Misplaced Pages

First-past-the-post voting: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 00:45, 23 April 2013 edit190.80.8.7 (talk) GerrymanderingTag: section blanking← Previous edit Latest revision as of 01:53, 21 December 2024 edit undoPigly3 (talk | contribs)153 edits Reverting edit(s) by 2601:244:5601:3020:8425:F9E4:9D41:D9CC (talk) to rev. 1261268300 by Safes007: NPOV issues (UV 0.1.6)Tags: Ultraviolet Undo 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Plurality voting system}}{{Use dmy dates|date=March 2023}}{{Citation style|date=July 2024}}
{{Electoral systems}}
{{Splitto|date=September 2024|Single-member district}}{{Electoral systems sidebar|expanded=Single-winner}}


]
A '''first-past-the-post''' (abbreviated '''FPTP''' or '''FPP''') election is one that is won by the candidate with more votes than any other(s). It is a common, but not universal, feature of ]s with ], and generally results over time with a ] competition.
'''First-past-the-post voting''' ('''FPTP'''), also known as '''first-preference plurality''' ('''FPP''') or '''single-member district plurality''' ('''SMDP''')—often shortened simply to '''plurality'''—is a ] voting rule. Voters typically mark one candidate as their favorite, and the candidate with the largest number of ] marks (a ]) is elected, regardless of whether they have over half of all votes (a '']''). The name ''first-past-the-post'' is a reference to ] (where bettors would guess which horse they thought would be first past the finishing post).<ref>{{Cite web |date=2018-07-31 |title=First-past-the-post: a rogue's practice? |url=https://onelections.net/2018/07/31/first-past-the-post-a-rogues-practice/ |access-date=2024-09-09 |website=On Elections |language=en}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |date=13 January 2016 |title=First past the post |url=https://nzhistory.govt.nz/politics/fpp-to-mmp/first-past-the-post |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220524111637/https://nzhistory.govt.nz/politics/fpp-to-mmp/first-past-the-post |archive-date=24 May 2022 |access-date=25 May 2022 |website=nzhistory.govt.nz |publisher=] |language=en}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |date=6 September 2010 |title=First Past the Post and Alternative Vote explained |url=https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/first-past-the-post-and-alternative-vote-explained |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240118113041/https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/first-past-the-post-and-alternative-vote-explained |archive-date=18 January 2024 |access-date=13 July 2024 |website=gov.uk}}</ref> In ], FPP is generally treated as a ] variant of ], where voters rank the candidates, but only the first preference matters. As a result, FPP is usually implemented with a '''choose-one ballot''', where voters place a single bubble next to their favorite candidate.


FPP has been used to elect the ] since the ].<ref>{{cite web |date=26 September 2016 |title=The Boundaries Review is a chance to bring back multi-member constituencies |url=https://blog.politics.ox.ac.uk/boundaries-review-chance-bring-back-multi-member-constituencies/}}</ref> Throughout the 20th century, many countries that previously used FPP have abandoned it in favor of other electoral systems, including the former British colonies of ] and ].
==Overview==
{{norefs|section|date = October 2012}}
The first-past-the-post voting method is one of several ]s. It is also known as the 'winner-takes-all', or 'simple plurality'.


Most ] still ] retain FPP for most elections. However, the combination of ] with the ] mean the country has effectively used a variation on the ] since ], where the first round selects two major contenders who go on to receive the overwhelming majority of votes.<ref name=":0322">{{Cite web |last1=Santucci |first1=Jack |last2=Shugart |first2=Matthew |last3=Latner |first3=Michael S. |date=2023-10-16 |title=Toward a Different Kind of Party Government |url=https://protectdemocracy.org/work/toward-a-different-kind-of-party-government/ |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240716205506/https://protectdemocracy.org/work/toward-a-different-kind-of-party-government/ |archive-date=2024-07-16 |access-date=2024-07-16 |website=Protect Democracy |language=en-US |quote="Finally, we should not discount the role of primaries. When we look at the range of countries with ] (FPTP) elections (given no primaries), none with an assembly larger than Jamaica’s (63) has a strict two-party system. These countries include the ] and ] (where multiparty competition is in fact nationwide). Whether the U.S. should be called ‘FPTP’ itself is dubious, and not only because some states (e.g. ]) hold runoffs or use the ] (e.g. ]). '''Rather, the U.S. has an unusual two-round system in which the first round winnows the field. This usually is at the intraparty level, although sometimes it is without regard to party (e.g. in Alaska and California).'''"}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book |last1=Gallagher |first1=Michael |title=The Politics of Electoral Systems |last2=Mitchell |first2=Paul |date=2005-09-15 |publisher=OUP Oxford |isbn=978-0-19-153151-4 |page=192 |language=en |chapter=The American Electoral System |quote="American elections become a two-round run-off system with a delay of several months between the rounds." |chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Igdj1P4vBwMC&q=%22American+elections+become+a+two-round+run-off+system+with+a+delay+of+several+months+between+the+rounds.%22&pg=PA3}}</ref><ref>{{Citation |last1=Bowler |first1=Shaun |title=The United States: A Case of Duvergerian Equilibrium |date=2009 |work=Duverger's Law of Plurality Voting: The Logic of Party Competition in Canada, India, the United Kingdom and the United States |pages=135–146 |url=https://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007/978-0-387-09720-6_9 |access-date=2024-08-31 |place=New York, NY |publisher=Springer |language=en |doi=10.1007/978-0-387-09720-6_9 |isbn=978-0-387-09720-6 |quote=In effect, the primary system means that the USA has a two-round runoff system of elections. |last2=Grofman |first2=Bernard |last3=Blais |first3=André}}</ref>
Confusion in terminology often exists between highest vote, majority vote and plurality ]s. All three use a first-past-the-post voting method, but there are subtle differences in the method of execution.{{Citation needed|date=May 2010}} First-past-the-post voting is also used in ]s and ]s.


]).]]
First-past-the-post voting methods can be used for single and multiple member elections. In a single member election the candidate with the highest number, not necessarily a majority, of votes is elected. The two-round ('runoff') voting system uses a first-past-the-post voting method in each of the two rounds. The first round determines which two candidates will progress to the second, final round ballot.


== Example ==
In a multiple member first-past-the-post ballot, the first number of candidates, in order of highest vote, corresponding to the number of positions to be filled are elected. If there are six vacancies then the first six candidates with the highest vote are elected. A multiple selection ballot where more than one candidate can be voted for is also a form of first-past-the-post voting in which voters are allowed to cast a vote for as many candidates as there are vacant positions; the candidate(s) with the highest number of votes is elected.
{{Tenn voting example}}


In FPTP, only the first preferences matter. As such, the votes would be counted as 42% for Memphis, 26% for Nashville, 17% for Knoxville, and 15% for Chattanooga. Since Memphis has the most votes, it would win a FPTP election, even though it is far from the center of the state and a ]. Similarly, ] would ], the easternmost city. This makes the election a ]. By contrast, both ]s and ] would ] (the capital of Tennessee).
The ] is a political pressure group based in the United Kingdom which advocates scrapping First Past the Post (FPTP) for all National and local elections. It argues FPTP is 'bad for voters, bad for government and bad for democracy'. It is the oldest organisation concerned with electoral systems in the world.{{cn|date=January 2013}}


== Properties and effects ==
All ]s – other than Maine and Nebraska – {{As of|2008|lc=y}} use a winner-take-all form of simple plurality, first-past-the-post voting to determine the electors appointed to the ]. Under the typical system, the candidate that gains the highest vote total wins all of the state's available electors.
{| class="wikitable"

|+Table of ]
==Example==
!

!Pathology
{{Singaporean presidential election, 2011}}
!Explanation/details

Under a first-past-the-post voting system the highest polling candidate is jaman fu real banna wiki pedia can be edited it is not accurate take it from my words bannnna
(or a group of candidates for some cases) is elected. In this real-life example, ] obtained a greater number than the other candidates, and so was declared the winner.

==Effects==
The effect of a system based on single seat constituencies is that the larger parties gain a disproportionately large share of seats, while smaller parties are left with a disproportionately small share of seats. For example, the 2005 UK General election results in Great Britain were as follows:

{{electiontable|United Kingdom parliamentary election, 2005}}'''Summary of the 5 May 2005 ] ] (parties with more than one seat; not incl. N. Ireland)
|- |-
|{{Xmark}}
!colspan=2|Seats<br /><small>This table indicates those parties with over one seat, Great Britain only</small>
|]
!Seats %
|The ] occurs when a majority of voters prefer some candidate ''Alice'' to every other candidate, but ''Alice'' still loses the election. First-past-the-post is vulnerable to this paradox because of vote-splitting.<ref name="lse27685">Felsenthal, Dan S. (2010) {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210224094341/http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/27685/1/Review_of_Paradoxes_Afflicting_Various_Voting_Procedures_(LSERO).pdf |date=24 February 2021 }}. In: Assessing Alternative Voting Procedures, London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK.</ref>
!Votes %
!Votes
|- |-
|{{Xmark}}
|Labour Party
|]
|355||56.5||36.1||9,552,436
|The ''']''' paradox happens when a majority of voters prefer every other candidate to ''A'', but ''Alice'' still wins. First-past-the-post is vulnerable to this paradox because of vote-splitting.<ref name="lse27685" />
|- |-
|{{Xmark}}
|Conservative Party
|''']'''
|198||31.5||33.2||8,782,192
|The center squeeze describes a type of violation of ] primarily affecting voting rules in the ] where the Condorcet winner is eliminated in an early round or otherwise due to a lack of first-preference support.
|- |-
|{{Xmark}}
|Liberal Democrats
|''']'''
|62||9.9||22.6||5,985,454
|A ] is when the results of an election between ''A'' and ''B'' is affected by voters' opinions on an unrelated candidate ''C''. First-past-the-post does not meet this criterion, which makes it vulnerable to ].
|- |-
|{{Xmark}}
|Scottish National Party
|]
|6||1.0||1.6||412,267
|The ] is a particular kind of spoiler effect that involves several perfect copies, or "clones", of a candidate. Candidate-cloning causes vote-splitting in FPP.
|- |-
|{{Xmark}}
|Plaid Cymru
|''']'''
|3||0.5||0.7||174,838
|The best-is-worst paradox occurs when an electoral system declares the same candidate to be in first and last place, depending on whether voters rank candidates from best-to-worst or worst-to-best. FPP demonstrates this pathology, because a candidate can be both the FPP winner and also the ] loser.
|- |-
|{{Xmark}}
|Others
|]
|4||0.6||5.7||1,523,716
|Lesser-evil voting occurs when voters are forced to support a "lesser of two evils" by rating them higher than their actual favorite candidate. FPP is vulnerable to this pathology.
|- |-
|{{Tick}}
!colspan=2|628!! !! !!26,430,908
|''']'''
| rowspan="2" |Since plurality does not consider later preferences on the ballot at all, it is impossible to either harm or help a favorite candidate by marking later preferences. Thus it passes both Later-No-Harm and Later-No-Help.
|-
|{{Tick}}
|]
|-
|{{Tick}}
|''']'''
|The multiple-districts paradox refers to a particularly egregious kind of ], when it is possible to draw a map where a candidate who loses the election nevertheless manages to win in every ]. This is not possible under FPP, or other ] methods.
|-
|{{Tick}}
|''']'''
|Perverse response occurs when a candidate loses as a result of receiving too ''much'' support from some voters, i.e. it is possible for a candidate to lose by receiving too many votes. FPP is not affected by this pathology.
|-
|{{Tick}}
|''']'''
|The ] is a situation where a candidate loses as a result of having ''too many'' supporters. In other words, adding a voter who supports ''A'' over ''B'' can cause ''A'' to lose to ''B''. FPP is not affected by this pathology.
|} |}
===Two-party rule===
{{Main|Duverger's law}}
]]]
Perhaps the most striking effect of FPP is the fact that the number of a party's seats in a legislature has nothing to do with its vote count in an election, only in how those votes were geographically distributed. This has been a target of criticism for the method, many arguing that a fundamental requirement of an election system is to accurately represent the views of voters. FPP often creates "false majorities" by over-representing larger parties (giving a majority of the parliamentary/legislative seats to a party that did not receive a majority of the votes) while under-representing smaller ones. In Canada, ]s have been formed due to one party winning a majority of the votes cast in Canada only three times since 1921: in ], ] and ]. In the United Kingdom, 19 of the 24 general elections since 1922 have produced a single-party majority government. In all but two of them (] and ]), the leading party did not take a majority of the votes across the UK.


In some cases, this can lead to a party receiving the plurality or even majority of total votes yet still failing to gain a plurality of legislative seats. This results in a situation called a ] or ].<ref>{{Cite journal|journal=American Economic Journal: Applied Economics|pages=327–357|volume=14|url=https://www.nber.org/papers/w26247|title=Inversions in US Presidential Elections: 1836-2016|first1=Michael|last1=Geruso|first2=Dean|last2=Spears|first3=Ishaana|last3=Talesara|date=5 September 2019|issue=1|doi=10.3386/w26247|pmid=38213750 |pmc=10782436 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210319145533/https://www.nber.org/papers/w26247|access-date=14 July 2021|archive-date=19 March 2021|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |url=https://slide-finder.com/view/ELECTION-INVERSIONS-BY-VARIANTS.214192.html |title=Election Inversions By Variants of the U.S. Electoral College |access-date=14 July 2021 |archive-date=18 July 2021 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210718043847/https://slide-finder.com/view/ELECTION-INVERSIONS-BY-VARIANTS.214192.html |url-status=dead |first=Nicholas R. |last=Miller |department=Department of Political Science |agency=UMBC }}</ref> Famous examples of the second-place party (in votes nationally) winning a majority of seats include the elections in Ghana in ], New Zealand in ] and ], and the United Kingdom in ]. Famous examples of the second placed party (in votes nationally) winning a plurality of seats include the elections in Canada in ] and ] as well as in Japan in ]. Even when a party wins more than half the votes in an almost purely two-party-competition, it is possible for the runner-up to win a majority of seats. This happened in ] in ], ], and ] and in Belize in ]. Even with only two parties and equally-sized constituencies, winning a majority of seats just requires receiving more than half the vote in more than half the districts—even if the other party receives all the votes cast in the other districts—so just over a quarter of the vote is theoretically enough to win a majority in the legislature. With enough candidates splitting the vote in a district, the total number of votes needed to win can be made ].{{Citation needed|date=October 2024}}
It can be seen that Labour took a majority of seats, 57%, with only 36% of the vote. The largest ''two'' parties took 69% of votes and 88% of seats. Meanwhile, the smaller Liberal Democrat party took over a fifth of votes but only about a tenth of the seats in parliament.

=== Two-party systems ===
Under first-past-the-post, a small party may draw votes and seats away from a larger party that it is ''more'' similar to, and therefore give an advantage to one it is ''less'' similar to. For example, in the ], the left-leaning ] drew more votes from the left-leaning ], resulting in Nader ] for the Democrats. According to the political pressure group ], FPTP creates a powerful electoral incentive for large parties to target similar segments of voters with similar policies. The effect of this reduces political diversity in a country because the larger parties are incentivized to coalesce around similar policies.<ref>{{Cite web|title=First Past the Post|url=https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/first-past-the-post|access-date=26 June 2020|website=Make Votes Matter|archive-date=31 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200731164815/https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/first-past-the-post|url-status=live}}</ref> The ] describes India's use of FPTP as a "legacy of British colonialism".<ref>{{Cite web|title=India – First Past the Post on a Grand Scale|url=https://aceproject.org/main/english/es/esy_in.htm|access-date=25 June 2020|website=ACE Electoral Knowledge Network}}</ref>

] is an idea in ] which says that constituencies that use first-past-the-post methods will lead to ]s, given enough time. Economist ] explains:
{{Blockquote|The main reason for America's majoritarian character is the electoral system for Congress. Members of Congress are elected in single-member districts according to the "first-past-the-post" (FPTP) principle, meaning that the candidate with the plurality of votes is the winner of the congressional seat. The losing party or parties win no representation at all. The first-past-the-post election tends to produce a small number of major parties, perhaps just two, a principle known in political science as ]. Smaller parties are trampled in first-past-the-post elections.|from Sachs's ''The Price of Civilization'', 2011<ref name="twsM18xxuy">{{Cite book |last=Sachs |first=Jeffrey |title=The Price of Civilization |date=2011 |publisher=Random House |isbn=978-1-4000-6841-8 |location=New York |page=107}}</ref>}}

However, most countries with first-past-the-post elections have multiparty legislatures (albeit with two parties larger than the others), the United States being the major exception.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Dunleavy |first1=Patrick |last2=Diwakar |first2=Rekha |year=2013 |title=Analysing multiparty competition in plurality rule elections |url=http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/38452/1/Dunleavy_Analysing%20multiparty_2014_author.pdf |journal=Party Politics |volume=19 |issue=6 |pages=855–886 |doi=10.1177/1354068811411026 |s2cid=18840573 |access-date=30 June 2016 |archive-date=9 June 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220609031929/http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/38452/1/Dunleavy_Analysing%20multiparty_2014_author.pdf |url-status=live }}</ref> There is a counter-argument to Duverger's Law, that while on the national level a plurality system may encourage two parties, in the individual constituencies supermajorities will lead to the vote fracturing.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Dickson |first1=Eric S.|author2-link=Kenneth Scheve |last2=Scheve |first2=Kenneth |year=2010 |title=Social Identity, Electoral Institutions and the Number of Candidates |journal=British Journal of Political Science |volume=40 |issue=2 |pages=349–375 |citeseerx=10.1.1.75.155 |doi=10.1017/s0007123409990354 |jstor=40649446|s2cid=7107526 }}</ref>

=== Strongholds, key constituencies and kingmakers ===
It has been suggested that the distortions in geographical representation provide incentives for parties to ignore the interests of areas in which they are too weak to stand much chance of gaining representation, leading to governments that do not govern in the national interest. Further, during election campaigns the campaigning activity of parties tends to focus on ]s where there is a prospect of a change in representation, leaving safer areas excluded from participation in an active campaign.<ref>{{Cite web |date=2011-01-04 |title=First Past the Post is a 'broken voting system' |url=https://www.ippr.org/news-and-media/press-releases/first-past-the-post-is-a-broken-voting-system |access-date=15 November 2017 |website=ippr.org |publisher=Institute for Public Policy Research |archive-date=15 November 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171115223042/https://www.ippr.org/news-and-media/press-releases/first-past-the-post-is-a-broken-voting-system |url-status=live }}</ref> Political parties operate by targeting districts, directing their activists and policy proposals toward those areas considered to be marginal, where each additional vote has more value.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Terry |first=Chris |date=2013-08-28 |title=In Britain's first past the post electoral system, some votes are worth 22 times more than others |url=http://www.democraticaudit.com/2013/08/28/in-britains-first-past-the-post-electoral-system-some-votes-are-worth-22-times-more-than-others/ |access-date=15 November 2017 |website=democraticaudit.com |publisher=London School of Economics}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |last=Galvin |first=Ray |title=What is a marginal seat? |url=http://www.justsolutions.eu/marginals/startmarginals.html |access-date=15 November 2017 |website=justsolutions.eu |archive-date=15 November 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171115215649/http://www.justsolutions.eu/marginals/startmarginals.html |url-status=live }}</ref><ref name="electoral-reform1" />

This feature of FPTP has often been used by its supporters in contrast to proportional systems. In the latter, smaller parties act as 'kingmakers' in coalitions as they have greater bargaining power and therefore, arguably, their influence on policy is disproportional to their parliamentary size- this is largely avoided in FPP systems where majorities are generally achieved.<ref name="Brams/Kilgour2010">{{cite journal |author=Brams/Kilgour. Dorey |title=Kingmakers and leaders in coalition formation |journal=Social Choice and Welfare |year=2013 |volume=41 |issue=1 |pages=1–18 |doi=10.1007/s00355-012-0680-4 |jstor=42001390 |s2cid=253849669 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/42001390 |hdl=10419/53209 |hdl-access=free |access-date=11 March 2023 |archive-date=11 March 2023 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230311121637/https://www.jstor.org/stable/42001390 |url-status=live }}</ref> FPP often produces governments which have legislative voting majorities,<ref name="Williams1998">{{Cite book |last=Andy Williams |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=6keDJpK0xL8C&pg=PA24 |title=UK Government & Politics |publisher=Heinemann |year=1998 |isbn=978-0-435-33158-0 |page=24 |access-date=11 October 2016 |archive-date=22 May 2024 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240522102106/https://books.google.com/books?id=6keDJpK0xL8C&pg=PA24#v=onepage&q&f=false |url-status=live }}</ref> thus providing such governments the legislative power necessary to implement their electoral ] commitments during their term in office. This may be beneficial for the country in question in circumstances where the government's legislative agenda has broad public support, albeit potentially divided across party lines, or at least benefits society as a whole. However handing a legislative voting majority to a government which lacks popular support can be problematic where said government's policies favor only that fraction of the electorate that supported it, particularly if the electorate divides on tribal, religious, or urban–rural lines. There is also the perceived issue of unfair coalitions where a smaller party can form a coalition with other smaller parties and form a government, without a clear mandate as was the case in the ] where the leading party ], was unable to form a coalition so ], a smaller party, managed to form a government without being the largest party. The use of ] (PR) may enable smaller parties to become decisive in the country's ] and gain leverage they would not otherwise enjoy, although this can be somewhat mitigated by a large enough ]. They argue that FPP generally reduces this possibility, except where parties have a strong regional basis. A journalist at '']'' noted that Israel's highly proportional ] "affords great power to relatively small parties, forcing the government to give in to political blackmail and to reach compromises";<ref>{{Cite news |last=Ilan |first=Shahar |title=Major Reforms Are Unlikely, but Electoral Threshold Could Be Raised |newspaper=Haaretz |url=https://www.haaretz.com/1.5074292 |access-date=8 May 2010 |archive-date=21 August 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190821221203/https://www.haaretz.com/1.5074292 |url-status=live }}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |last=Macavei |first=Mihaela |publisher=University of Alba Iulia |location=Romania |title=Advantages and disadvantages of the uninominal voting system |url=http://www.uab.ro/reviste_recunoscute/reviste_drept/annales_10_2007/macavei_en.pdf |access-date=8 May 2010 |archive-date=24 December 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191224074113/http://www.uab.ro/reviste_recunoscute/reviste_drept/annales_10_2007/macavei_en.pdf |url-status=dead }}</ref> ], defending FPP, argued that other systems give small parties the balance of power, and influence disproportionate to their votes.<ref name="Dorey2008">{{cite book|author=P. Dorey|title=The Labour Party and Constitutional Reform: A History of Constitutional Conservatism|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=JsaHDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA400|date=17 June 2008|publisher=Palgrave Macmillan UK|isbn=978-0-230-59415-9|pages=400–}}</ref>

The concept of kingmakers is adjacent to how ] criticized the ] system as "determined by the most worthless votes given for the most worthless candidates."<ref name="Johnston2011">{{cite book|author=Larry Johnston|title=Politics: An Introduction to the Modern Democratic State|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ZcpZ1eADwSMC&pg=PA231|date=13 December 2011|publisher=University of Toronto Press|isbn=978-1-4426-0533-6|pages=231–}}</ref> meaning that votes for the least supported candidates may change the outcome of the election between the most supported candidates. In this case however, this is a feature of the alternative vote, since those votes would have otherwise been wasted (and in some sense this makes every vote count, as opposed to FPP), and this effect is only possible when no candidate receives an outright majority of first preference votes. it is related to kingmakers in that the lesser-known candidates may encourage their supporters to rank the other candidates a certain way. Supporters of electoral reform generally see this as a positive development, and claim that alternatives certain to FPP will encourage less negative and more positive campaigning, as candidates will have to appeal to a wider group of people. Opinions are split on whether the alternative vote (better known as ] outside the UK) achieves this better than other systems.

=== Extremist parties ===
Supporters and opponents of FPP often argue whether FPP advantages or disadvantages extremist parties. Among single-winner systems, FPP suffers from the ], where more moderate candidates are squeezed out by more extreme ones. However, the different types (or the absence of) of party primaries maybe strengthen or weaken this effect. In general, FPP has no mechanism that would benefit more moderate candidates and many supporters of FPP defend it electing the largest and most unified (even if more polarizing) minority over a more consensual majority supported candidate. Allowing people into parliament who did not finish first in their district was described by ] as creating a "Parliament full of second-choices who no one really wanted but didn't really object to either."<ref>"]. " {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180118220917/http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/politics/av-referendum/8485118/David-Cameron-why-keeping-first-past-the-post-is-vital-for-democracy.html|date=18 January 2018}}." ''Daily Telegraph.'' 30 April 2011</ref>

However, FPP often results in ], which has prevented extreme left- and right-wing parties from gaining parliamentary seats{{Citation needed|date=September 2024}}, as opposed to ]. This also implies that strategic voting is necessary to keep extremists from gaining seats, which often fails to materialize in practice for multiple reasons. In comparison, many other systems encourage voters to rank other candidates and thereby not (or at least less often to) have to strategically compromise on their first choice at the same time.

On the other hand, ] published a report in April 2019 stating that, " FPP can ... abet ], since should a radical faction gain control of one of the major political parties, FPP works to preserve that party's position. ...This is because the psychological effect of the plurality system disincentivises a major party's supporters from voting for a minor party in protest at its policies, since to do so would likely only help the major party's main rival. Rather than curtailing extreme voices, FPP today empowers the (relatively) extreme voices of the Labour and Conservative party memberships."<ref>{{Cite news|first=Peter|last=Walker|date=22 April 2019|title=First past the post abets extreme politics, says thinktank|work=]|url=https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2019/apr/23/first-past-the-post-abets-extreme-politics-says-thinktank|archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20231206101252/https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2019/apr/23/first-past-the-post-abets-extreme-politics-says-thinktank|archive-date=6 December 2023|url-status=live|access-date=23 June 2020}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|title=The Electoral System and British Politics|url=https://consoc.org.uk/publications/the-electoral-system-and-british-politics/|website=consoc.org.uk|access-date=23 June 2020|archive-date=25 June 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200625171041/https://consoc.org.uk/publications/the-electoral-system-and-british-politics/|url-status=live}}</ref> For example, the ], a mixed system dominated by FPP have seen Fidesz (right-wing, populist party) win 135 seats in the ] and has remained the largest party in Hungary since ] by changing the electoral system to mostly use FPP instead of the previous mixed system using mostly the ]. Since 2010, Fidesz has implemented other anti-democratic reforms that now mean the European Parliament no longer qualifies Hungary as a full democracy.<ref>{{cite press release |title=MEPs: Hungary can no longer be considered a full democracy |date=15 September 2022 |publisher=] |url=https://www.europarl.europa.eu/news/en/press-room/20220909IPR40137/meps-hungary-can-no-longer-be-considered-a-full-democracy |ref=20220909IPR40137 |access-date=25 March 2023 |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220915103936/https://www.europarl.europa.eu/news/en/press-room/20220909IPR40137/meps-hungary-can-no-longer-be-considered-a-full-democracy |archive-date=15 September 2022}}</ref> Electoral reform campaigners have argued that the use of FPP in ] was a contributory factor in the country adopting the ] system after the ] in that country.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Cowen|first=Doug|title=The Graveyard of First Past the Post|url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/the-graveyard-of-first-past-the-post/|access-date=4 July 2020|website=Electoral Reform Society|archive-date=4 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200704094624/https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/the-graveyard-of-first-past-the-post/|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|last=Winter|first=Owen|date=25 August 2016|title=How a Broken Voting System Gave South Africa Apartheid in 1948|url=https://www.huffingtonpost.co.uk/owen-winter/south-africa-apartheid_b_11662272.html|access-date=4 July 2020|website=Huffington Post|archive-date=18 March 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210318014711/https://www.huffingtonpost.co.uk/owen-winter/south-africa-apartheid_b_11662272.html|url-status=live}}</ref> Leblang and Chan found that a country's electoral system is the most important predictor of a country's involvement in war, according to three different measures: (1) when a country was the first to enter a war; (2) when it joined a multinational coalition in an ongoing war; and (3) how long it stayed in a war after becoming a party to it.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Leblang |first1=D.|last2=Chan|first2=S.|date=2003|title=Explaining Wars Fought By Established Democracies: Do Institutional Constraints Matter?|journal=Political Research Quarterly|page=56-24: 385–400}}</ref><ref name="PR and Conflict">{{Cite web|title=PR and Conflict|url=https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/conflict|access-date=27 June 2020|website=Make Votes Matter|archive-date=31 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200731155640/https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/conflict|url-status=live}}</ref> When the people are fairly represented in parliament, more of those groups who may object to any potential war have access to the political power necessary to prevent it. In a proportional democracy, war and other major decisions generally requires the consent of the majority.<ref name="PR and Conflict" /><ref>{{Cite web|date=19 November 2017|title=What the Evidence Says|url=https://fairvotingbc.com/join-the-campaign-for-fair-voting/why-voting-reform/what-the-evidence-says/|access-date=27 June 2020|website=Fair Voting BC|archive-date=29 June 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200629185607/https://fairvotingbc.com/join-the-campaign-for-fair-voting/why-voting-reform/what-the-evidence-says/|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|date=3 May 2010|title=Democracy: we've never had it so bad|url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2010/may/03/democracy-first-past-the-post|access-date=27 June 2020|website=The Guardian|archive-date=22 May 2024|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240522102019/https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2010/may/03/democracy-first-past-the-post|url-status=live}}</ref> The British human rights campaigner ], and others, have argued that Britain entered the Iraq War primarily because of the political effects of FPP and that proportional representation would have prevented Britain's involvement in the war.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Tatchell|first=Peter|date=3 May 2010|title=Democracy: we've never had it so bad|url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2010/may/03/democracy-first-past-the-post|access-date=26 June 2020|website=The Guardian|archive-date=22 May 2024|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240522102019/https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2010/may/03/democracy-first-past-the-post|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|last=Barnett|first=Anthony|title=Will Labour's next leader finally break with first-past-the-post?|url=https://labourlist.org/2020/01/will-labours-next-leader-finally-break-with-first-past-the-post/|access-date=5 July 2020|website=Labourlist.org|date=10 January 2020|archive-date=5 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200705132235/https://labourlist.org/2020/01/will-labours-next-leader-finally-break-with-first-past-the-post/|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|last=Root|first=Tim|date=30 September 2019|title=Making government accountable to the people|url=https://leftfootforward.org/2019/09/making-government-accountable-to-the-people/|access-date=5 July 2020|website=Left Foot Forward|archive-date=31 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200731180947/https://leftfootforward.org/2019/09/making-government-accountable-to-the-people/|url-status=live}}</ref>


==Criticisms==
===Tactical voting=== ===Tactical voting===
{{Main|Strategic voting}}
{{main|Comparison of instant runoff voting to other voting systems}}
To a greater extent than many others, the first-past-the-post method encourages "tactical voting". Voters have an incentive to vote for a candidate who they predict is more likely to win, as opposed to their preferred candidate who may be unlikely to win and for whom a vote could be considered as ]. FPP wastes fewer votes when it is used in two-party contests. But waste of votes and minority governments are more likely when large groups of voters vote for three, four or more parties as in Canadian elections. Canada uses FPP and only two of the last seven federal Canadian elections (] and ]) produced single-party majority governments. In none of them did the leading party receive a majority of the votes.


The position is sometimes summarized, in an extreme form, as "all votes for anyone other than the runner-up are votes for the winner."<ref>{{Cite web |last=Begany |first=Brent |date=2016-06-30 |title=The 2016 Election Proves The Need For Voting Reform |url=https://policyinterns.com/2016/06/30/the-2016-election-proves-the-need-for-voting-reform/ |access-date=2019-10-22 |website=Policy Interns |language=en |archive-date=22 October 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191022182755/https://policyinterns.com/2016/06/30/the-2016-election-proves-the-need-for-voting-reform/ |url-status=live }}</ref> This is because votes for these other candidates deny potential support from the second-placed candidate, who might otherwise have won. Following the extremely close ], some supporters of ] candidate ] believed one reason he lost to ] ] is that a portion of the electorate (2.7%) voted for ] of the ], and exit polls indicated that more of them would have preferred Gore (45%) to Bush (27%).<ref>{{Cite news |last=Rosenbaum |first=David E. |date=24 February 2004 |title=THE 2004 CAMPAIGN: THE INDEPENDENT; Relax, Nader Advises Alarmed Democrats, but the 2000 Math Counsels Otherwise |work=The New York Times |url=https://query.nytimes.com/gst/fullpage.html?res=9B03E4D6173CF937A15751C0A9629C8B63 |access-date=7 February 2017 |archive-date=19 September 2008 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080919015320/http://query.nytimes.com/gst/fullpage.html?res=9B03E4D6173CF937A15751C0A9629C8B63 |url-status=live }}</ref> The election was ultimately determined by the ], where Bush prevailed over Gore by a margin of only 537 votes (0.009%), which was far exceeded by the 97488 (1.635%) votes cast for Nader in that state.
To a greater extent than many other electoral methods, the first-past-the-post system encourages ]. Voters have an incentive to vote for one of the two candidates they predict are most likely to win, even if they would prefer another of the candidates to win, because a vote for any other candidate will likely be "]" and have no impact on the final result.


In ], there has been a tendency for ] voters to support ] candidates. This phenomenon is responsible for some Popular victories, even though the ] have the most voters on the island, and is so widely recognised that Puerto Ricans sometimes call the Independentistas who vote for the Populares "melons", because that fruit is green on the outside but red on the inside (in reference to the party colors).
The position is sometimes summed up, in an extreme form, as "All votes for anyone other than the second place are votes for the winner", because by voting for other candidates, they have denied those votes to the second place candidate who could have won had they received them. Following the ], some supporters of ] candidate ] believed he lost the extremely close election to ] ] because a portion of the electorate (2.7%) voted for ] of the ], and exit polls indicated that more of these voters would have preferred Gore (45%) to Bush (27%), with the rest not voting in Nader's absence.<ref>{{cite web|last=Rosenbaum |first=David E. |url=http://query.nytimes.com/gst/fullpage.html?res=9B03E4D6173CF937A15751C0A9629C8B63 |title=THE 2004 CAMPAIGN: THE INDEPENDENT; Relax, Nader Advises Alarmed Democrats, but the 2000 Math Counsels Otherwise |publisher=New York Times |date=2004-02-24 |accessdate=2010-05-08}}</ref>


Because voters have to predict who the top two candidates will be, results can be significantly distorted:
In ], there are three principal voter groups: the ] (pro-independence), the ] (pro-]), and the ] (pro-]). Historically, there has been a tendency for Independentista voters to elect Popular candidates and policies. This phenomenon is responsible for some Popular victories, even though the Estadistas have the most voters on the island. It is so widely recognised that the Puerto Ricans sometimes call the Independentistas who vote for the Populares "melons", because the fruit is green on the outside but red on the inside (in reference to the party colors).
* Some voters will vote based on their view of how others will vote as well, changing their originally intended vote;
* Substantial power is given to the media, because some voters will believe its assertions as to who the leading contenders are likely to be. Even voters who distrust the media will know that others ''do'' believe the media, and therefore those candidates who receive the most media attention will probably be the most popular;
* A new candidate with no track record, who might otherwise be supported by the majority of voters, may be considered unlikely to be one of the top two, and thus lose votes to tactical voting;
* The method may promote votes ''against'' as opposed to votes ''for''. For example, in the UK (and only in the ] region), entire campaigns have been organised with the aim of voting ''against'' the ] by voting ], ] in ] and ], and since 2015 the ] in ], depending on which is seen as best placed to win in each locality. Such behavior is difficult to measure objectively.


Proponents of other voting methods in ]s argue that these would reduce the need for tactical voting and reduce the ]. Examples include preferential voting systems, such as ], as well as the ] of runoffs and less tested methods such as ] and ]s.
Because voters have to predict in advance who the top two candidates will be, results can be significantly distorted:
]s are seen as those cast for losing candidates, and for winning candidates in excess of the number required for victory. For example, in the ], 52% of votes were cast for losing candidates and 18% were excess votes—a total of 70% "wasted" votes. On this basis a large majority of votes may play no part in determining the outcome. This winner-takes-all system may be one of the reasons why "voter participation tends to be lower in countries with FPP than elsewhere."<ref>{{Cite book|last=Drogus|first=Carol Ann|url=https://archive.org/details/introducingcompa00drog/page/257|title=Introducing comparative politics: concepts and cases in context|publisher=CQ Press|year=2008|isbn=978-0-87289-343-6|pages=|url-access=registration}}</ref>


===Geography===
*Substantial power is given to the media. Some voters will tend to believe the media's assertions as to who the leading contenders are likely to be in the election. Even voters who distrust the media will know that other voters ''do'' believe the media, and therefore that those candidates who receive the most media attention will probably be the most popular and thus most likely to be the top two.
The effect of a system based on plurality voting spread over many separate districts is that the larger parties, and parties with more geographically concentrated support, gain a disproportionately large share of seats, while smaller parties with more evenly distributed support gain a disproportionately small share. This is because in doing this they win many seats and do not 'waste' many votes in other areas. As voting patterns are similar in about two-thirds of the districts, it is more likely that a single party will hold a majority of legislative seats under FPP than happens in a proportional system, and under FPP it is rare to elect a majority government that actually has the support of a majority of voters. Because FPP permits many ]s, an election under FPP is more easily gerrymandered. Through ], electoral areas are designed deliberately to unfairly increase the number of seats won by one party by redrawing the map such that one party has a small number of districts in which it has an overwhelming majority of votes (whether due to policy, demographics which tend to favor one party, or other reasons), and many districts where it is at a smaller disadvantage.{{citation needed|date=June 2020}}


The British ] (ERS) says that regional parties benefit from this system. "With a geographical base, parties that are small UK-wide can still do very well".<ref name="First Past the Post">{{Cite web |title=First Past the Post |url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/voting-systems/types-of-voting-system/first-past-the-post/ |access-date=2019-12-16 |website=electoral-reform.org.uk |language=en-US |archive-date=13 December 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191213064535/https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/voting-systems/types-of-voting-system/first-past-the-post/ |url-status=live }}</ref>
*A new candidate with no track record, who might otherwise be supported by the majority of voters, may be considered unlikely to be one of the top two candidates; thus they will receive fewer votes, which will then give them a reputation as a low poller in future elections, perpetuating the position.


On the other hand, minor parties that do not concentrate their vote usually end up getting a much lower proportion of seats than votes, as they lose most of the seats they contest and 'waste' most of their votes.<ref name="electoral-reform1">{{Cite web |title=First Past the Post |url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/voting-systems/types-of-voting-system/first-past-the-post/ |access-date=2019-12-05 |website=electoral-reform.org.uk |language=en-US |archive-date=13 December 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191213064535/https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/voting-systems/types-of-voting-system/first-past-the-post/ |url-status=live }}</ref>
*The system may promote votes ''against'' as opposed to votes ''for''. In the UK, entire campaigns have been organised with the aim of voting ''against'' the ] by voting either ] or ]. For example, in a ] held by the Conservatives, with the Liberal Democrats as the second-place party and the Labour Party in third, Labour supporters might be urged to vote for the Liberal Democrat candidate (who has a smaller shortfall of votes to make up and more support in the constituency) rather than their own candidate, on the basis that Labour supporters would prefer an MP from a competing left/liberal party to a Conservative one.


The ERS also says that in FPP elections using many separate districts "small parties without a geographical base find it hard to win seats".<ref name="First Past the Post" />
*If enough voters use this tactic, the first-past-the-post system effectively becomes ] - a completely different system - in which the first round is held in the court of public opinion. A good example of this is believed to be the ].


] said that in the ], "the Green Party, Liberal Democrats and UKIP (minor, non-regional parties) received 11% of votes between them, yet they ''shared'' just 2% of seats", and in the ], "he same three parties received almost a quarter of all the votes cast, yet these parties ''shared'' just 1.5% of seats."<ref name=":0">{{Cite web |title=Make Votes Matter—Everything wrong with First Past the Post—Proportional Representation |url=https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/first-past-the-post |access-date=2019-12-16 |website=Make Votes Matter |language=en-GB |archive-date=2 November 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191102013320/https://www.makevotesmatter.org.uk/first-past-the-post |url-status=live }}</ref>
Proponents of other ] argue that their proposals would reduce the need for tactical voting and reduce the ]. Examples include the commonly used ] of runoffs and ], along with less tested systems such as ] and ].


According to Make Votes Matter, in the 2015 UK general election ] came in third in terms of number of votes (3.9 million/12.6%), but gained only one seat in Parliament, resulting in one seat per 3.9 million votes. The Conservatives on the other hand received one seat per 34,000 votes.<ref name=":0" />
===Effect on political parties===


The winner-takes-all nature of FPP leads to distorted patterns of representation, since it exaggerates the correlation between party support and geography.
]]]
] is an idea in ] which says that constituencies that use first-past-the-post systems will become ]s, given enough time. Economist ] explains:


For example, in the UK the ] represents most of the rural seats in England, and most of the south of England, while the ] represents most of the English cities and most of the north of England.<ref>{{Cite journal |title=Divided by Values: Jeremy Corbyn, the Labour Party and England's 'North-South Divide' |last1=Beech |first1=Matt |date=2020-07-03 |url=https://journals.openedition.org/rfcb/5456 |last2=Hickson |first2=Kevin|journal=Revue Française de Civilisation Britannique |volume=XXV |issue=2 |doi=10.4000/rfcb.5456 |s2cid=198655613 |doi-access=free }}</ref> This pattern hides the large number of votes for the non-dominant party. Parties can find themselves without elected politicians in significant parts of the country, heightening feelings of regionalism. Party supporters (who may nevertheless be a significant minority) in those sections of the country are unrepresented.
{{Quote|The main reason for America's majoritarian character is the electoral system for Congress. Members of Congress are elected in single-member districts according to the "first-past-the-post" (FPTP) principle, meaning that the candidate with the plurality of votes is the winner of the congressional seat. The losing party or parties win no representation at all. The first-past-the-post election tends to produce a small number of major parties, perhaps just two, a principle known in political science as Duverger's Law. Smaller parties are trampled in first-past-the-post elections.|from Sachs' ''The Price of Civilization'', 2011<ref name=twsM18xxuy>{{cite book
| last = Sachs
| first = Jeffrey
| title = ''The Price of Civilization''
| publisher = Random House
| date = 2011
| location = New York
| pages = 107
| language = English
| isbn = 978-1-4000-6841-8}}</ref>}}


In the 2019 Canadian federal election ] won 98% of the seats in Alberta and Saskatchewan with only 68% of the vote. The lack of non-Conservative representation gives the appearance of greater Conservative support than actually exists.<ref>{{Cite web |title=First Past the Post |url=http://www.conservativeelectoralreform.org/support-reform/first-past-the-post/ |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171115214736/http://www.conservativeelectoralreform.org/support-reform/first-past-the-post/ |archive-date=15 November 2017 |access-date=15 November 2017 |website=conservativeelectoralreform.org |publisher=Conservative Action for Electoral Reform}}</ref> Similarly, in Canada's 2021 elections, the Conservative Party won 88% of the seats in Alberta with only 55% of the vote, and won 100% of the seats in Saskatchewan with only 59% of the vote.<ref>{{cite web |url=https://enr.elections.ca/Provinces.aspx |title=Elections Canada – Results by Province(s) |work=2021 Elections Canada – Provinces |publisher=Elections Canada |date=2020-09-21 |access-date=2021-11-04 |archive-date=9 December 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221209014337/https://enr.elections.ca/Provinces.aspx |url-status=live }}</ref>
First-past-the-post tends to reduce the number of viable political parties to a greater extent than most other methods, thus making it more likely that a single party will hold a majority of legislative seats. (In the ], 18 out of 23 general elections since 1922 have produced a single party majority government.)


First-past-the-post within geographical areas tends to deliver (particularly to larger parties) a significant number of ]s, where a representative is sheltered from any but the most dramatic change in voting behavior. In the UK, the Electoral Reform Society estimates that more than half the seats can be considered as safe.<ref>{{Cite web|date=2010-04-07|title=General Election 2010: Safe and marginal seats|url=https://www.theguardian.com/news/datablog/2010/apr/07/election-safe-seats-electoral-reform|access-date=15 November 2017|website=The Guardian|archive-date=3 March 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160303235530/http://www.theguardian.com/news/datablog/2010/apr/07/election-safe-seats-electoral-reform|url-status=live}}</ref> It has been claimed that members involved in the 2009 ] were significantly more likely to hold a safe seat.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Wickham|first=Alex|title="Safe seats" almost guarantee corruption|url=http://www.thecommentator.com/article/3678/_safe_seats_almost_guarantee_corruption|access-date=15 November 2017|website=thecommentator.com|archive-date=15 April 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210415082539/http://www.thecommentator.com/article/3678/_safe_seats_almost_guarantee_corruption|url-status=dead}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|title=FactCheck: expenses and safe seats|url=http://www.channel4.com/news/articles/uk/factcheck+expenses+and+safe+seats/3388597.html|access-date=15 November 2017|website=channel4.com|publisher=Channel 4|archive-date=8 May 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210508102457/http://www.channel4.com/news/articles/uk/factcheck+expenses+and+safe+seats/3388597.html|url-status=live}}</ref>
FPTP's tendency toward fewer parties and more frequent one-party rule can potentially produce a government that may not consider as wide a range of perspectives and concerns. It is entirely possible that a voter will find that all major parties agree on a particular issue. In this case, the voter will not have any meaningful way of expressing a dissenting opinion through his or her vote.


==History==
As fewer choices are offered to the voters, voters may vote for a candidate with whom they largely disagree so as to oppose a candidate with whom they disagree even more (See tactical voting above). The downside of this is that candidates will less closely reflect the viewpoints of those who vote for them.
The ] originated in the Middle Ages as an assembly representing the gentry of the counties and cities of the Kingdom, each of which elected either one or two members of parliament (MPs) by ]. Starting in the 19th century, ] advocates pushed to replace these multi-member constituencies with single-member districts.{{Cn|date=September 2024}} Elections to the Canadian ] have always been conducted with FPP.{{Cn|date=September 2024}}


The ] broke away from British rule in the late 18th century, and its constitution provides for an electoral college to elect its president. Despite original intentions to the contrary, by the mid-19th century this college had transformed into a ''de facto'' use of FPP for each state's presidential election. This further morphed through the introduction of the ], which made American elections into a ] in practice.
It may also be argued that one-party rule is more likely to lead to radical changes in government policy that are only favoured by a plurality or bare majority of the voters, whereas multi-party systems usually require greater consensus in order to make dramatic changes.


===Wasted votes=== ===Criticism and replacement===
{{multiple image
]s are votes cast for losing candidates or votes cast for winning candidates in excess of the number required for victory. For example, in the ], 52% of votes were cast for losing candidates and 18% were excess votes - a total of 70% wasted votes. This is perhaps the most fundamental criticism of FPTP, that a large majority of votes may play no part in determining the outcome. This "winner-takes-all" system may be one of the reasons why "voter participation tends to be lower in countries with FPTP than elsewhere."<ref>{{cite book|last=Drogus|first=Carol Ann|title=Introducing comparative politics: concepts and cases in context|year=2008|publisher=CQ Press|isbn=978-0-87289-343-6|pages=257}}</ref>
| direction = vertical
| width = 250
| footer = People campaigning against first-past-the-post and in favour of proportional representation
| image1 = Guelph Rally on Electoral Reform - National Day of Action for Electoral Reform - 11 Feb 2017 - 04.jpg
| image2 = Make Votes Matter ! No to FPTP. Yes to PR. (51868539320).jpg
}}
Non-plurality voting systems have been devised since at least 1299, when ] came up with both the Condorcet and ] methods, which were respectively reinvented in the 18th century by the ] and ]. More serious investigation into electoral systems came in the late 18th century, when several thinkers independently proposed systems of ] to elect legislatures. The ] in particular was invented in 1819 by ], and first used in a public election in 1840 by his son ] for the ] in Australia. STV saw its first national use in Denmark in 1855, and was reinvented several times in the 19th century.


The Proportional Representation Society was founded in England in 1884 and began campaigning. STV was used to elect the British House of Commons's ] between 1918 and their abolition in 1950.{{Cn|date=September 2024}}
===Manipulation charges===
The presence of ]s often gives rise to suspicions that ] has taken place. The spoiler may have received incentives to run. A spoiler may also drop out at the last moment, inducing charges that such an act was intended from the beginning.


Many countries which use FPP have active campaigns to switch to proportional representation (e.g. UK<ref>{{Cite web |title=What We Stand For |url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/who-we-are/what-we-stand-for/ |website=electoral-reform.org.uk |access-date=25 June 2020 |archive-date=26 June 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200626022218/https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/who-we-are/what-we-stand-for/ |url-status=live }}</ref> and Canada<ref>{{Cite web |title=Home |url=https://www.fairvote.ca/ |website=Fair Vote Canada |access-date=25 June 2020 |archive-date=1 July 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200701200741/https://www.fairvote.ca/ |url-status=live }}</ref>). Most modern democracies use some form of proportional representation.<ref>{{cite web |title=Electoral Systems around the World |url=https://www.fairvote.org/research_electoralsystems_world |website=FairVote.org |access-date=18 July 2020 |archive-date=11 September 2021 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210911132640/https://www.fairvote.org/research_electoralsystems_world |url-status=dead }}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |title=Labour Campaign for Electoral Reform – About LCER |url=https://www.labourcampaignforelectoralreform.org.uk/About-LCER |website=labourcampaignforelectoralreform.org.uk |access-date=25 June 2020 |archive-date=11 August 2021 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210811033648/https://www.labourcampaignforelectoralreform.org.uk/About-LCER |url-status=dead }}</ref>
===Disproportionate influence of smaller parties===
Smaller parties can disproportionately change the outcome of an FPTP election by swinging what is called the 50-50% balance of two party systems, by creating a ] within one or both ends of the ] which shifts the winner of the election from an ] outcome to a ] outcome favouring the previously less favoured party. In comparison, for electoral systems using ] small groups win only their proportional share of representation. However in PR systems, small parties can become decisive in Parliament so gaining a power of blackmail against the Government, a problem which is generally reduced by the FPTP system.<ref>{{cite web|last=Ilan |first=Shahar |url=http://www.haaretz.com/hasen/spages/1063585.html |title=about blackmail power of Israeli small parties under PR |publisher=Haaretz.com |date= |accessdate=2010-05-08}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.uab.ro/reviste_recunoscute/reviste_drept/annales_10_2007/macavei_en.pdf |title=Dr.Mihaela Macavei, University of Alba Iulia. |format=PDF |date= |accessdate=2010-05-08}}</ref>


== Countries using FPP ==
==Voting system criteria==
{{Main|Comparison of instant runoff voting to other voting systems#Voting system criteria}}


=== Legislatures elected exclusively by single-member plurality ===
Scholars rate voting systems using mathematically-derived ], which describe desirable features of a system. No ranked preference method can meet all of the criteria, because some of them are mutually exclusive, as shown by statements such as ] and the ].<ref>David Austen-Smith and Jeffrey Banks, "Monotonicity in Electoral Systems," ''American Political Science Review'', Vol 85, No 2 (Jun. 1991)</ref>
The following is a list of countries currently following the first-past-the-post voting system for their national legislatures.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Countries using FPTP electoral system for national legislature |url=http://www.idea.int/esd/type.cfm?electoralSystem=FPTP |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20141006214357/http://www.idea.int/esd/type.cfm?electoralSystem=FPTP |archive-date=6 October 2014 |access-date=3 December 2018 |website=idea.int}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |title=Electoral Systems |url=http://aceproject.org/epic-en/CDTable?question=ES005 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://archive.today/20140826220250/http://aceproject.org/epic-en/CDTable?question=ES005 |archive-date=26 August 2014 |access-date=3 November 2015 |publisher=ACE Electoral Knowledge Network}}</ref>
]


{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
===Majority criterion===
*{{Flagicon|Antigua and Barbuda}} ]
{{Tick}} The ''']''' states that "if one candidate is preferred by a majority (more than 50%) of voters, then that candidate must win".<ref> "Majority Favorite Criterion: If a majority (more than 50%) of voters consider candidate A to be the best choice, then A should win."</ref> First-past-the-post meets this criterion (though not the converse: a candidate does not need 50% of the votes in order to win). Although the criterion is met for each constituency vote, it is not met when adding up the total votes for a winning party in a parliament.
*{{Flagicon|Azerbaijan}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Bahamas}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Bangladesh}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Barbados}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Belarus}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Belize}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Botswana}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Canada}} ] (for the ] only)
*{{Flagicon|Dominica}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Eritrea}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Eswatini}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Ethiopia}} ]
*{{Flagicon|The Gambia}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Ghana}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Grenada}} ]
*{{Flagicon|India}} ] (for the ] only)
*{{Flagicon|Jamaica}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Kenya}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Liberia}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Malaysia}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Malawi}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Maldives}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Mauritius}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Federated States of Micronesia}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Myanmar}} ] (both houses)
*{{Flagicon|Nigeria}} ] (both houses)
*{{Flagicon|Palau}} ] (lower house only)
*{{Flagicon|Qatar}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Saint Kitts and Nevis}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Saint Lucia}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Saint Vincent and the Grenadines}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Samoa}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Solomon Islands}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Tonga}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Trinidad and Tobago}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Uganda}} ]
*{{Flagicon|United Kingdom}} ] (for the ] only)
*{{Flagicon|Yemen}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Zambia}} ]
{{div col end}}


===Condorcet winner criterion=== ==== Upper house only ====
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
{{Cross}}<ref name="lse27685"/> The ''']''' criterion states that "if a candidate would win a ] against every other candidate, then that candidate must win the overall election". First-past-the-post does not<ref name="lse27685">Felsenthal, Dan S. (2010) . In: Assessing Alternative Voting Procedures, London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK.</ref> meet this criterion.
*{{Flagicon|Bhutan}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Dominican Republic}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Poland}} ]
{{div col end}}


===Condorcet loser criterion=== ==== Varies by state ====
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
{{Cross}}<ref name="lse27685"/> The ''']''' criterion states that "if a candidate would lose a ] against every other candidate, then that candidate must not win the overall election". First-past-the-post does not<ref name="lse27685"/> meet this criterion.
*{{Flagicon|United States}} ] (both houses){{refn|group=footnote|name=first|Prior to the ], the US states of ] and ] completely abandoned FPTP in favor of ] or IRV. In the US, 48 of the 50 ] and the ] use FPTP-] to choose the electors of the ] (which in turn elects the president); Maine and ] use a variation where the electoral vote of each congressional district is awarded by FPTP (or by IRV in Maine beginning in 2020), and the statewide winner (using the same method used in each congressional district in the state) is awarded an additional two electoral votes. In states that employ FPTP-GT, the presidential candidate gaining the greatest number of votes wins all the state's available electors (seats), regardless of the number or share of votes won (majority vs non-majority plurality), or the difference separating the leading candidate and the first runner-up.<ref>{{Cite web|title=Electoral College Frequently Asked Questions|url=https://www.archives.gov/federal-register/electoral-college/faq.html|access-date=23 October 2015 |date=6 July 2023 |archive-date=6 December 2023 |archive-url=https://archive.today/20231206102739/https://www.archives.gov/electoral-college/faq |url-status=live |work=]}}</ref>}}
{{div col end}}


==== Subnational legislatures ====
===Independence of irrelevant alternatives criterion===
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
{{Cross}} The ''']''' criterion states that "the election outcome remains the same even if a candidate who cannot win decides to run." First-past-the-post does not meet this criterion.
* {{Flagicon|Cook Islands}} ] (New Zealand)
* {{Flagicon|US Virgin Islands}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Bermuda}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Cayman Islands}} ]
{{div col end}}


=== Use of single-member plurality in mixed systems for electing legislatures ===
===Independence of clones criterion===
The following countries use single-member plurality to elect part of their national legislature, in different types of mixed systems.
{{Cross}} The ''']''' states that "the election outcome remains the same even if an identical candidate who is equally-preferred decides to run." First-past-the-post does not meet this criterion.

'''Alongside block voting (fully majoritarian systems) or as part of mixed-member majoritarian systems (semi-proportional representation)'''
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
*{{Flagicon|Brazil}} ] – in the ], alongside ] (alternating elections)
*{{Flagicon|Hungary}} ] – as part is a mixed system (parallel voting with partial compensation)
*{{Flagicon|Ivory Coast}} ] – in single-member electoral districts, alongside ]
*{{Flagicon|Iran}} ] – in single-member electoral districts for ], alongside ]
*{{Flagicon|Marshall Islands}} ] – in single-member electoral districts, alongside ]
*{{Flagicon|Oman}} ] – in single-member electoral districts, alongside ]
*{{Flagicon|Pakistan}} ] – alongside seats distributed proportional to seats already won
*{{Flagicon|Singapore}} ] – in single-member electoral districts, alongside ]
*{{Flagicon|Taiwan}} ] – as part is a mixed system (parallel voting){{div col end}}

'''As part of mixed-member proportional (MMP) or additional member systems (AMS)'''

{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
*{{Flagicon|Bolivia}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Lesotho}} ]
*{{Flagicon|New Zealand}} ]
*{{Flagicon|South Korea}} ] – as part is a mixed system (AMS and parallel voting)
Subnational legislatures
*{{Flagicon|Scotland}} ] (United Kingdom){{div col end}}

=== Heads of state elected by FPP ===
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
*{{Flagicon|Angola}} ] (] for the presidential and legislative elections)
*{{Flagicon|Bosnia and Herzegovina}} ] (one for each main ethnic group)
*{{Flagicon|Cameroon}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Democratic Republic of the Congo}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Equatorial Guinea}} ]
*{{Flagicon|The Gambia}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Guyana}} ] (] for the presidential and legislative elections)
*{{Flagicon|Honduras}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Iceland}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Kiribati}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Malawi}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Mexico}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Nicaragua}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Nigeria}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Palestine}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Panama}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Paraguay}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Philippines}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Rwanda}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Singapore}} ]
*{{Flagicon|South Korea}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Taiwan}} ] (from 1996 ])
*{{Flagicon|Tanzania}} ]
*{{Flagicon|Venezuela}} ]

{{div col end}}

===Former use===

{{incomplete list|date=July 2016}}
* ] (The ] uses ]. Only twice used FPTP, first between 1902 and 1905 used only in the {{ill|1904 Argentine legislative election|lt=elections of 1904|es|Elecciones legislativas de Argentina de 1904}},<ref>{{Cite book |last=Milia |first=Juan Guillermo |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=NStcCgAAQBAJ&pg=PA40 |title=El Voto. Expresión del poder ciudadano |date=2015 |publisher=Editorial Dunken |isbn=978-987-02-8472-7 |location=Buenos Aires |pages=40–41 }}{{Dead link|date=May 2024 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}</ref> and the second time between 1951 and 1957 used only in the ] and ].)<ref>{{Cite web |title=Law 14,032 |url=http://www.saij.gob.ar/legislacion/ley-nacional-14032.htm?bsrc=ci |website=Sistema Argentino de Información Jurídica |access-date=19 October 2017 |archive-date=20 October 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171020135532/http://www.saij.gob.ar/legislacion/ley-nacional-14032.htm?bsrc=ci |url-status=live }}</ref>
* ] (replaced by ] in 1918 for both the ] and the ], with ] being introduced to the Senate in 1948)
* ] (adopted in 1831, replaced by ] in 1899)—<ref name="winklerprins">{{cite encyclopedia | title=Kiesstelsel. §1.1 Federale verkiezingen | encyclopedia=Encarta-encyclopedie Winkler Prins | publisher=Microsoft Corporation/Het Spectrum | year=1993–2002}}</ref> the ] for the ] is still elected by FPTP<ref>{{cite web | url=https://www.vrt.be/vrtnws/en/2019/03/20/elections-2019-the-european-parliament/ | title=Elections 2019: The European Parliament | work=Flanders News | date=17 April 2019 | access-date=2 December 2022 | quote=The European Parliament elections in Belgium will be held on 26 May, the same day as the regional and federal elections. In the European elections there are three Belgian constituencies: the Dutch-speaking electoral college, the Francophone electoral college and the German-speaking electoral college. | archive-date=6 April 2023 | archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230406012005/https://www.vrt.be/vrtnws/en/2019/03/20/elections-2019-the-european-parliament/ | url-status=live }}</ref>
* ] (replaced by ] in 1981)
* ] (replaced by ] in 1920)
* ] (adopted in 1995, replaced by ] in 1998)
* ] (used between 1860 and 1882, and between 1892 and 1919)
* ] (replaced by ] in ])
* ] (replaced by ] in June 2017)
* ] (replaced by ] ] in 2002)
* ] (replaced by ] in 1921)
* ] (replaced by ] in 1977)
* ] (replaced by ])<ref name="Upreti2010">{{Cite book |last=Bhuwan Chandra Upreti |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=TEq3D4evrO0C&pg=PA69 |title=Nepal: Transition to Democratic Republican State : 2008 Constituent Assembly |publisher=Gyan Publishing House |year=2010 |isbn=978-81-7835-774-4 |pages=69– |access-date=11 October 2016 |archive-date=22 May 2024 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240522102013/https://books.google.com/books?id=TEq3D4evrO0C&pg=PA69#v=onepage&q&f=false |url-status=live }}</ref>
* ] (replaced by ] in 1917)<ref>Encarta-encyclopedie Winkler Prins (1993–2002) s.v. "Kiesstelsel. §1.1 Geschiedenis". Microsoft Corporation/Het Spectrum.</ref>
* ] (replaced by ] in 1996)
* ] (replaced by ] in 2002)<ref>{{Cite web |date=12 December 2003 |title=PNG voting system praised by new MP |url=http://www.abc.net.au/ra/newstories/RANewsStories_1015553.htm |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20050104074304/http://www.abc.net.au/ra/newstories/RANewsStories_1015553.htm |archive-date=4 January 2005 |access-date=19 May 2015 |publisher=]}}</ref>
*] (replaced by ] in 1998 for House of Representatives elections, and by ] in 1941 for Senate elections)
* ] (replaced by ])<ref>{{Cite web|title=Which European countries use proportional representation?|url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/which-european-countries-use-proportional-representation/|access-date=2019-12-01|website=electoral-reform.org.uk|language=en-US|archive-date=27 December 2019|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191227222723/https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/which-european-countries-use-proportional-representation/|url-status=live}}</ref>
* ] (adopted in 1990, replaced by ] in 1992)<ref>{{Cite web |last1=MrdaljPolitikolog |first1=Mladen |last2=Univerzitetu |first2=Predavač na Webster |date=2020-10-08 |title=Sedam zabluda o uvođenju većinskog izbornog sistema |url=https://talas.rs/2020/10/08/sedam-zabluda-o-uvodenju-vecinskog-izbornog-sistema/ |access-date=2024-01-13 |website=Talas.rs |language=en-US |archive-date=13 January 2024 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240113164807/https://talas.rs/2020/10/08/sedam-zabluda-o-uvodenju-vecinskog-izbornog-sistema/ |url-status=live }}</ref>
*] (replaced by ] in 1994)
* ] (replaced by ] in 1995)


==See also== ==See also==

{{Portal|Politics}} {{Portal|Politics}}

* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ] * ]


==References== ==References==
{{reflist|2}} {{Reflist}}
{{reflist|group=footnote}}


==External links== ==External links==
{{commons category}}
* from
* from
*
* - Detailed explanation of first-past-the-post voting *
* * —detailed explanation of first-past-the-post voting
* *
* *
* *
*
* - week 5 gives a detailed description by David Farrell, of the University of Manchester (England), Elizabeth McLeay of Victoria University of Wellington, New Zealand.
*
*
* *
* {{YouTube|s7tWHJfhiyo|The Problems with First Past the Post Voting Explained (video)}}
*


{{voting systems}} {{Voting systems}}
{{2011 United Kingdom Alternative Vote referendum}}
{{Parliament of NZ}}


{{United Kingdom Alternative Vote referendum, 2011}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=May 2011}}
{{DEFAULTSORT:First-Past-The-Post}} {{DEFAULTSORT:First-Past-The-Post}}
] ]
]

]
]

Latest revision as of 01:53, 21 December 2024

Plurality voting system
This article has an unclear citation style. The references used may be made clearer with a different or consistent style of citation and footnoting. (July 2024) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
It has been suggested that this article be split into a new article titled Single-member district. (discuss) (September 2024)
A joint Politics and Economics series
Social choice and electoral systems
Single-winner methodsSingle vote - plurality methods

Condorcet methods


Positional voting


Cardinal voting

Proportional representationParty-list

Quota-remainder methods


Approval-based committees


Fractional social choice


Semi-proportional representation

Mixed systemsBy results of combination
By mechanism of combination

By ballot type

Paradoxes and pathologiesSpoiler effects

Pathological response


Strategic voting


Paradoxes of majority rule

Social and collective choiceImpossibility theorems

Positive results

icon Mathematics portal
Countries that primarily use a first-past-the-post voting system for national legislative elections

First-past-the-post voting (FPTP), also known as first-preference plurality (FPP) or single-member district plurality (SMDP)—often shortened simply to plurality—is a single-winner voting rule. Voters typically mark one candidate as their favorite, and the candidate with the largest number of first-preference marks (a plurality) is elected, regardless of whether they have over half of all votes (a majority). The name first-past-the-post is a reference to gambling on horse races (where bettors would guess which horse they thought would be first past the finishing post). In social choice, FPP is generally treated as a degenerate variant of ranked voting, where voters rank the candidates, but only the first preference matters. As a result, FPP is usually implemented with a choose-one ballot, where voters place a single bubble next to their favorite candidate.

FPP has been used to elect the British House of Commons since the Middle Ages. Throughout the 20th century, many countries that previously used FPP have abandoned it in favor of other electoral systems, including the former British colonies of Australia and New Zealand.

Most U.S. states still officially retain FPP for most elections. However, the combination of partisan primaries with the two-party system mean the country has effectively used a variation on the two-round system since the 1970s, where the first round selects two major contenders who go on to receive the overwhelming majority of votes.

A first-past-the-post ballot for a single-member district. The voter must mark one (and only one).

Example

Tennessee and its four major cities: Memphis in the far west; Nashville in the center; Chattanooga in the east; and Knoxville in the far northeast

Suppose that Tennessee is holding an election on the location of its capital. The population is concentrated around four major cities. All voters want the capital to be as close to them as possible. The options are:

  • Memphis, the largest city, but far from the others (42% of voters)
  • Nashville, near the center of the state (26% of voters)
  • Chattanooga, somewhat east (15% of voters)
  • Knoxville, far to the northeast (17% of voters)

The preferences of each region's voters are:

42% of voters
Far-West
26% of voters
Center
15% of voters
Center-East
17% of voters
Far-East
  1. Memphis
  2. Nashville
  3. Chattanooga
  4. Knoxville
  1. Nashville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Knoxville
  4. Memphis
  1. Chattanooga
  2. Knoxville
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis
  1. Knoxville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis


In FPTP, only the first preferences matter. As such, the votes would be counted as 42% for Memphis, 26% for Nashville, 17% for Knoxville, and 15% for Chattanooga. Since Memphis has the most votes, it would win a FPTP election, even though it is far from the center of the state and a majority of voters would prefer Nashville. Similarly, instant-runoff voting would elect Knoxville, the easternmost city. This makes the election a center squeeze. By contrast, both Condorcet methods and score voting would return Nashville (the capital of Tennessee).

Properties and effects

Table of pathological behaviors
Pathology Explanation/details
☒N Frustrated majority The frustrated majority paradox occurs when a majority of voters prefer some candidate Alice to every other candidate, but Alice still loses the election. First-past-the-post is vulnerable to this paradox because of vote-splitting.
☒N Condorcet loser paradox The Condorcet loser paradox happens when a majority of voters prefer every other candidate to A, but Alice still wins. First-past-the-post is vulnerable to this paradox because of vote-splitting.
☒N Center squeeze The center squeeze describes a type of violation of Independence of irrelevant alternatives primarily affecting voting rules in the Plurality-rule_family where the Condorcet winner is eliminated in an early round or otherwise due to a lack of first-preference support.
☒N Spoiler effect A spoiler effect is when the results of an election between A and B is affected by voters' opinions on an unrelated candidate C. First-past-the-post does not meet this criterion, which makes it vulnerable to spoilers.
☒N Cloning paradox The cloning paradox is a particular kind of spoiler effect that involves several perfect copies, or "clones", of a candidate. Candidate-cloning causes vote-splitting in FPP.
☒N Best-is-worst paradox The best-is-worst paradox occurs when an electoral system declares the same candidate to be in first and last place, depending on whether voters rank candidates from best-to-worst or worst-to-best. FPP demonstrates this pathology, because a candidate can be both the FPP winner and also the anti-plurality loser.
☒N Lesser-evil voting Lesser-evil voting occurs when voters are forced to support a "lesser of two evils" by rating them higher than their actual favorite candidate. FPP is vulnerable to this pathology.
checkY Later-no-harm Since plurality does not consider later preferences on the ballot at all, it is impossible to either harm or help a favorite candidate by marking later preferences. Thus it passes both Later-No-Harm and Later-No-Help.
checkY Later-no-help
checkY Multiple-districts paradox The multiple-districts paradox refers to a particularly egregious kind of gerrymander, when it is possible to draw a map where a candidate who loses the election nevertheless manages to win in every electoral district. This is not possible under FPP, or other positional voting methods.
checkY Perverse response Perverse response occurs when a candidate loses as a result of receiving too much support from some voters, i.e. it is possible for a candidate to lose by receiving too many votes. FPP is not affected by this pathology.
checkY No-show paradox The no-show paradox is a situation where a candidate loses as a result of having too many supporters. In other words, adding a voter who supports A over B can cause A to lose to B. FPP is not affected by this pathology.

Two-party rule

Main article: Duverger's law
A graph showing the difference between the popular vote (inner circle) and the seats won by parties (outer circle) at the 2015 UK general election

Perhaps the most striking effect of FPP is the fact that the number of a party's seats in a legislature has nothing to do with its vote count in an election, only in how those votes were geographically distributed. This has been a target of criticism for the method, many arguing that a fundamental requirement of an election system is to accurately represent the views of voters. FPP often creates "false majorities" by over-representing larger parties (giving a majority of the parliamentary/legislative seats to a party that did not receive a majority of the votes) while under-representing smaller ones. In Canada, majority governments have been formed due to one party winning a majority of the votes cast in Canada only three times since 1921: in 1940, 1958 and 1984. In the United Kingdom, 19 of the 24 general elections since 1922 have produced a single-party majority government. In all but two of them (1931 and 1935), the leading party did not take a majority of the votes across the UK.

In some cases, this can lead to a party receiving the plurality or even majority of total votes yet still failing to gain a plurality of legislative seats. This results in a situation called a majority reversal or electoral inversion. Famous examples of the second-place party (in votes nationally) winning a majority of seats include the elections in Ghana in 2012, New Zealand in 1978 and 1981, and the United Kingdom in 1951. Famous examples of the second placed party (in votes nationally) winning a plurality of seats include the elections in Canada in 2019 and 2021 as well as in Japan in 2003. Even when a party wins more than half the votes in an almost purely two-party-competition, it is possible for the runner-up to win a majority of seats. This happened in Saint Vincent and the Grenadines in 1966, 1998, and 2020 and in Belize in 1993. Even with only two parties and equally-sized constituencies, winning a majority of seats just requires receiving more than half the vote in more than half the districts—even if the other party receives all the votes cast in the other districts—so just over a quarter of the vote is theoretically enough to win a majority in the legislature. With enough candidates splitting the vote in a district, the total number of votes needed to win can be made arbitrarily small.

Two-party systems

Under first-past-the-post, a small party may draw votes and seats away from a larger party that it is more similar to, and therefore give an advantage to one it is less similar to. For example, in the 2000 United States presidential election, the left-leaning Ralph Nader drew more votes from the left-leaning Al Gore, resulting in Nader spoiling the election for the Democrats. According to the political pressure group Make Votes Matter, FPTP creates a powerful electoral incentive for large parties to target similar segments of voters with similar policies. The effect of this reduces political diversity in a country because the larger parties are incentivized to coalesce around similar policies. The ACE Electoral Knowledge Network describes India's use of FPTP as a "legacy of British colonialism".

Duverger's law is an idea in political science which says that constituencies that use first-past-the-post methods will lead to two-party systems, given enough time. Economist Jeffrey Sachs explains:

The main reason for America's majoritarian character is the electoral system for Congress. Members of Congress are elected in single-member districts according to the "first-past-the-post" (FPTP) principle, meaning that the candidate with the plurality of votes is the winner of the congressional seat. The losing party or parties win no representation at all. The first-past-the-post election tends to produce a small number of major parties, perhaps just two, a principle known in political science as Duverger's Law. Smaller parties are trampled in first-past-the-post elections.

— from Sachs's The Price of Civilization, 2011

However, most countries with first-past-the-post elections have multiparty legislatures (albeit with two parties larger than the others), the United States being the major exception. There is a counter-argument to Duverger's Law, that while on the national level a plurality system may encourage two parties, in the individual constituencies supermajorities will lead to the vote fracturing.

Strongholds, key constituencies and kingmakers

It has been suggested that the distortions in geographical representation provide incentives for parties to ignore the interests of areas in which they are too weak to stand much chance of gaining representation, leading to governments that do not govern in the national interest. Further, during election campaigns the campaigning activity of parties tends to focus on marginal seats where there is a prospect of a change in representation, leaving safer areas excluded from participation in an active campaign. Political parties operate by targeting districts, directing their activists and policy proposals toward those areas considered to be marginal, where each additional vote has more value.

This feature of FPTP has often been used by its supporters in contrast to proportional systems. In the latter, smaller parties act as 'kingmakers' in coalitions as they have greater bargaining power and therefore, arguably, their influence on policy is disproportional to their parliamentary size- this is largely avoided in FPP systems where majorities are generally achieved. FPP often produces governments which have legislative voting majorities, thus providing such governments the legislative power necessary to implement their electoral manifesto commitments during their term in office. This may be beneficial for the country in question in circumstances where the government's legislative agenda has broad public support, albeit potentially divided across party lines, or at least benefits society as a whole. However handing a legislative voting majority to a government which lacks popular support can be problematic where said government's policies favor only that fraction of the electorate that supported it, particularly if the electorate divides on tribal, religious, or urban–rural lines. There is also the perceived issue of unfair coalitions where a smaller party can form a coalition with other smaller parties and form a government, without a clear mandate as was the case in the 2009 Israeli legislative election where the leading party Kadima, was unable to form a coalition so Likud, a smaller party, managed to form a government without being the largest party. The use of proportional representation (PR) may enable smaller parties to become decisive in the country's legislature and gain leverage they would not otherwise enjoy, although this can be somewhat mitigated by a large enough electoral threshold. They argue that FPP generally reduces this possibility, except where parties have a strong regional basis. A journalist at Haaretz noted that Israel's highly proportional Knesset "affords great power to relatively small parties, forcing the government to give in to political blackmail and to reach compromises"; Tony Blair, defending FPP, argued that other systems give small parties the balance of power, and influence disproportionate to their votes.

The concept of kingmakers is adjacent to how Winston Churchill criticized the alternative vote system as "determined by the most worthless votes given for the most worthless candidates." meaning that votes for the least supported candidates may change the outcome of the election between the most supported candidates. In this case however, this is a feature of the alternative vote, since those votes would have otherwise been wasted (and in some sense this makes every vote count, as opposed to FPP), and this effect is only possible when no candidate receives an outright majority of first preference votes. it is related to kingmakers in that the lesser-known candidates may encourage their supporters to rank the other candidates a certain way. Supporters of electoral reform generally see this as a positive development, and claim that alternatives certain to FPP will encourage less negative and more positive campaigning, as candidates will have to appeal to a wider group of people. Opinions are split on whether the alternative vote (better known as instant runoff voting outside the UK) achieves this better than other systems.

Extremist parties

Supporters and opponents of FPP often argue whether FPP advantages or disadvantages extremist parties. Among single-winner systems, FPP suffers from the center squeeze phenomenon, where more moderate candidates are squeezed out by more extreme ones. However, the different types (or the absence of) of party primaries maybe strengthen or weaken this effect. In general, FPP has no mechanism that would benefit more moderate candidates and many supporters of FPP defend it electing the largest and most unified (even if more polarizing) minority over a more consensual majority supported candidate. Allowing people into parliament who did not finish first in their district was described by David Cameron as creating a "Parliament full of second-choices who no one really wanted but didn't really object to either."

However, FPP often results in strategic voting, which has prevented extreme left- and right-wing parties from gaining parliamentary seats, as opposed to proportional representation. This also implies that strategic voting is necessary to keep extremists from gaining seats, which often fails to materialize in practice for multiple reasons. In comparison, many other systems encourage voters to rank other candidates and thereby not (or at least less often to) have to strategically compromise on their first choice at the same time.

On the other hand, the Constitution Society published a report in April 2019 stating that, " FPP can ... abet extreme politics, since should a radical faction gain control of one of the major political parties, FPP works to preserve that party's position. ...This is because the psychological effect of the plurality system disincentivises a major party's supporters from voting for a minor party in protest at its policies, since to do so would likely only help the major party's main rival. Rather than curtailing extreme voices, FPP today empowers the (relatively) extreme voices of the Labour and Conservative party memberships." For example, the electoral system of Hungary, a mixed system dominated by FPP have seen Fidesz (right-wing, populist party) win 135 seats in the 2022 Hungarian parliamentary election and has remained the largest party in Hungary since 2010 by changing the electoral system to mostly use FPP instead of the previous mixed system using mostly the two-round system. Since 2010, Fidesz has implemented other anti-democratic reforms that now mean the European Parliament no longer qualifies Hungary as a full democracy. Electoral reform campaigners have argued that the use of FPP in South Africa was a contributory factor in the country adopting the apartheid system after the 1948 general election in that country. Leblang and Chan found that a country's electoral system is the most important predictor of a country's involvement in war, according to three different measures: (1) when a country was the first to enter a war; (2) when it joined a multinational coalition in an ongoing war; and (3) how long it stayed in a war after becoming a party to it. When the people are fairly represented in parliament, more of those groups who may object to any potential war have access to the political power necessary to prevent it. In a proportional democracy, war and other major decisions generally requires the consent of the majority. The British human rights campaigner Peter Tatchell, and others, have argued that Britain entered the Iraq War primarily because of the political effects of FPP and that proportional representation would have prevented Britain's involvement in the war.

Tactical voting

Main article: Strategic voting

To a greater extent than many others, the first-past-the-post method encourages "tactical voting". Voters have an incentive to vote for a candidate who they predict is more likely to win, as opposed to their preferred candidate who may be unlikely to win and for whom a vote could be considered as wasted. FPP wastes fewer votes when it is used in two-party contests. But waste of votes and minority governments are more likely when large groups of voters vote for three, four or more parties as in Canadian elections. Canada uses FPP and only two of the last seven federal Canadian elections (2011 and 2015) produced single-party majority governments. In none of them did the leading party receive a majority of the votes.

The position is sometimes summarized, in an extreme form, as "all votes for anyone other than the runner-up are votes for the winner." This is because votes for these other candidates deny potential support from the second-placed candidate, who might otherwise have won. Following the extremely close 2000 U.S. presidential election, some supporters of Democratic candidate Al Gore believed one reason he lost to Republican George W. Bush is that a portion of the electorate (2.7%) voted for Ralph Nader of the Green Party, and exit polls indicated that more of them would have preferred Gore (45%) to Bush (27%). The election was ultimately determined by the results from Florida, where Bush prevailed over Gore by a margin of only 537 votes (0.009%), which was far exceeded by the 97488 (1.635%) votes cast for Nader in that state.

In Puerto Rico, there has been a tendency for Independentista voters to support Populares candidates. This phenomenon is responsible for some Popular victories, even though the Estadistas have the most voters on the island, and is so widely recognised that Puerto Ricans sometimes call the Independentistas who vote for the Populares "melons", because that fruit is green on the outside but red on the inside (in reference to the party colors).

Because voters have to predict who the top two candidates will be, results can be significantly distorted:

  • Some voters will vote based on their view of how others will vote as well, changing their originally intended vote;
  • Substantial power is given to the media, because some voters will believe its assertions as to who the leading contenders are likely to be. Even voters who distrust the media will know that others do believe the media, and therefore those candidates who receive the most media attention will probably be the most popular;
  • A new candidate with no track record, who might otherwise be supported by the majority of voters, may be considered unlikely to be one of the top two, and thus lose votes to tactical voting;
  • The method may promote votes against as opposed to votes for. For example, in the UK (and only in the Great Britain region), entire campaigns have been organised with the aim of voting against the Conservative Party by voting Labour, Liberal Democrat in England and Wales, and since 2015 the SNP in Scotland, depending on which is seen as best placed to win in each locality. Such behavior is difficult to measure objectively.

Proponents of other voting methods in single-member districts argue that these would reduce the need for tactical voting and reduce the spoiler effect. Examples include preferential voting systems, such as instant runoff voting, as well as the two-round system of runoffs and less tested methods such as approval voting and Condorcet methods. Wasted votes are seen as those cast for losing candidates, and for winning candidates in excess of the number required for victory. For example, in the UK general election of 2005, 52% of votes were cast for losing candidates and 18% were excess votes—a total of 70% "wasted" votes. On this basis a large majority of votes may play no part in determining the outcome. This winner-takes-all system may be one of the reasons why "voter participation tends to be lower in countries with FPP than elsewhere."

Geography

The effect of a system based on plurality voting spread over many separate districts is that the larger parties, and parties with more geographically concentrated support, gain a disproportionately large share of seats, while smaller parties with more evenly distributed support gain a disproportionately small share. This is because in doing this they win many seats and do not 'waste' many votes in other areas. As voting patterns are similar in about two-thirds of the districts, it is more likely that a single party will hold a majority of legislative seats under FPP than happens in a proportional system, and under FPP it is rare to elect a majority government that actually has the support of a majority of voters. Because FPP permits many wasted votes, an election under FPP is more easily gerrymandered. Through gerrymandering, electoral areas are designed deliberately to unfairly increase the number of seats won by one party by redrawing the map such that one party has a small number of districts in which it has an overwhelming majority of votes (whether due to policy, demographics which tend to favor one party, or other reasons), and many districts where it is at a smaller disadvantage.

The British Electoral Reform Society (ERS) says that regional parties benefit from this system. "With a geographical base, parties that are small UK-wide can still do very well".

On the other hand, minor parties that do not concentrate their vote usually end up getting a much lower proportion of seats than votes, as they lose most of the seats they contest and 'waste' most of their votes.

The ERS also says that in FPP elections using many separate districts "small parties without a geographical base find it hard to win seats".

Make Votes Matter said that in the 2017 general election, "the Green Party, Liberal Democrats and UKIP (minor, non-regional parties) received 11% of votes between them, yet they shared just 2% of seats", and in the 2015 general election, "he same three parties received almost a quarter of all the votes cast, yet these parties shared just 1.5% of seats."

According to Make Votes Matter, in the 2015 UK general election UKIP came in third in terms of number of votes (3.9 million/12.6%), but gained only one seat in Parliament, resulting in one seat per 3.9 million votes. The Conservatives on the other hand received one seat per 34,000 votes.

The winner-takes-all nature of FPP leads to distorted patterns of representation, since it exaggerates the correlation between party support and geography.

For example, in the UK the Conservative Party represents most of the rural seats in England, and most of the south of England, while the Labour Party represents most of the English cities and most of the north of England. This pattern hides the large number of votes for the non-dominant party. Parties can find themselves without elected politicians in significant parts of the country, heightening feelings of regionalism. Party supporters (who may nevertheless be a significant minority) in those sections of the country are unrepresented.

In the 2019 Canadian federal election Conservatives won 98% of the seats in Alberta and Saskatchewan with only 68% of the vote. The lack of non-Conservative representation gives the appearance of greater Conservative support than actually exists. Similarly, in Canada's 2021 elections, the Conservative Party won 88% of the seats in Alberta with only 55% of the vote, and won 100% of the seats in Saskatchewan with only 59% of the vote.

First-past-the-post within geographical areas tends to deliver (particularly to larger parties) a significant number of safe seats, where a representative is sheltered from any but the most dramatic change in voting behavior. In the UK, the Electoral Reform Society estimates that more than half the seats can be considered as safe. It has been claimed that members involved in the 2009 expenses scandal were significantly more likely to hold a safe seat.

History

The House of Commons of England originated in the Middle Ages as an assembly representing the gentry of the counties and cities of the Kingdom, each of which elected either one or two members of parliament (MPs) by block plurality voting. Starting in the 19th century, electoral reform advocates pushed to replace these multi-member constituencies with single-member districts. Elections to the Canadian House of Commons have always been conducted with FPP.

The United States broke away from British rule in the late 18th century, and its constitution provides for an electoral college to elect its president. Despite original intentions to the contrary, by the mid-19th century this college had transformed into a de facto use of FPP for each state's presidential election. This further morphed through the introduction of the party primary, which made American elections into a two-round system in practice.

Criticism and replacement

People campaigning against first-past-the-post and in favour of proportional representation

Non-plurality voting systems have been devised since at least 1299, when Ramon Llull came up with both the Condorcet and Borda count methods, which were respectively reinvented in the 18th century by the Marquis de Condorcet and Jean-Charles de Borda. More serious investigation into electoral systems came in the late 18th century, when several thinkers independently proposed systems of proportional representation to elect legislatures. The single transferable vote in particular was invented in 1819 by Thomas Wright Hill, and first used in a public election in 1840 by his son Rowland for the Adelaide City Council in Australia. STV saw its first national use in Denmark in 1855, and was reinvented several times in the 19th century.

The Proportional Representation Society was founded in England in 1884 and began campaigning. STV was used to elect the British House of Commons's university constituencies between 1918 and their abolition in 1950.

Many countries which use FPP have active campaigns to switch to proportional representation (e.g. UK and Canada). Most modern democracies use some form of proportional representation.

Countries using FPP

Legislatures elected exclusively by single-member plurality

The following is a list of countries currently following the first-past-the-post voting system for their national legislatures.

Map showing countries where the lower house or unicameral national legislature is elected by FPTP (red) or mixed systems using FPTP (pink - mixed majoritarian, purple/lavender - mixed proportional/compensatory).

Upper house only

Varies by state

Subnational legislatures

Use of single-member plurality in mixed systems for electing legislatures

The following countries use single-member plurality to elect part of their national legislature, in different types of mixed systems.

Alongside block voting (fully majoritarian systems) or as part of mixed-member majoritarian systems (semi-proportional representation)

As part of mixed-member proportional (MMP) or additional member systems (AMS)

Subnational legislatures

Heads of state elected by FPP

Former use

This list is incomplete; you can help by adding missing items. (July 2016)

See also

References

  1. "First-past-the-post: a rogue's practice?". On Elections. 31 July 2018. Retrieved 9 September 2024.
  2. "First past the post". nzhistory.govt.nz. Ministry for Culture and Heritage. 13 January 2016. Archived from the original on 24 May 2022. Retrieved 25 May 2022.
  3. "First Past the Post and Alternative Vote explained". gov.uk. 6 September 2010. Archived from the original on 18 January 2024. Retrieved 13 July 2024.
  4. "The Boundaries Review is a chance to bring back multi-member constituencies". 26 September 2016.
  5. Santucci, Jack; Shugart, Matthew; Latner, Michael S. (16 October 2023). "Toward a Different Kind of Party Government". Protect Democracy. Archived from the original on 16 July 2024. Retrieved 16 July 2024. Finally, we should not discount the role of primaries. When we look at the range of countries with first-past-the-post (FPTP) elections (given no primaries), none with an assembly larger than Jamaica's (63) has a strict two-party system. These countries include the United Kingdom and Canada (where multiparty competition is in fact nationwide). Whether the U.S. should be called 'FPTP' itself is dubious, and not only because some states (e.g. Georgia) hold runoffs or use the alternative vote (e.g. Maine). Rather, the U.S. has an unusual two-round system in which the first round winnows the field. This usually is at the intraparty level, although sometimes it is without regard to party (e.g. in Alaska and California).
  6. Gallagher, Michael; Mitchell, Paul (15 September 2005). "The American Electoral System". The Politics of Electoral Systems. OUP Oxford. p. 192. ISBN 978-0-19-153151-4. American elections become a two-round run-off system with a delay of several months between the rounds.
  7. Bowler, Shaun; Grofman, Bernard; Blais, André (2009), "The United States: A Case of Duvergerian Equilibrium", Duverger's Law of Plurality Voting: The Logic of Party Competition in Canada, India, the United Kingdom and the United States, New York, NY: Springer, pp. 135–146, doi:10.1007/978-0-387-09720-6_9, ISBN 978-0-387-09720-6, retrieved 31 August 2024, In effect, the primary system means that the USA has a two-round runoff system of elections.
  8. ^ Felsenthal, Dan S. (2010) Review of paradoxes afflicting various voting procedures where one out of m candidates (m ≥ 2) must be elected Archived 24 February 2021 at the Wayback Machine. In: Assessing Alternative Voting Procedures, London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK.
  9. Geruso, Michael; Spears, Dean; Talesara, Ishaana (5 September 2019). "Inversions in US Presidential Elections: 1836-2016". American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. 14 (1): 327–357. doi:10.3386/w26247. PMC 10782436. PMID 38213750. Archived from the original on 19 March 2021. Retrieved 14 July 2021.
  10. Miller, Nicholas R. "Election Inversions By Variants of the U.S. Electoral College". Department of Political Science. UMBC. Archived from the original on 18 July 2021. Retrieved 14 July 2021.
  11. "First Past the Post". Make Votes Matter. Archived from the original on 31 July 2020. Retrieved 26 June 2020.
  12. "India – First Past the Post on a Grand Scale". ACE Electoral Knowledge Network. Retrieved 25 June 2020.
  13. Sachs, Jeffrey (2011). The Price of Civilization. New York: Random House. p. 107. ISBN 978-1-4000-6841-8.
  14. Dunleavy, Patrick; Diwakar, Rekha (2013). "Analysing multiparty competition in plurality rule elections" (PDF). Party Politics. 19 (6): 855–886. doi:10.1177/1354068811411026. S2CID 18840573. Archived (PDF) from the original on 9 June 2022. Retrieved 30 June 2016.
  15. Dickson, Eric S.; Scheve, Kenneth (2010). "Social Identity, Electoral Institutions and the Number of Candidates". British Journal of Political Science. 40 (2): 349–375. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.75.155. doi:10.1017/s0007123409990354. JSTOR 40649446. S2CID 7107526.
  16. "First Past the Post is a 'broken voting system'". ippr.org. Institute for Public Policy Research. 4 January 2011. Archived from the original on 15 November 2017. Retrieved 15 November 2017.
  17. Terry, Chris (28 August 2013). "In Britain's first past the post electoral system, some votes are worth 22 times more than others". democraticaudit.com. London School of Economics. Retrieved 15 November 2017.
  18. Galvin, Ray. "What is a marginal seat?". justsolutions.eu. Archived from the original on 15 November 2017. Retrieved 15 November 2017.
  19. ^ "First Past the Post". electoral-reform.org.uk. Archived from the original on 13 December 2019. Retrieved 5 December 2019.
  20. Brams/Kilgour. Dorey (2013). "Kingmakers and leaders in coalition formation". Social Choice and Welfare. 41 (1): 1–18. doi:10.1007/s00355-012-0680-4. hdl:10419/53209. JSTOR 42001390. S2CID 253849669. Archived from the original on 11 March 2023. Retrieved 11 March 2023.
  21. Andy Williams (1998). UK Government & Politics. Heinemann. p. 24. ISBN 978-0-435-33158-0. Archived from the original on 22 May 2024. Retrieved 11 October 2016.
  22. Ilan, Shahar. "Major Reforms Are Unlikely, but Electoral Threshold Could Be Raised". Haaretz. Archived from the original on 21 August 2019. Retrieved 8 May 2010.
  23. Macavei, Mihaela. "Advantages and disadvantages of the uninominal voting system" (PDF). Romania: University of Alba Iulia. Archived from the original (PDF) on 24 December 2019. Retrieved 8 May 2010.
  24. P. Dorey (17 June 2008). The Labour Party and Constitutional Reform: A History of Constitutional Conservatism. Palgrave Macmillan UK. pp. 400–. ISBN 978-0-230-59415-9.
  25. Larry Johnston (13 December 2011). Politics: An Introduction to the Modern Democratic State. University of Toronto Press. pp. 231–. ISBN 978-1-4426-0533-6.
  26. "David Cameron. "David Cameron: why keeping first past the post is vital for democracy Archived 18 January 2018 at the Wayback Machine." Daily Telegraph. 30 April 2011
  27. Walker, Peter (22 April 2019). "First past the post abets extreme politics, says thinktank". The Guardian. Archived from the original on 6 December 2023. Retrieved 23 June 2020.
  28. "The Electoral System and British Politics". consoc.org.uk. Archived from the original on 25 June 2020. Retrieved 23 June 2020.
  29. "MEPs: Hungary can no longer be considered a full democracy" (Press release). European Parliament. 15 September 2022. Archived from the original on 15 September 2022. Retrieved 25 March 2023.
  30. Cowen, Doug. "The Graveyard of First Past the Post". Electoral Reform Society. Archived from the original on 4 July 2020. Retrieved 4 July 2020.
  31. Winter, Owen (25 August 2016). "How a Broken Voting System Gave South Africa Apartheid in 1948". Huffington Post. Archived from the original on 18 March 2021. Retrieved 4 July 2020.
  32. Leblang, D.; Chan, S. (2003). "Explaining Wars Fought By Established Democracies: Do Institutional Constraints Matter?". Political Research Quarterly: 56-24: 385–400.
  33. ^ "PR and Conflict". Make Votes Matter. Archived from the original on 31 July 2020. Retrieved 27 June 2020.
  34. "What the Evidence Says". Fair Voting BC. 19 November 2017. Archived from the original on 29 June 2020. Retrieved 27 June 2020.
  35. "Democracy: we've never had it so bad". The Guardian. 3 May 2010. Archived from the original on 22 May 2024. Retrieved 27 June 2020.
  36. Tatchell, Peter (3 May 2010). "Democracy: we've never had it so bad". The Guardian. Archived from the original on 22 May 2024. Retrieved 26 June 2020.
  37. Barnett, Anthony (10 January 2020). "Will Labour's next leader finally break with first-past-the-post?". Labourlist.org. Archived from the original on 5 July 2020. Retrieved 5 July 2020.
  38. Root, Tim (30 September 2019). "Making government accountable to the people". Left Foot Forward. Archived from the original on 31 July 2020. Retrieved 5 July 2020.
  39. Begany, Brent (30 June 2016). "The 2016 Election Proves The Need For Voting Reform". Policy Interns. Archived from the original on 22 October 2019. Retrieved 22 October 2019.
  40. Rosenbaum, David E. (24 February 2004). "THE 2004 CAMPAIGN: THE INDEPENDENT; Relax, Nader Advises Alarmed Democrats, but the 2000 Math Counsels Otherwise". The New York Times. Archived from the original on 19 September 2008. Retrieved 7 February 2017.
  41. Drogus, Carol Ann (2008). Introducing comparative politics: concepts and cases in context. CQ Press. pp. 257. ISBN 978-0-87289-343-6.
  42. ^ "First Past the Post". electoral-reform.org.uk. Archived from the original on 13 December 2019. Retrieved 16 December 2019.
  43. ^ "Make Votes Matter—Everything wrong with First Past the Post—Proportional Representation". Make Votes Matter. Archived from the original on 2 November 2019. Retrieved 16 December 2019.
  44. Beech, Matt; Hickson, Kevin (3 July 2020). "Divided by Values: Jeremy Corbyn, the Labour Party and England's 'North-South Divide'". Revue Française de Civilisation Britannique. XXV (2). doi:10.4000/rfcb.5456. S2CID 198655613.
  45. "First Past the Post". conservativeelectoralreform.org. Conservative Action for Electoral Reform. Archived from the original on 15 November 2017. Retrieved 15 November 2017.
  46. "Elections Canada – Results by Province(s)". 2021 Elections Canada – Provinces. Elections Canada. 21 September 2020. Archived from the original on 9 December 2022. Retrieved 4 November 2021.
  47. "General Election 2010: Safe and marginal seats". The Guardian. 7 April 2010. Archived from the original on 3 March 2016. Retrieved 15 November 2017.
  48. Wickham, Alex. ""Safe seats" almost guarantee corruption". thecommentator.com. Archived from the original on 15 April 2021. Retrieved 15 November 2017.
  49. "FactCheck: expenses and safe seats". channel4.com. Channel 4. Archived from the original on 8 May 2021. Retrieved 15 November 2017.
  50. "What We Stand For". electoral-reform.org.uk. Archived from the original on 26 June 2020. Retrieved 25 June 2020.
  51. "Home". Fair Vote Canada. Archived from the original on 1 July 2020. Retrieved 25 June 2020.
  52. "Electoral Systems around the World". FairVote.org. Archived from the original on 11 September 2021. Retrieved 18 July 2020.
  53. "Labour Campaign for Electoral Reform – About LCER". labourcampaignforelectoralreform.org.uk. Archived from the original on 11 August 2021. Retrieved 25 June 2020.
  54. "Countries using FPTP electoral system for national legislature". idea.int. Archived from the original on 6 October 2014. Retrieved 3 December 2018.
  55. "Electoral Systems". ACE Electoral Knowledge Network. Archived from the original on 26 August 2014. Retrieved 3 November 2015.
  56. "Electoral College Frequently Asked Questions". National Archives. 6 July 2023. Archived from the original on 6 December 2023. Retrieved 23 October 2015.
  57. Milia, Juan Guillermo (2015). El Voto. Expresión del poder ciudadano. Buenos Aires: Editorial Dunken. pp. 40–41. ISBN 978-987-02-8472-7.
  58. "Law 14,032". Sistema Argentino de Información Jurídica. Archived from the original on 20 October 2017. Retrieved 19 October 2017.
  59. "Kiesstelsel. §1.1 Federale verkiezingen". Encarta-encyclopedie Winkler Prins. Microsoft Corporation/Het Spectrum. 1993–2002.
  60. "Elections 2019: The European Parliament". Flanders News. 17 April 2019. Archived from the original on 6 April 2023. Retrieved 2 December 2022. The European Parliament elections in Belgium will be held on 26 May, the same day as the regional and federal elections. In the European elections there are three Belgian constituencies: the Dutch-speaking electoral college, the Francophone electoral college and the German-speaking electoral college.
  61. Bhuwan Chandra Upreti (2010). Nepal: Transition to Democratic Republican State : 2008 Constituent Assembly. Gyan Publishing House. pp. 69–. ISBN 978-81-7835-774-4. Archived from the original on 22 May 2024. Retrieved 11 October 2016.
  62. Encarta-encyclopedie Winkler Prins (1993–2002) s.v. "Kiesstelsel. §1.1 Geschiedenis". Microsoft Corporation/Het Spectrum.
  63. "PNG voting system praised by new MP". Australian Broadcasting Corporation. 12 December 2003. Archived from the original on 4 January 2005. Retrieved 19 May 2015.
  64. "Which European countries use proportional representation?". electoral-reform.org.uk. Archived from the original on 27 December 2019. Retrieved 1 December 2019.
  65. MrdaljPolitikolog, Mladen; Univerzitetu, Predavač na Webster (8 October 2020). "Sedam zabluda o uvođenju većinskog izbornog sistema". Talas.rs. Archived from the original on 13 January 2024. Retrieved 13 January 2024.
  1. Prior to the 2020 election, the US states of Alaska and Maine completely abandoned FPTP in favor of Instant-runoff voting or IRV. In the US, 48 of the 50 states and the District of Columbia use FPTP-GT to choose the electors of the Electoral College (which in turn elects the president); Maine and Nebraska use a variation where the electoral vote of each congressional district is awarded by FPTP (or by IRV in Maine beginning in 2020), and the statewide winner (using the same method used in each congressional district in the state) is awarded an additional two electoral votes. In states that employ FPTP-GT, the presidential candidate gaining the greatest number of votes wins all the state's available electors (seats), regardless of the number or share of votes won (majority vs non-majority plurality), or the difference separating the leading candidate and the first runner-up.

External links

Electoral systems
Part of the politics and Economics series
Single-winner
Proportional
Systems
Allocation
Quotas
Mixed
Semi-proportional
Criteria
Other
Comparison
PortalProject
2011 United Kingdom Alternative Vote referendum
Results
Referendum question"At present, the UK uses the “first past the post” system to elect MPs to the House of Commons. Should the “alternative vote” system be used instead?"
Legislation
Parties
For a "Yes" vote
Neutral/split
For a "No" vote
Advocacy groups
Advocating a "Yes" vote
Advocating a "No" vote
Print media
For a "Yes" vote
For a "No" vote
Politics Portal
Parliament of New Zealand
Components
Parliamentary
officers
Legislative Council
House of
Representatives
Members
Legislative Council
House of
Representatives
Procedure
Elections
Locations
Miscellaneous
Categories: