=George Allen & Sons |location=London}}</ref>


{{poemquote|It has often struck our notice that the course our city runs
The referenced passage from '']'' is as follows (usually dated at 405 BC):{{Citation needed|date=November 2012}}
Is the same towards men and money. She has true and worthy sons:
She has good and ancient silver, she has good and recent gold.
These are coins untouched with alloys; everywhere their fame is told;
Not all Hellas holds their equal, not all Barbary far and near.
Gold or silver, each well minted, tested each and ringing clear.
Yet, we never use them! Others always pass from hand to hand.
Sorry brass just struck last week and branded with a wretched brand.
So with men we know for upright, blameless lives and noble names.
Trained in music and palaestra, freemen's choirs and freemen's games,
These we spurn for men of brass...}}


According to Ben Tamari, the currency devaluation phenomenon was already recognized in ancient sources.<ref name="Tamari">Originally published as {{cite journal|last1=Tamari|first1=Ben|date=1982|script-title=he:חוק גרשם ופרדוקס החסכון |trans-title=Gresham's Law and the Savings Paradox|journal=רבעון לכלכלה|volume=115|access-date=15 March 2012|url=http://www.bentamari.com/PicturesEcometry/articals02-GreshamLawEn.pdf|language=he}} translated and updated in 2011 at {{cite web|url=http://www.bentamari.com/PicturesEcometry/articals02-GreshamLawEn.pdf|title=Gresham's Law|first=Ben|last=Tamar|others=Translated by Liat Etta|date=July 2011|access-date=15 March 2012}}</ref> He brings some examples which include the ] transaction<ref>{{bibleverse||Genesis|23:16|HE}}</ref> and the building of the ]<ref>{{bibleverse|1|Kings|10:21|HE}}</ref> from the Bible and the Mishna in tractate Bava Metzia (]) from the ].<ref name = "Tamari" />
{{quote|The course our city runs is the same towards men and money.


In China, ] economic authors ] and ] (c. 1223) were aware of the same phenomenon.<ref>{{cite book|title=Forty Centuries of Wage and Price Controls: How Not To Fight Inflation|first1=Robert L.|last1=Shuettinger|first2=Eamonn F.|last2=Butler|place=Thornwood, NY|publisher=The Heritage Foundation|year=1979|page=14|isbn= 0-89195-023-0}}</ref>
She has true and worthy sons.


] (1263–1328) described the phenomenon as follows:
She has fine new gold and ancient silver,


{{blockquote|If the ruler cancels the use of a certain coin and mints another kind of money for the people, he will spoil the riches (amwal) which they possess, by decreasing their value as the old coins will now become merely a commodity. He will do injustice to them by depriving them of the higher values originally owned by them. Moreover, if the intrinsic values of coins are different it will become a source of profit for the wicked to collect the small (bad) coins and exchange them (for good money) and then they will take them to another country and shift the small (bad) money of that country (to this country). So (the value of) people's goods will be damaged.}}
Coins untouched with alloys, gold or silver,


Notably this passage mentions only the flight of good money abroad and says nothing of its disappearance due to hoarding or melting.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.islamic-world.net/economics/ibn_taimiyyah.htm|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20040316133009/http://www.islamic-world.net/economics/ibn_taimiyyah.htm|url-status=dead|archive-date=16 March 2004|title=Economic Concepts of Ibn Taimiyyah|date=16 March 2004|access-date=8 April 2018}}</ref> Palestinian economist Adel Zagha also attributes a similar concept to medieval Islamic thinker ], who offered, claims Zagha, a close approximation to what would become known as Gresham's law centuries later.<ref>. ].</ref>
Each well minted, tested each and ringing clear.


In the 14th century it was noted by ] {{circa|1350}},<ref name="ReferenceA">Woods, Thomas E. ''How The Catholic Church Built Western Civilization''.</ref>{{full citation needed|date=November 2022}} in his treatise ''On the Origin, Nature, Law, and Alterations of Money'',<ref name="Durant 1957 252">{{cite book |last=Durant |first=Will |title=The Reformation |series=] |volume=6 |publisher=] |year=1957 |page=252}}</ref> and by jurist and historian ] (1364–1442) in the ]<!--when exactly did he do it?-->.<ref>{{cite book|last=Baeck|first=Louis|title=The Mediterranean Tradition in Economic Thought|date=1994|publisher=Routledge|location=New York|isbn=0-415-09301-5<!-- |page=241 -->|pages=105–106}}</ref>
Yet we never use them!


Johannes de Strigys, an agent of ] in ], wrote in a June 1472 report {{lang|it|che la cativa cazarà via la bona}} ("that the bad money will chase out the good").<ref>{{cite book|author=Fernand Braudel|title=La Méditerranée et le monde méditerranéen à l'époque de Philippe II, Volume 2: Destins collectifs et mouvements d'ensemble|language=fr|date=1966|location=Paris|publisher=Armand Colin|page=41}}</ref>
Others pass from hand to hand,


In the year that Gresham was born, 1519, it was described by ] in a ] called {{lang|la|italic=yes|]}}: "bad (debased) coinage drives good (un-debased) coinage out of circulation". Copernicus was aware of the practice of exchanging bad coins for good ones and melting down the latter or sending them abroad, and he seems to have drawn up some notes on this subject while he was at ] in 1519. He made them the basis of a report which he presented to the ] held in 1522, attending the session with his friend ] to represent his chapter. Copernicus's {{lang|la|italic=yes|Monetae cudendae ratio}} was an enlarged, ] version of that report, setting forth a general theory of money for the 1528 diet. He also formulated a version of the ].<ref name="Angus Armitage pp. 89">Angus Armitage, ''The World of Copernicus'', chapter 24: "The Diseases of Money", pp. 89–91</ref> For this reason, it is occasionally known as the Gresham–Copernicus law.<ref name="Measurement of Co-Circulation of Currencies">{{cite book |title=Measurement of Co-Circulation of Currencies |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=5XvPv3vWdSQC&pg=PT61 |access-date=16 March 2013 |publisher=International Monetary Fund |isbn=978-1-4552-9991-1 |page=61 |date=1995}}</ref>
Sorry brass just struck last week and branded with a wretched brand.


Sir ], a 16th century financial agent of the English Crown in the city of Antwerp, was one in a long series of proponents of the law, which he did to explain to ] what was happening to the English shilling. Her father, ], had replaced 40% of the silver in the coin with base metals, to increase the government's income without raising taxes. Astute English merchants and ordinary subjects saved the good shillings from pure silver and circulated the bad ones. Hence, the bad money would be used whenever possible, and the good coinage would be saved and disappear from circulation.
So with men we know for upright, blameless lives and noble names.


According to the economist ] in his paper "Gresham's Law":
These we spurn for men of brass...}}


{{blockquote|As for Gresham himself, he observed "that good and bad coin cannot circulate together" in a letter written to Queen Elizabeth on the occasion of her accession in 1558. The statement was part of Gresham's explanation for the "unexampled state of badness" that England's coinage had been left in following the "Great Debasements" of Henry VIII and ], which reduced the metallic value of English silver coins to a small fraction of what it had been at the time of Henry VII. Owing to these debasements, Gresham observed to the Queen, that "all your fine gold was convayed out of this your realm".<ref name="eh.net">{{cite web |url=http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/selgin.gresham.law |title=Gresham's Law |website=EH.net |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130317073119/http://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/selgin.gresham.law |archive-date=2013-03-17}}</ref>}}
=== Precursors ===
According to Ben Tamari, the currency devaluation phenomenon was already recognized in ancient sources.<ref name = "Tamari">Originally published as {{cite journal
| last1 = Tamari
| first1 = Ben
| year = 1982
| title = {{lang|he|חוק גרשם ופרדוקס החסכון}}
| trans_title = Gresham’s Law and the Savings Paradox
| journal = {{lang|he|רבעון לכלכלה}}
| volume = 115
| language = {{He icon}}
| format = PDF
| accessdate = March 15, 2012
| url = http://www.bentamari.com/PicturesEcometry/articals02-GreshemLaw.pdf
}} translated and updated in 2011 at {{cite web
| url = http://www.bentamari.com/PicturesEcometry/articals02-GreshamLawEn.pdf
| title = Gresham’s Law
| first = Ben
| last = Tamari
| others = Translated by Liat Etta
| month = July
| year = 2011
| format = PDF
| accessdate = March 15, 2012
}}
</ref> He brings some examples which include the Machpela Cave transaction ({{bibleverse||Genesis|23:16|HE}}) and the building of the Temple ({{bibleverse|1|Kings|10:21|HE}}) from the Bible and the Mishna in tractate Bava Metzia (]) from the Talmud.<ref name = "Tamari" />


Gresham made his observations of good and bad money while in the service of Queen Elizabeth, with respect only to the observed poor quality of British coinage. Earlier monarchs, Henry VIII and Edward VI, had forced the people to accept debased coinage by means of legal tender laws. Gresham also made his comparison of good and bad money where the precious metal in the money was the same metal, but of different weight. He did not compare silver to gold, or gold to paper.
] (1263–1328) described the phenomenon as follows:

{{quote|If the ruler cancels the use of a certain coin and mints another kind of money for the people, he will spoil the riches (amwal) which they possess, by decreasing their value as the old coins will now become merely a commodity. He will do injustice to them by depriving them of the higher values originally owned by them. Moreover, if the intrinsic value of coins are different it will become a source of profit for the wicked to collect the small (bad) coins and exchange them (for good money) and then they will take them to another country and shift the small (bad) money of that country (to this country). So (the value of) people's goods will be damaged.}}
In his "Gresham's Law" article, Selgin also offers the following comments regarding the origin of the name:
Notably this passage mentions only the flight of good money abroad and says nothing of its disappearance due to hoarding or melting.<ref></ref>

{{blockquote|The expression "Gresham's Law" dates back only to 1858, when British economist ] (1858, pp. 476–8) decided to name the tendency for bad money to drive good money out of circulation after Sir Thomas Gresham (1519–1579). However, references to such a tendency, sometimes accompanied by discussion of conditions promoting it, occur in various medieval writings, most notably Nicholas Oresme's (c. 1357) ''Treatise on money''. The concept can be traced to ancient works, including ]' ''The Frogs'', where the prevalence of bad politicians is attributed to forces similar to those favoring bad money over good.<ref name="eh.net"/>}}

==Reverse of Gresham's law (Thiers' law)==

The experiences of ] in countries with weak economies and currencies (such as ] in the 1980s, ] and countries in the period immediately after the collapse of the ], or ] throughout the late 20th and early 21st century) may be seen as Gresham's law operating in its reverse form (Guidotti & Rodriguez, 1992) because in general, the dollar has not been legal tender in such situations, and in some cases, its use has been illegal.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Bernholz |first=Peter |date=March 31, 2011 |title=Understanding Early Monetary Developments by Applying Economic Laws: The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments, Gresham's and Thiers' Laws |url=https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1799983#:~:text=By%20contrast%2C%20Thiers%27%20Law%20%28a%20name%20coined%20by,good%20money%20will%20drive%20out%20the%20bad%20one. |journal=SSRN |doi=10.2139/ssrn.1799983 |ssrn=1799983 |s2cid=152412531 }}</ref>

] and ] (in his book {{lang|it|Le vicende del marco tedesco}}, published in 1931) pointed out that, during the great ] in 1923,{{dubious|text=Gresham's Law began to work in reverse|This is apples and oranges, as Gresham's law referred to ''specie'', whereas this compares printed currency – by definition fiat money – with minted coins with some intrinsic metal value.|date=January 2022}} as the official money became so worthless that virtually nobody would take it, people simply stopped accepting the currency in exchange for goods. That was particularly serious because farmers began to hoard food. Accordingly, any currency backed by any sort of value became a circulating medium of exchange.<ref>{{cite book |url=http://mises.org/resources/4016 |first=Adam |last=Fergusson |title=When Money Dies: The Nightmare of the Weimar Collapse |chapter=12: The Bottom of the Abyss |publisher=Ludwig von Mises Institute |year=1975 |access-date=29 November 2009 |archive-date=24 March 2010 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100324032949/http://mises.org/resources/4016 |url-status=dead }}</ref> In 2009, ] began to show similar characteristics.


Those examples show that in the absence of effective legal tender laws, Gresham's law works in reverse. If given the choice of what money to accept, people will accept the money they believe to be of highest long-term value, and not accept what they believe to be of low long-term value. If not given the choice and required to accept all money, good and bad, they will tend to keep the money of greater perceived value in their own possession and pass the bad money to others.
==Reverse of Gresham's Law (Thiers' Law)==
In an influential theoretical article, Rolnick and Weber (1986) argued that bad money would drive good money to a premium rather than driving it out of circulation. However, their research did not take into account the context in which Gresham made his observation. Rolnick and Weber ignored the influence of legal tender legislation which requires people to accept both good and bad money as if they were of equal value. They also focused mainly on the interaction between different metallic monies, comparing the relative "goodness" of silver to that of gold, which is not what Gresham was speaking of.


In short, in the absence of legal tender laws, the seller will not accept anything but money of certain value (good money), but the existence of legal tender laws will cause the buyer to offer only money with the lowest commodity value (bad money), as the creditor must accept such money at face value.<ref name="Rowe">{{cite web |url=http://worthwhile.typepad.com/worthwhile_canadian_initi/2009/07/the-states-theory-of-money-california-and-canadian-tire.html |title=The State(s) Theory of Money: California and Canadian Tire |last=Rowe |first=Nick |date=2009-07-14 |work=Worthwhile Canadian Initiative |access-date=2009-07-16}}</ref>{{unreliable source?|reason=blog posts are generally not ]|date=November 2022}}
The experiences of ] in countries with weak economies and currencies (for example ] in the 1980s, ] and countries in the period immediately after the collapse of the ], or ]n countries throughout the late 20th and early 21st century) may be seen as Gresham's Law operating in its reverse form (Guidotti & Rodriguez, 1992), since in general the dollar has not been legal tender in such situations, and in some cases its use has been illegal.


Nobel Prize winner ] believes that Gresham's law could be more accurately rendered, taking care of the reverse, if it were expressed as: "Bad money drives out good ''if they exchange for the same price''."<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.columbia.edu/~ram15/grash.html |title=Uses and Abuses of Gresham's Law in the History of Money |first=Robert |last=Mundell |publisher=Columbia University |date=August 1998 |access-date=10 October 2009 |archive-date=11 January 2012 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120111131003/http://www.columbia.edu/~ram15/grash.html |url-status=dead }}</ref>
] pointed out that in 1923 during the great ] Gresham's Law began to work in reverse, since the official money became so worthless that virtually nobody would take it. This was particularly serious since farmers began to hoard food. Accordingly, any currencies backed by any sorts of value became the circulating mediums of exchange.<ref></ref> In 2009 ] began to show similar characteristics.


The reverse of Gresham's law, that good money drives out bad money whenever the bad money becomes nearly worthless, has been named "Thiers' law" by economist Peter Bernholz in honor of French politician and historian ].<ref>Peter Bernholz (2003), ''Monetary Regimes and Inflation'', pp. 41, 115, 132, Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton, Massachusetts, {{ISBN|978-1-84542-778-8}}</ref> "Thiers' Law will only operate later when the increase of the new flexible exchange rate and of the rate of inflation lower the real demand for the inflating money."<ref>Bernholz, p. 132</ref>
These examples show that in the absence of effective legal tender laws, Gresham's Law works in reverse. If given the choice of what money to accept, people will transact with money they believe to be of highest long-term value. However, if not given the choice, and required to accept all money, good and bad, they will tend to keep the money of greater perceived value in their possession, and pass on the bad money to someone else. In short, in the absence of legal tender laws, the seller will not accept anything but money of certain value (good money), while the existence of legal tender laws will cause the buyer to offer only money with the lowest commodity value (bad money) as the creditor must accept such money at face value.<ref name="Rowe">{{cite web|url=http://worthwhile.typepad.com/worthwhile_canadian_initi/2009/07/the-states-theory-of-money-california-and-canadian-tire.html |title=The State(s) Theory of Money: California and Canadian Tire|last=Rowe |first=Nick |date=2009-07-14|work=Worthwhile Canadian Initiative|accessdate=2009-07-16}}</ref>


==Analogs in other fields==
The Nobel prize-winner ] believes that Gresham's Law could be more accurately rendered, taking care of the reverse, if it were expressed as, "Bad money drives out good ''if they exchange for the same price''."<ref>"Uses and Abuses of Gresham's Law in the History of Money", Robert Mundell, Columbia University (August 1998)</ref>
The principles of Gresham's law can sometimes be applied to different fields of study. Gresham's law may be generally applied to any circumstance in which the true value of something is markedly different from the value people are required to accept, due to factors such as lack of information or governmental decree.


Vice President ] used Gresham's law in describing American ], stating that "Bad news drives out good news", although his argument was closer to that of a ] for higher ratings rather than over- and under-valuing certain kinds of news.<ref>] (13 November 1969). . Des Moines, Iowa – via American Rhetoric.</ref>
The reverse of Gresham's Law, that good money drives out bad money whenever the bad money becomes nearly worthless, has been named "Thiers' Law" by economist Peter Bernholz, in honor of French politician and historian ].<ref>''Monetary Regimes and Inflation'', pages 41, 115, 132, Peter Bernholz, 2003, Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton, Massachusetts, ISBN 978-1-84542-778-8</ref> "Thiers' Law will only operate later when the increase of the new flexible exchange rate and of the rate of inflation lower the real demand for the inflating money."<ref>Bernholz, page 132</ref>


] postulated an analogue to Gresham's law operating in cultural evolution, in which "the oversimplified ideas will always displace the sophisticated and the vulgar and hateful will always displace the beautiful. And yet the beautiful persists."<ref>Gregory Bateson, ''Mind and Nature: A Necessary Unity'' 6 (1979).</ref>
==Application==
The principles of Gresham's law can sometimes be applied to different fields of study. Gresham's law may be generally applied to any circumstance in which the "true" value of something is markedly different from the value people are required to accept, due to factors such as lack of information or governmental decree.


] wrote that a similar effect to Gresham's law occurred in ] trading. The alleged information asymmetry is that people find it difficult to distinguish just how effective credits purchased are, but can easily tell the price. As a result, cheap credits that are ineffective can displace expensive but worthwhile carbon credits.<ref>{{cite web| url = https://pluralistic.net/2020/12/12/fairy-use-tale/#greenwashing| title = Carbon offsets are bullshit |last=Doctorow |first=Cory |work=Pluralistic |date=12 December 2020}}</ref> The example given was ] offering cheap, yet "meaningless", carbon credits by purchasing cheap land unlikely to be logged anyway, rather than expensive and valuable land at risk of logging.<ref>{{cite news| url = https://www.bloomberg.com/features/2020-nature-conservancy-carbon-offsets-trees/| title = These Trees Are Not What They Seem: How the Nature Conservancy, the world's biggest environmental group, became a dealer of meaningless carbon offsets| newspaper = Bloomberg |first=Ben |last=Elgin
In the market for ]s, ] (analogous to bad currency) will drive out the good cars.<ref>Phlips, Louis. '''', 1983. p. 239.</ref> The problem is one of asymmetry of information. Sellers have a strong financial incentive to pass all used cars off as "good" cars, especially lemons. This makes it difficult to buy a good car at a fair price, as the buyer risks overpaying for a lemon. The result is that buyers will only pay the fair price of a lemon, so at least they reduce the risk of overpaying. High-quality cars tend to be pushed out of the market, because there is no good way to establish that they really are worth more. ] programs are an attempt to mitigate this problem by providing a ] and other guarantees of quality. "]" is a work that examines this problem in more detail.
|date=9 December 2020}}</ref>
Some also use an explanation of Gresham's Law as "The more efficient you become, the less effective you get"; i.e. "when you try to go on the cheap, you will stop selling" or "the less you invest in your non-tangible services, the fewer sales you will get".


A corollary, Hughes' law, exists in moral philosophy, stating that, "The evil acts of bad men elicit from better men acts which, under better circumstances, would also be called evil."<ref>{{cite book| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=ugwYEAAAQBAJ&pg=PT77| title = Ethical Universe: the Vectors of Evil Vs. Good: Secular Ethics for the 21st Century|last=McAlister |first=John W. |work=ISBN : 9781665511919 |date=14 January 2021| publisher = AuthorHouse| isbn = 9781665511919}}</ref>
Vice President ] used Gresham's law in describing American ], stating that "Bad news drives out good news," although his argument was closer to that of a ] for higher ratings rather than over and undervaluing certain kinds of news.<ref>"" 13 November 1969, Des Moines, Iowa</ref>


In the market for ]s, ] (analogous to bad currency) will drive out the good cars.<ref>Phlips, Louis (1983). . p. 239.</ref> The problem is one of asymmetry of information. Sellers have a strong financial incentive to pass all used cars off as good cars, especially lemons. This makes it difficult to buy a good car at a fair price, as the buyer risks overpaying for a lemon. The result is that buyers will only pay the fair price of a lemon, so at least they reduce the risk of overpaying. High-quality cars tend to be pushed out of the market, because there is no good way to establish that they really are worth more. ] programs are an attempt to mitigate this problem by providing a ] and other guarantees of quality. '']'' is a work that examines this problem in more detail.
Gresham's law has been cited as "Silver currency will inevitably force gold currency out of circulation" (L. Pyenson, Servants of Nature (W.W. Norton, 1999) p.&nbsp;21); this suggests a fundamental misinterpretation, cf. Mundell (above).


==See also== ==See also==
{{cols}}
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ], coins collected specifically for the value of their silver content
* ] * ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ]
* ]
{{colend}}


==Notes== ==Notes==
{{Reflist|2}} {{reflist}}


==References== ==References==
*Armitage, Angus, ''The World of Copernicus'', New York, Mentor Books, 1951. * Armitage, Angus, ''The World of Copernicus'', New York, Mentor Books, 1951.
* Bernholz, Peter and Gersbach, Hans, "Gresham's Law: Theory." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, vol. 2. Macmillan: London and Basingstoke 1992, 286–288.
*], (1950) ''Science, the Endless Frontier'', Report from the Director of the OSRD to President H. Truman
* ], (1950) ''Science, the Endless Frontier'', Report from the Director of the OSRD to President H. Truman
*Guidotti, P. E., & Rodriguez, C. A. (1992). Dollarization in Latin America – Gresham law in reverse. ''International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, 39'', 518-544.
* Guidotti, P.E., & Rodriguez, C.A. (1992). Dollarization in Latin America – Gresham law in reverse. ''] Staff Papers, 39'', 518–544.
*{{cite journal |last=Rolnick |first=A. J. |authorlink= |coauthors=Weber, W. E. |year=1986 |month= |title=Gresham's Law or Gresham's Fallacy |journal=Journal of Political Economy |volume=94 |issue=1 |pages=185–199 |doi=10.1086/261368 |jstor= 1831965}}
* {{cite journal |last=Rolnick |first=A. J. |author2=Weber, W. E. |date=1986 |title=Gresham's Law or Gresham's Fallacy |journal=Journal of Political Economy |volume=94 |issue=1 |pages=185–199 |doi=10.1086/261368 |jstor= 1831965|s2cid=102968 |url=http://minneapolisfed.org/research/qr/qr1012.pdf }}
*] (1980). '']'' Gresham's Law and Coinage . Auburn AL, ].
* ] (1980). '']'' Gresham's Law and Coinage .
*Selgin, G., University of Georgia (2003). .
* Selgin, G., University of Georgia (2003). .
*{{cite book | author=Spiegel, Henry William | title=The growth of economic thought | edition=3rd | publisher=Duke University Press | year=1991 | isbn=0-8223-0965-3}}
*{{cite book|last=Stokes|first=D.E|year=1997|title=Pasteur's Quadrant: Basic Science and Technological Innovation|publisher=Brookings Institution Press|location=Washington D.C.|isbn=0815781776}} * {{cite book | author=Spiegel, Henry William | title=The growth of economic thought | edition=3rd | publisher=Duke University Press | date=1991 | isbn=0-8223-0965-3}}
* {{cite book|last=Stokes|first=D.E|date=1997|title=Pasteur's Quadrant: Basic Science and Technological Innovation|url=https://archive.org/details/pasteursquadrant00stok|url-access=registration|publisher=Brookings Institution Press|location=Washington, D.C.|isbn=0815781776}}


==External links== ==External links==
{{Wiktionary|a bad penny always turns up}}
*{{Commons category-inline}}
{{wiktionary|bad money drives out good}} {{wiktionary|bad money drives out good}}
* * (archived 21 February 2012)
*
* – illustrates Gresham's Law based upon the current metal value of coins in circulation. * – illustrates Gresham's Law based upon the current metal value of coins in circulation.


{{Nicolaus Copernicus|state=collapsed}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=January 2011}}
{{Authority control}}


{{DEFAULTSORT:Gresham's Law}} {{DEFAULTSORT:Gresham's Law}}
] ]
] ]
] ]
] ]
] ]
]
] ]
]

Latest revision as of 02:56, 20 December 2024

Monetary principle – "bad money drives out good" "Good money" redirects here. For the banking platform, see Good Money.

Sir Thomas Gresham

In economics, Gresham's law is a monetary principle stating that "bad money drives out good". For example, if there are two forms of commodity money in circulation, which are accepted by law as having similar face value, the more valuable commodity will gradually disappear from circulation.

The law was named in 1857 by economist Henry Dunning Macleod after Sir Thomas Gresham (1519–1579), an English financier during the Tudor dynasty. Gresham had urged Queen Elizabeth to restore confidence in then-debased English currency.

The concept was thoroughly defined in Renaissance Europe by Nicolaus Copernicus and known centuries earlier in classical Antiquity, the Near East, and China.

"Good money" and "bad money"

Under Gresham's law, "good money" is money that shows little difference between its nominal value (the face value of the coin) and its commodity value (the value of the metal of which it is made, often precious metals, such as gold or silver).

The price spread between face value and commodity value when it is minted is called seigniorage. As some coins do not circulate, remaining in the possession of coin collectors, this can increase demand for coinage.

On the other hand, "bad money" is money that has a commodity value considerably lower than its face value and is in circulation along with good money, where both forms are required to be accepted at equal value as legal tender.

In Gresham's day, bad money included any coin that had been debased. Debasement was often done by the issuing body, where less than the officially specified amount of precious metal was contained in an issue of coinage, usually by alloying it with a base metal. The public could also debase coins, usually by clipping or scraping off small portions of the precious metal, also known as "stemming" (reeded edges on coins were intended to make clipping evident). Other examples of bad money include counterfeit coins made from base metal. Today virtually all circulating coins are made from base metals, often the cheapest available, durable base metal; collectively these monies are known as fiat money. While virtually all contemporary coinage is composed solely of base metals, there have been periods during the 21st century in which the market value of some base metals, like copper, have been high enough that at least one common coin (the U.S. nickel) still maintained "good money" status.

In the case of clipped, scraped, or counterfeit coins, the commodity value was reduced by fraud. The face value remains at the previous higher level. On the other hand, with a coinage debased by a government issuer, the commodity value of the coinage was often reduced quite openly, while the face value of the debased coins was held at the higher level by legal tender laws.

The old saying, "a bad penny always turns up" is a colloquial recognition of Gresham's law.

Theory

The law states that any circulating currency consisting of both "good" and "bad" money (both forms required to be accepted at equal value under legal tender law) quickly becomes dominated by the "bad" money. This is because people spending money will hand over the "bad" coins rather than the "good" ones, keeping the "good" ones for themselves. Legal tender laws act as a form of price control. In such a case, the intrinsically less valuable money is preferred in exchange, because people prefer to save the intrinsically more valuable money.

Imagine that a customer with several silver sixpence coins purchases an item which costs five pence. Some of the customer's coins are more debased, while others are less so – but legally, they are all mandated to be of equal value. The customer would prefer to retain the better coins, and so offers the shopkeeper the most debased one. In turn, the shopkeeper must give one penny in change, and has every reason to give the most debased penny. Thus, the coins that circulate in the transaction will tend to be of the most debased sort available to the parties.

A stack of twenty Walking Liberty half dollars (left), which contain 90% silver. In an example of Gresham's law, these coins were quickly hoarded by the public after the Coinage Act of 1965 debased half dollars to contain only 40% silver, and then were debased entirely in 1971 to base cupronickel (right).

If "good" coins have a face value below that of their metallic content, individuals may be motivated to melt them down and sell the metal for its higher intrinsic value, even if such destruction is illegal. The 1965 United States half-dollar coins contained 40% silver; in previous years these coins were 90% silver (.900, or one nine fine). With the release of the 1965 half-dollar, which was legally required to be accepted at the same value as the earlier 90% halves, the older 90% silver coinage quickly disappeared from circulation, while the newer debased coins remained in use. As the value of the dollar (Federal Reserve notes) continued to decline, resulting in the value of the silver content exceeding the face value of the coins, many of the older half dollars were melted down or removed from circulation and into private collections and hoards. Beginning in 1971, the U.S. government abandoned including any silver in half dollars. The metal value of the 40% silver coins began to exceed their face value, which resulted in a repeat of the previous event. The 40% silver coins also began to vanish from circulation and into coin hoards.

A similar situation occurred in 2007 in the United States with the rising price of copper, zinc, and nickel, which led the U.S. government to ban the melting or mass exportation of one-cent and five-cent coins.

In addition to being melted down for its bullion value, money that is considered to be "good" tends to leave an economy through international trade. International traders are not bound by legal tender laws as citizens of the issuing country are, so they will offer higher value for good coins than bad ones. The good coins may leave their country of origin to become part of international trade, escaping that country's legal tender laws and leaving the "bad" money behind. This occurred in Britain during the period of adoption of the gold standard: In 1717 Isaac Newton, then Master of the Mint, declared the gold guinea to be worth 21 silver shillings. This overvalued the gold guinea in Britain, making it "bad", and encouraged people to send "good" silver shillings abroad, where it could buy more gold than at home. This gold was then minted as currency, which bought silver shillings, which were sent abroad for gold, and so on. For a century hardly any silver coins were minted in Britain, and Britain moved onto a de facto gold standard.

Austrian economist Hans-Hermann Hoppe said that "so-called Gresham's law" only applies under certain conditions, largely a result of governmental interventionist policies. In his 2021 book, Economy, Society, and History Hoppe states:

You might have heard about the so-called Gresham's law, which states that bad money drives out good money, but this law only holds if there are price controls in effect, only if the exchange ratios of different monies are fixed and no longer reflect market forces. Is it the case that bad money drives out good money under normal circumstances without any interference? No, for money holds to exactly the same law that holds for every other good. Good goods drive out bad goods. Good money drives out bad money, so this bezant was for something like 800 years considered to be the best money available and was preferred by merchants from India to Rome to the Baltic Sea.

History of the concept

Gresham was not the first to state the law which took his name. The phenomenon had been noted by Aristophanes in his play The Frogs, which dates from around the end of the 5th century BCE. The referenced passage from The Frogs is as follows (usually dated at 405 BCE):

It has often struck our notice that the course our city runs
Is the same towards men and money. She has true and worthy sons:
She has good and ancient silver, she has good and recent gold.
These are coins untouched with alloys; everywhere their fame is told;
Not all Hellas holds their equal, not all Barbary far and near.
Gold or silver, each well minted, tested each and ringing clear.
Yet, we never use them! Others always pass from hand to hand.
Sorry brass just struck last week and branded with a wretched brand.
So with men we know for upright, blameless lives and noble names.
Trained in music and palaestra, freemen's choirs and freemen's games,
These we spurn for men of brass...

According to Ben Tamari, the currency devaluation phenomenon was already recognized in ancient sources. He brings some examples which include the Machpela Cave transaction and the building of the Temple from the Bible and the Mishna in tractate Bava Metzia (Bava Metzia 4:1) from the Talmud.

In China, Yuan dynasty economic authors Yeh Shih and Yuan Hsieh (c. 1223) were aware of the same phenomenon.

Ibn Taimiyyah (1263–1328) described the phenomenon as follows:

If the ruler cancels the use of a certain coin and mints another kind of money for the people, he will spoil the riches (amwal) which they possess, by decreasing their value as the old coins will now become merely a commodity. He will do injustice to them by depriving them of the higher values originally owned by them. Moreover, if the intrinsic values of coins are different it will become a source of profit for the wicked to collect the small (bad) coins and exchange them (for good money) and then they will take them to another country and shift the small (bad) money of that country (to this country). So (the value of) people's goods will be damaged.

Notably this passage mentions only the flight of good money abroad and says nothing of its disappearance due to hoarding or melting. Palestinian economist Adel Zagha also attributes a similar concept to medieval Islamic thinker Al-Maqrizi, who offered, claims Zagha, a close approximation to what would become known as Gresham's law centuries later.

In the 14th century it was noted by Nicole Oresme c. 1350, in his treatise On the Origin, Nature, Law, and Alterations of Money, and by jurist and historian Al-Maqrizi (1364–1442) in the Mamluk Empire.

Johannes de Strigys, an agent of Ludovico III Gonzaga, Marquis of Mantua in Venice, wrote in a June 1472 report che la cativa cazarà via la bona ("that the bad money will chase out the good").

In the year that Gresham was born, 1519, it was described by Nicolaus Copernicus in a treatise called Monetae cudendae ratio: "bad (debased) coinage drives good (un-debased) coinage out of circulation". Copernicus was aware of the practice of exchanging bad coins for good ones and melting down the latter or sending them abroad, and he seems to have drawn up some notes on this subject while he was at Olsztyn in 1519. He made them the basis of a report which he presented to the Prussian Diet held in 1522, attending the session with his friend Tiedemann Giese to represent his chapter. Copernicus's Monetae cudendae ratio was an enlarged, Latin version of that report, setting forth a general theory of money for the 1528 diet. He also formulated a version of the quantity theory of money. For this reason, it is occasionally known as the Gresham–Copernicus law.

Sir Thomas Gresham, a 16th century financial agent of the English Crown in the city of Antwerp, was one in a long series of proponents of the law, which he did to explain to Queen Elizabeth I what was happening to the English shilling. Her father, Henry VIII, had replaced 40% of the silver in the coin with base metals, to increase the government's income without raising taxes. Astute English merchants and ordinary subjects saved the good shillings from pure silver and circulated the bad ones. Hence, the bad money would be used whenever possible, and the good coinage would be saved and disappear from circulation.

According to the economist George Selgin in his paper "Gresham's Law":

As for Gresham himself, he observed "that good and bad coin cannot circulate together" in a letter written to Queen Elizabeth on the occasion of her accession in 1558. The statement was part of Gresham's explanation for the "unexampled state of badness" that England's coinage had been left in following the "Great Debasements" of Henry VIII and Edward VI, which reduced the metallic value of English silver coins to a small fraction of what it had been at the time of Henry VII. Owing to these debasements, Gresham observed to the Queen, that "all your fine gold was convayed out of this your realm".

Gresham made his observations of good and bad money while in the service of Queen Elizabeth, with respect only to the observed poor quality of British coinage. Earlier monarchs, Henry VIII and Edward VI, had forced the people to accept debased coinage by means of legal tender laws. Gresham also made his comparison of good and bad money where the precious metal in the money was the same metal, but of different weight. He did not compare silver to gold, or gold to paper.

In his "Gresham's Law" article, Selgin also offers the following comments regarding the origin of the name:

The expression "Gresham's Law" dates back only to 1858, when British economist Henry Dunning Macleod (1858, pp. 476–8) decided to name the tendency for bad money to drive good money out of circulation after Sir Thomas Gresham (1519–1579). However, references to such a tendency, sometimes accompanied by discussion of conditions promoting it, occur in various medieval writings, most notably Nicholas Oresme's (c. 1357) Treatise on money. The concept can be traced to ancient works, including Aristophanes' The Frogs, where the prevalence of bad politicians is attributed to forces similar to those favoring bad money over good.

Reverse of Gresham's law (Thiers' law)

The experiences of dollarization in countries with weak economies and currencies (such as Israel in the 1980s, Eastern Europe and countries in the period immediately after the collapse of the Soviet bloc, or Ecuador throughout the late 20th and early 21st century) may be seen as Gresham's law operating in its reverse form (Guidotti & Rodriguez, 1992) because in general, the dollar has not been legal tender in such situations, and in some cases, its use has been illegal.

Adam Fergusson and Costantino Bresciani-Turroni (in his book Le vicende del marco tedesco, published in 1931) pointed out that, during the great inflation in the Weimar Republic in 1923, as the official money became so worthless that virtually nobody would take it, people simply stopped accepting the currency in exchange for goods. That was particularly serious because farmers began to hoard food. Accordingly, any currency backed by any sort of value became a circulating medium of exchange. In 2009, hyperinflation in Zimbabwe began to show similar characteristics.

Those examples show that in the absence of effective legal tender laws, Gresham's law works in reverse. If given the choice of what money to accept, people will accept the money they believe to be of highest long-term value, and not accept what they believe to be of low long-term value. If not given the choice and required to accept all money, good and bad, they will tend to keep the money of greater perceived value in their own possession and pass the bad money to others.

In short, in the absence of legal tender laws, the seller will not accept anything but money of certain value (good money), but the existence of legal tender laws will cause the buyer to offer only money with the lowest commodity value (bad money), as the creditor must accept such money at face value.

Nobel Prize winner Robert Mundell believes that Gresham's law could be more accurately rendered, taking care of the reverse, if it were expressed as: "Bad money drives out good if they exchange for the same price."

The reverse of Gresham's law, that good money drives out bad money whenever the bad money becomes nearly worthless, has been named "Thiers' law" by economist Peter Bernholz in honor of French politician and historian Adolphe Thiers. "Thiers' Law will only operate later when the increase of the new flexible exchange rate and of the rate of inflation lower the real demand for the inflating money."

Analogs in other fields

The principles of Gresham's law can sometimes be applied to different fields of study. Gresham's law may be generally applied to any circumstance in which the true value of something is markedly different from the value people are required to accept, due to factors such as lack of information or governmental decree.

Vice President Spiro Agnew used Gresham's law in describing American news media, stating that "Bad news drives out good news", although his argument was closer to that of a race to the bottom for higher ratings rather than over- and under-valuing certain kinds of news.

Gregory Bateson postulated an analogue to Gresham's law operating in cultural evolution, in which "the oversimplified ideas will always displace the sophisticated and the vulgar and hateful will always displace the beautiful. And yet the beautiful persists."

Cory Doctorow wrote that a similar effect to Gresham's law occurred in carbon offset trading. The alleged information asymmetry is that people find it difficult to distinguish just how effective credits purchased are, but can easily tell the price. As a result, cheap credits that are ineffective can displace expensive but worthwhile carbon credits. The example given was The Nature Conservancy offering cheap, yet "meaningless", carbon credits by purchasing cheap land unlikely to be logged anyway, rather than expensive and valuable land at risk of logging.

A corollary, Hughes' law, exists in moral philosophy, stating that, "The evil acts of bad men elicit from better men acts which, under better circumstances, would also be called evil."

In the market for used cars, lemon automobiles (analogous to bad currency) will drive out the good cars. The problem is one of asymmetry of information. Sellers have a strong financial incentive to pass all used cars off as good cars, especially lemons. This makes it difficult to buy a good car at a fair price, as the buyer risks overpaying for a lemon. The result is that buyers will only pay the fair price of a lemon, so at least they reduce the risk of overpaying. High-quality cars tend to be pushed out of the market, because there is no good way to establish that they really are worth more. Certified pre-owned programs are an attempt to mitigate this problem by providing a warranty and other guarantees of quality. The Market for Lemons is a work that examines this problem in more detail.

See also

Notes

  1. Gresham's law – economics. Encyclopædia Britannica. Retrieved 8 April 2018.
  2. Investopedia Staff (9 February 2010). "Gresham's Law". Investopedia. Retrieved 8 April 2018.
  3. Macleod, Henry Dunning (1896). The History of Economics. London: Bliss, Sands and Co. pp. 38-39, 146, 448 –. Retrieved 7 December 2023 – via Internet Archive.
  4. ^ Wooldridge, Leslie Quander. "Fiat money: Currencies that derive their value largely through trust in the governments that issue them". Business Insider. Retrieved 5 October 2023.
  5. "News – U.S. Mint". www.usmint.gov. Archived from the original on 12 September 2016. Retrieved 8 April 2018.
  6. Fray, C R (1935). "Newton and the Gold Standard". Cambridge Historical Journal. 5 (1): 109–117. doi:10.1017/S1474691300001256. JSTOR 3020836.
  7. Hoppe, Hans-Hermann (2021). Economy, Society, and History. Auburn, AL: Mises Institute. p. 49. ISBN 978-1-61016-734-5.
  8. Aristophanes (1908). The Frogs (tr. Gilbert Murray). London: George Allen & Sons. p. 56. Retrieved 17 April 2019.
  9. ^ Originally published as Tamari, Ben (1982). חוק גרשם ופרדוקס החסכון [Gresham's Law and the Savings Paradox] (PDF). רבעון לכלכלה (in Hebrew). 115. Retrieved 15 March 2012. translated and updated in 2011 at Tamar, Ben (July 2011). "Gresham's Law" (PDF). Translated by Liat Etta. Retrieved 15 March 2012.
  10. Genesis 23:16
  11. 1 Kings 10:21
  12. Shuettinger, Robert L.; Butler, Eamonn F. (1979). Forty Centuries of Wage and Price Controls: How Not To Fight Inflation. Thornwood, NY: The Heritage Foundation. p. 14. ISBN 0-89195-023-0.
  13. "Economic Concepts of Ibn Taimiyyah". 16 March 2004. Archived from the original on 16 March 2004. Retrieved 8 April 2018.
  14. "ACRPS Seminar on the Contribution of Al-Maqrizi to Economic Thinking". Arab Center for Research and Policy Studies.
  15. Woods, Thomas E. How The Catholic Church Built Western Civilization.
  16. Durant, Will (1957). The Reformation. The Story of Civilization. Vol. 6. Simon & Schuster. p. 252.
  17. Baeck, Louis (1994). The Mediterranean Tradition in Economic Thought. New York: Routledge. pp. 105–106. ISBN 0-415-09301-5.
  18. Fernand Braudel (1966). La Méditerranée et le monde méditerranéen à l'époque de Philippe II, Volume 2: Destins collectifs et mouvements d'ensemble (in French). Paris: Armand Colin. p. 41.
  19. Angus Armitage, The World of Copernicus, chapter 24: "The Diseases of Money", pp. 89–91
  20. Measurement of Co-Circulation of Currencies. International Monetary Fund. 1995. p. 61. ISBN 978-1-4552-9991-1. Retrieved 16 March 2013.
  21. ^ "Gresham's Law". EH.net. Archived from the original on 17 March 2013.
  22. Bernholz, Peter (31 March 2011). "Understanding Early Monetary Developments by Applying Economic Laws: The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments, Gresham's and Thiers' Laws". SSRN. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1799983. S2CID 152412531. SSRN 1799983.
  23. Fergusson, Adam (1975). "12: The Bottom of the Abyss". When Money Dies: The Nightmare of the Weimar Collapse. Ludwig von Mises Institute. Archived from the original on 24 March 2010. Retrieved 29 November 2009.
  24. Rowe, Nick (14 July 2009). "The State(s) Theory of Money: California and Canadian Tire". Worthwhile Canadian Initiative. Retrieved 16 July 2009.
  25. Mundell, Robert (August 1998). "Uses and Abuses of Gresham's Law in the History of Money". Columbia University. Archived from the original on 11 January 2012. Retrieved 10 October 2009.
  26. Peter Bernholz (2003), Monetary Regimes and Inflation, pp. 41, 115, 132, Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton, Massachusetts, ISBN 978-1-84542-778-8
  27. Bernholz, p. 132
  28. Agnew, Spiro Theodore (13 November 1969). "Television News Coverage". Des Moines, Iowa – via American Rhetoric.
  29. Gregory Bateson, Mind and Nature: A Necessary Unity 6 (1979).
  30. Doctorow, Cory (12 December 2020). "Carbon offsets are bullshit". Pluralistic.
  31. Elgin, Ben (9 December 2020). "These Trees Are Not What They Seem: How the Nature Conservancy, the world's biggest environmental group, became a dealer of meaningless carbon offsets". Bloomberg.
  32. McAlister, John W. (14 January 2021). Ethical Universe: the Vectors of Evil Vs. Good: Secular Ethics for the 21st Century. AuthorHouse. ISBN 9781665511919. {{cite book}}: |work= ignored (help)
  33. Phlips, Louis (1983). The Economics of Price Discrimination. p. 239.

References

External links

Nicolaus Copernicus
Scientific career
Works
Family
Related
Categories: