Misplaced Pages

Economic inequality: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 04:44, 26 January 2015 editC.J. Griffin (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users, Pending changes reviewers, Rollbackers20,950 edits External links← Previous edit Latest revision as of 07:42, 2 December 2024 edit undoCitation bot (talk | contribs)Bots5,421,839 edits Added doi-broken-date. | Use this bot. Report bugs. | #UCB_CommandLine 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Distribution of income or wealth between different groups}}
{{About||the economic inequality among countries|international inequality}}
{{for|the more general social form|Social inequality}}
{{Use mdy dates|date=August 2014}}
{{other uses|Inequality (disambiguation){{!}}Inequality}}
{{See also|Social inequality}}
{{redirect|Rich and poor|other uses|Rich and Poor (disambiguation){{!}}Rich and Poor}}
{{split|Income inequality|Wealth concentration|date=February 2013}}
{{Use mdy dates|date=September 2021}}
]. The Gini coefficient is a number between 0 and 1, where 0 corresponds with perfect equality (where everyone has the same income) and 1 corresponds with absolute inequality (where one person has all the income, and everyone else has zero income).]]


]
'''Economic inequality''' (also described as '''the gap between rich and poor''', '''income inequality''', '''wealth disparity''', '''wealth and income differences''' or '''wealth gap''')<ref name="AP-20140127">{{cite news |last1=Rugaber |first1=Christopher S. |last2=Boak |first2=Josh |title=Wealth gap: A guide to what it is, why it matters |url=http://apnews.excite.com/article/20140127/DABJ40P00.html |date=January 27, 2014 |work=] |accessdate=January 27, 2014 }}</ref> is the state of affairs in which ], ], or ] are distributed unequally among individuals in a group, among groups in a population, or ]. The issue of economic inequality can implicate notions of ], ], and ].<ref name=WaPoLifespan>{{cite news|last=Fletcher|first=Michael A.|title=Research ties economic inequality to gap in life expectancy|url=http://www.washingtonpost.com/business/economy/research-ties-economic-inequality-to-gap-in-life-expectancy/2013/03/10/c7a323c4-7094-11e2-8b8d-e0b59a1b8e2a_story.html|accessdate=March 23, 2013|newspaper=Washington Post|date=March 10, 2013}}</ref>
] as of 2018.<ref name="auto">{{Cite web|title=GINI index (World Bank estimate) {{!}} Data|url=https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SI.POV.GINI?view=map|access-date=July 23, 2020|website=data.worldbank.org}}</ref> The Gini coefficient is a number between 0 and 100, where 0 corresponds with perfect equality (where everyone has the same income) and 100 corresponds with absolute inequality (where one person has all the income, and everyone else has zero income).]]
] by wealth group, Credit Suisse, 2021]]
{{multiple image | direction = horizontal |total_width=450
| header = Wealth disparity in major cities
| image1= Tenting in Los Angeles Skid Row.jpg | alt1 = Skid row tents | caption1 = Tents of the homeless on the sidewalk in ]
| image2 = The Manor, Holmby Hills, Los Angeles, in 2008.jpg | alt2 = a Beverly Hills mansion | caption2 = An affluent house in ], roughly 12 miles from downtown
}}
'''Economic inequality''' is an ] for a) income inequality or ] (how the total sum of money paid to people is distributed among them), b) ] or ] (how the total sum of wealth owned by people is distributed among the owners), and c) ] inequality (how the total sum of money spent by people is distributed among the spenders). Each of these can be measured between two or more nations, within a single nation, or between and within sub-populations (such as within a low-income group, within a high-income group and between them, within an age group and between inter-generational groups, within a gender group and between them etc, either from one or from multiple nations).<ref name="urlWealth Distribution and Income Inequality by Country 2018 | Global Finance Magazine">{{Cite web|url=https://www.gfmag.com/global-data/economic-data/wealth-distribution-income-inequality |title=World Wealth Distribution And Income Inequality 2022 |first1=Luca |last1=Ventura |website=Global Finance Magazine |date=June 6, 2023 }}</ref>


] are used for measuring income inequality,<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Trapeznikova |first1=Ija |title=Measuring income inequality |journal=IZA World of Labor |date=2019 |doi=10.15185/izawol.462 |url=https://wol.iza.org/articles/measuring-income-inequality|doi-access=free }}</ref> the ] being a widely used one. Another type of measurement is the ], which is a statistic composite index that takes inequality into account.<ref>Human Development Reports. {{Webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190712222023/http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/inequality-adjusted-human-development-index-ihdi |date=July 12, 2019}}. ''United Nations Development Programme''. Retrieved: March 3, 2019.</ref> Important concepts of equality include ], ], and ].
Some studies have emphasized inequality as a growing social problem.<ref name="Spirit Level">{{cite book |title=] |last=Wilkinson |first=Richard |authorlink= |author2=Pickett, Kate |year=2009 |publisher=Allen Lane |location= |isbn=978-1-84614-039-6 |page=352}}</ref> Too much inequality can be destructive,<ref name="biu.ac.il">Easterly, W. (2007) ''Journal of Development Economics'' '''84'''(2): 755-776.</ref><ref name=Castells-Quintana>{{cite journal|last=Castells-Quintana|first=David|first2=Vicente | last2 = Royuela|title=Unemployment and long-run economic growth: The role of income inequality and urbanisation|journal=Investigaciones Regionales|year=2012|volume=12|issue=24|pages=153–173|url=http://diposit.ub.edu/dspace/bitstream/2445/33140/1/617293.pdf|accessdate=17 October 2013}}</ref> because income inequality and wealth concentration can hinder long term growth.<ref name="ilo.org">Stiglitz, J. (2009) ''International Labour Review'' '''148'''(1-2).</ref><ref name="The New Growth Evidence">Temple, J. (1999) ''Journal of Economic Literature'' '''37'''(1): 112-156.</ref><ref name="www-wds.worldbank.org">Clarke, G. (1995) ''Journal of Development Economics'' '''47''': 403-427.</ref> Early statistical studies comparing inequality to economic growth had been inconclusive,<ref name=BanerjeeDuflo/> however in 2011, ] economists showed that greater income equality, less inequality, increased the duration of countries' economic growth spells more than free trade, low government ], foreign investment, or low ].<ref name=BergOstryEE />


], there has been a long-run trend towards greater economic inequality over time. The exceptions to this during the modern era are the declines in economic inequality during the two World Wars and amid the creation of modern ]s after World War II.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Alfani |first=Guido |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=nCHEEAAAQBAJ |title=As Gods Among Men: A History of the Rich in the West |date=2023 |publisher=Princeton University Press |isbn=978-0-691-22712-2 |language=en}}</ref> Whereas globalization has reduced the inequality between nations, it has increased the inequality within the population in most nations.<ref name=":9">{{Cite web |title=Introduction to Inequality |url=https://www.imf.org/en/Topics/Inequality/introduction-to-inequality |access-date=May 9, 2022 |website=IMF |language=en}}</ref><ref name=":10" /><ref name=":11" /><ref name=":12" /> Income inequality between nations peaked in the 1970s, when world income was ] into "rich" and "poor" countries. Since then, income levels across countries have been converging, with most people now living in ].<ref name=":9" /><ref>{{Cite web |date=January 22, 2010 |title=Parametric estimations of the world distribution of income |url=http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/4508}}</ref> However, inequality within the population in most has risen significantly in the last 30 years, particularly among ].<ref name=":9" /><ref name=":10">{{Cite book|last1=Bourguignon |first1=François |url=http://press.princeton.edu/titles/10433.html |title=The Globalization of Inequality |date=2015|publisher=Princeton University Press |isbn=978-0691160528|access-date=August 19, 2017}}</ref><ref name=":11">{{Cite journal|last=Hung|first=Ho-Fung|date=2021|title=Recent Trends in Global Economic Inequality |journal=Annual Review of Sociology|volume=47|issue=1|pages=349–367|doi=10.1146/annurev-soc-090320-105810 |s2cid=235574406|issn=0360-0572}}</ref><ref name=":12">{{Cite journal |last1=Flaherty|first1=Thomas M. |last2=Rogowski |first2=Ronald|date=2021|title=Rising Inequality As a Threat to the Liberal International Order |journal=International Organization|volume=75|issue=2|pages=495–523 |doi=10.1017/S0020818321000163 |issn=0020-8183|doi-access=free}}</ref>
Economic inequality varies between societies, historical periods, economic structures and systems. The term can refer to cross sectional distribution of income or wealth at any particular period, or to the lifetime income and wealth over longer periods of time.<ref>Wojciech Kopczuk, Emmanuel Saez, and Jae Song find that “most of the increase in the variance of (log) annual earnings is due to increases in the variance of (log) permanent earnings with modest increases in the variance of transitory (log) earnings.” Thus, in fact, the increase in earnings inequality is in lifetime income. Furthermore, they find that it remains difficult for someone to move up the earnings distribution (though they do find upward mobility for women in their lifetime). See their “Earnings Inequality and Mobility in the United States: Evidence from Social Security Data since 1937,” ''Quarterly Journal of Economics''. 125, no. 1 (2010): 91–128.</ref> There are various numerical ] for measuring economic inequality. A widely used one is the ], but there are also ]. Engerman and Sokoloff further explain economic inequality via historical institutions, as demonstrated by European colonial institutions of the Americas. See their "Inequality, institutions, and differential paths of growing among new world economies" 'Journal of Economic Perspectives' 14, no. 3 (2000) for further reading.


Research has generally linked economic inequality to political and social instability, including ], democratic breakdown and ].<ref name=":9" /><ref>{{Cite journal |last1=MacCulloch |first1=Robert |year=2005 |title=Income Inequality and the Taste for Revolution |journal=The Journal of Law and Economics |volume=48 |issue=1 |pages=93–123 |doi=10.1086/426881 |jstor=10.1086/426881 |s2cid=154993058}}</ref><ref name=":5">{{Cite book |last1=Acemoglu |first1=Daron |url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/books/economic-origins-of-dictatorship-and-democracy/3F29DF90519971B183CAA16ED0203507 |title=Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy |last2=Robinson |first2=James A. |date=2005 |publisher=Cambridge University Press |isbn=978-0521855266 |location=Cambridge |doi=10.1017/cbo9780511510809}}</ref><ref name=":6">{{Cite book |last1=Cederman |first1=Lars-Erik |last2=Gleditsch |first2=Kristian Skrede |last3=Buhaug |first3=Halvard |title=Inequality, Grievances, and Civil War |url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/books/inequality-grievances-and-civil-war/39F26D12EFEE2D7D621A59DF74DED496 |publisher=Cambridge University Press |year=2013|isbn=978-1107017429|doi=10.1017/cbo9781139084161}}</ref> Research suggests that greater inequality ] and macroeconomic stability, and that ] and ] inequality reduce growth more than inequality of income.<ref name=":9" /><ref name=":0">{{cite journal |last1=Neves |first1=Pedro Cunha |last2=Afonso |first2=Óscar |last3=Silva |first3=Sandra Tavares |year=2016 |title=A Meta-Analytic Reassessment of the Effects of Inequality on Growth |journal=World Development |volume=78 |pages=386–400 |doi=10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.10.038}}</ref> Inequality is at the center stage of economic policy debate across the globe, as government tax and spending policies have significant effects on income distribution.<ref name=":9" /> In advanced economies, taxes and transfers decrease income inequality by one-third, with most of this being achieved via public social spending (such as ]s and family benefits).<ref name=":9" /> While the "optimum" amount of economic inequality is widely debated, there is a near-universal belief that complete economic equality (Gini of zero) would be undesirable and unachieveable.{{ r | Peterson_2017 | p=1 | q=It is important to note that virtually no-one believes complete equality in the distribution of income and wealth is a desirable state of affairs. There is no clear agreement that an optimal level of inequality would be achieved at some given value for the Gini coefficient but there does appear to be widespread agreement that a value of zero would be unsuitable as well as impossible to achieve. The evidence from the Twentieth Century, however, shows that there can be great general prosperity with lower economic inequality than at present so that, given the clear distress caused by rising inequality, lowering it appears to be a worthy aspiration. }}
==Extent==
A study entitled "Divided we Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising” by the ] (OECD) reported its conclusions on the causes, consequences and policy implications for the ongoing intensification of the extremes of wealth and poverty across its 22 member nations (OECD 2011-12-05).<ref name="PR divided">{{cite report| url= http://www.oecd.org/document/22/0,3746,en_21571361_44315115_49185046_1_1_1_1,00.html |title=Press Release for Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising| publisher=OECD| author=Gurría, Angel| date=December 5, 2011| accessdate=December 16, 2011| doi=10.1787/9789264119536-en}}</ref>
* "Income inequality in OECD countries is at its highest level for the past half century. The average income of the richest 10% of the population is about nine times that of the poorest 10% across the OECD, up from seven times 25 years ago."<ref name="PR divided"/>
* ] has increased further from already high levels.<ref name="PR divided"/><ref name=gap>{{cite journal | title="Inflation-Gap Persistence in the US". Timothy Cogley, Giorgio E. Primiceri and Thomas J. Sargent. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. Vol. 2, No. 1 (January 2010), pp. 43–69. Published by: American Economic Association | jstor=25760284}}</ref>
* Referring to median incomes for the upper 10% contrasted with medians for the lowest 10%, "Other traditionally more egalitarian countries, such as ], ] and ], have seen the gap between rich and poor expand from 5 to 1 in the 1980s, to 6 to 1 today."<ref name="PR divided"/>


{{TOC limit|3}}
A study by the World Institute for Development Economics Research at ] reports that the richest 1% of adults alone owned 40% of global assets in the year 2000. The ] in the world possess more financial assets than the lowest 48 nations combined.<ref>http://articles.moneycentral.msn.com/News/StudyRevealsOverwhelmingWealthGap.aspx</ref> The combined wealth of the "10 million dollar millionaires" grew to nearly $41 trillion in 2008.<ref>"". ''Thaindian News''. June 25, 2008.</ref> A January 2014 report by ] claims that the 85 wealthiest individuals in the world have a combined wealth equal to that of the bottom 50% of the world's population, or about 3.5 billion people.<ref>. ''].'' January 20, 2014.</ref><ref>Neuman, Scott (January 20, 2014). . ''].'' Retrieved January 25, 2014.</ref><ref>{{cite web|last=Stout|first=David|title=One Stat to Destroy Your Faith in Humanity: The World’s 85 Richest People Own as Much as the 3.5 Billion Poorest|url=http://business.time.com/2014/01/20/worlds-85-wealthiest-people-as-rich-as-3-5-billion-poorest/|publisher=Time|accessdate=January 21, 2014|date=January 20, 2014}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|last=Wearden|first=Graeme|title=Oxfam: 85 richest people as wealthy as poorest half of the world|url=http://www.theguardian.com/business/2014/jan/20/oxfam-85-richest-people-half-of-the-world|publisher=The Guardian|accessdate=January 21, 2014|date=January 20, 2014}}</ref><ref name="NYT-20140722" /> According to a '']'' analysis of the report, the wealthiest 1% owns 46% of the world's wealth; the 85 richest people, a small part of the wealthiest 1%, own about 0.7% of the human population's wealth, which is the same as the bottom half of the population.<ref>Jim Puzzanghera (January 20, 2014). . '']''. Retrieved January 22, 2014.</ref> More recently, in January 2015, Oxfam reported that the wealthiest 1 percent will own more than half of the global wealth by 2016.<ref name="NYT-20150119-PC">{{cite news |last=Cohen |first=Patricia |title=Richest 1% Likely to Control Half of Global Wealth by 2016, Study Finds |url=http://www.nytimes.com/2015/01/19/business/richest-1-percent-likely-to-control-half-of-global-wealth-by-2016-study-finds.html |date=January 19, 2015 |work=] |accessdate=January 19, 2015 }}</ref><ref>Larry Elliott and Ed Pilkington (January 19, 2015). . ''].'' Retrieved January 19, 2015.</ref> An October 2014 study by ] also claims that the top 1% now own nearly half of the world's wealth and that the accelerating disparity could trigger a recession.<ref>Jill Treanor (13 October 2014). . ''].'' Retrieved 14 October 2014.</ref>


==Measurements==
According to ] the top 400 richest Americans "have more wealth than half of all Americans combined."<ref name="PF-20110311">{{cite news |last1=Kertscher |first1=Tom |last2=Borowski |first2=Greg |title=The Truth-O-Meter Says: '''True''' - Michael Moore says 400 Americans have more wealth than half of all Americans combined |url=http://www.politifact.com/wisconsin/statements/2011/mar/10/michael-moore/michael-moore-says-400-americans-have-more-wealth-/ |date=March 10, 2011 |work=] |accessdate=August 11, 2013 }}</ref><ref name="HP-20110306">{{cite news |last=Moore |first=Michael |authorlink=Michael Moore |title=America Is Not Broke |url=http://www.huffingtonpost.com/michael-moore/america-is-not-broke_b_832006.html |date=March 6, 2011 |work=] |accessdate=August 11, 2013 }}</ref><ref name="MM-20110307">{{cite web |last=Moore |first=Michael |authorlink=Michael Moore |title=The Forbes 400 vs. Everybody Else |url=http://www.michaelmoore.com/words/must-read/forbes-400-vs-everybody-else |date=March 7, 2011 |work='''' |accessdate=August 11, 2013 |deadurl=yes |archivedate=2011-03-09 |accessdate=2014-08-28 |archiveurl=http://web.archive.org/web/20110309211959/http://www.michaelmoore.com/words/must-read/forbes-400-vs-everybody-else }}</ref><ref name="CNN-20100922">{{cite news |last=Pepitone |first=Julianne |title=Forbes 400: The super-rich get richer |url=
{{Main|Income inequality metrics|List of countries by income equality}}
http://money.cnn.com/2010/09/22/news/companies/forbes_400/index.htm |date=September 22, 2010 |work=] |accessdate=August 11, 2013 }}</ref> According to the ] on July 22, 2014, the "richest 1 percent in the United States now own more wealth than the bottom 90 percent".<ref name="NYT-20140722">{{cite news |last=Kristof |first=Nicholas |title=An Idiot’s Guide to Inequality |url=http://www.nytimes.com/2014/07/24/opinion/nicholas-kristof-idiots-guide-to-inequality-piketty-capital.html |date=July 22, 2014 |work=] |accessdate=July 22, 2014 }}</ref> ] may help explain why many Americans who have become rich may have had a "substantial head start".<ref name="Salon-20140324">{{cite web |last=Bruenig |first=Matt |title=You call this a meritocracy? How rich inheritance is poisoning the American economy |url=http://www.salon.com/2014/03/24/death_of_meritocracy_how_inheritance_is_poisoning_the_american_economy/ |date=March 24, 2014 |work=] |accessdate=August 24, 2014 }}</ref><ref name="ECO-20140318">{{cite web |author=Staff |title=Inequality - Inherited wealth |url=http://www.economist.com/blogs/buttonwood/2014/03/inequality |date=March 18, 2014 |work=] |accessdate=August 24, 2014 }}</ref> In September 2012, according to the ], "over 60 percent" of the ] "grew up in substantial privilege".<ref name="OW-20120924">{{cite web |last=Pizzigati |first=Sam |title=The 'Self-Made' Hallucination of America's Rich |url=http://inequality.org/selfmade-myth-hallucinating-rich/ |date=September 24, 2012 |work=] |accessdate=August 24, 2014 }}</ref>


In 1820, the ratio between the income of the top and bottom 20 percent of the world's population was three to one. By 1991, it was eighty-six to one.<ref>{{Cite book|title=The World Transformed: 1945 to the Present|last=Hunt|first=Michael|publisher=Bedford/St. Martin's|year=2004|isbn=978-0312245832|location=Boston|pages=|url=https://archive.org/details/worldtransformed0000hunt/page/442}}</ref> A 2011 study titled "Divided we Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising" by the ] (OECD) sought to explain the causes for this rising inequality by investigating economic inequality in OECD countries; it concluded that the following factors played a role:<ref name="PR divided">{{cite report| url= http://www.oecd.org/document/22/0,3746,en_21571361_44315115_49185046_1_1_1_1,00.html |title=Press Release for Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising| publisher=OECD| author=Gurría, Angel| date=December 5, 2011| access-date=December 16, 2011| doi=10.1787/9789264119536-en|isbn=9789264111639}}</ref>
The existing data and estimates suggest a large increase in international (and more generally inter-macroregional) component between 1820 and 1960. It might have slightly decreased since that time at the expense of increasing inequality within countries.<ref name="see for example Novotny 2007">NOVOTNÝ, J. (2007): On the measurement of regional inequality: does spatial dimension of income inequality matter? The Annals of Regional Science, 41, 3, 563–580. http://web.natur.cuni.cz/~pepino/NOVOTNY2007AnnalsofRegionalScience.pdf</ref>
* Changes in the structure of households can play an important role. Single-headed households in OECD countries have risen from an average of 15% in the late 1980s to 20% in the mid-2000s, resulting in higher inequality.
* ] refers to the phenomenon of people marrying people with similar background, for example doctors marrying other doctors rather than nurses. OECD found out that 40% of couples where both partners work belonged to the same or neighbouring earnings deciles compared with 33% some 20 years before.<ref name="oecd-dws">{{cite book|title=Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising|date=2011|publisher=OECD|isbn=978-9264119536 |doi=10.1787/9789264119536-en}}{{page needed|date=September 2018}}</ref>
* In the bottom percentiles, number of hours worked has decreased.<ref name="oecd-dws"/>
* The main reason for increasing inequality seems to be the difference between the demand for and supply of skills.<ref name="oecd-dws"/>
The study made the following conclusions about the level of economic inequality:
* Income inequality in OECD countries is at its highest level for the past half century. The ratio between the bottom 10% and the top 10% has increased from 1:7 to 1:9 in 25 years.<ref name="oecd-dws"/>
* There are tentative signs of a possible convergence of inequality levels towards a common and higher average level across OECD countries.<ref name="oecd-dws"/>
* With very few exceptions (], ], and ]), the wages of the 10% best-paid workers have risen relative to those of the 10% lowest paid.<ref name="oecd-dws"/>


A 2011 OECD study investigated economic inequality in ], ], ], ], ], ], and ]. It concluded that key sources of inequality in these countries include "a large, persistent ], widespread regional divides (e.g., ]), gaps in access to education, and barriers to employment and career progression for women."<ref name="oecd-dws"/>
The ] in 2014 asserted that greater investments in social security, jobs and laws that protect vulnerable populations are necessary to prevent widening income inequality...<!---- fluctuating food prices, disasters and conflict from reducing human development--->.<ref>Mark Anderson (July 24, 2014). . ''].'' Retrieved July 24, 2014.</ref>
{{multiple image | total_width=450
| image1= Countries by total wealth (trillions USD), Credit Suisse.png |caption1= Countries by total wealth (2022)
| image2= 2018 Inequality-Adjusted Human Development INdex.svg |caption2= Countries by the ].
}}
A study by the World Institute for Development Economics Research at ] reported that the richest 1% of adults alone owned 40% of global assets in the year 2000. The ] in the world possess more financial assets than the lowest 48 nations combined.<ref>{{cite web|title=Stock quotes, financial tools, news and analysis |work=MSN Money |url=http://articles.moneycentral.msn.com/News/StudyRevealsOverwhelmingWealthGap.aspx |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110905042236/http://articles.moneycentral.msn.com/News/StudyRevealsOverwhelmingWealthGap.aspx |archive-date=September 5, 2011 |url-status=dead |access-date=July 24, 2010}}</ref> The combined wealth of the "10 million dollar millionaires" grew to nearly $41 trillion in 2008.<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130623172139/http://www.thaindian.com/newsportal/world-news/growth-of-millionaires-in-india-fastest-in-world_10064367.html |date=June 23, 2013 }}. ''Thaindian News''. June 25, 2008.</ref>


]'s 2021 report on global inequality said that the ] has increased economic inequality substantially; the wealthiest people across the globe were impacted the least by the pandemic and their fortunes recovered quickest, with billionaires seeing their wealth increase by $3.9 trillion, while at the same time the number of people living on less than $5.50 a day likely increased by 500 million.<ref>{{cite news |last=Clifford |first=Catherine |date=January 26, 2021 |title=The '1%' are the main drivers of climate change, but it hits the poor the hardest: Oxfam report |work=] |url=https://www.cnbc.com/2021/01/26/oxfam-report-the-global-wealthy-are-main-drivers-of-climate-change.html |access-date=February 14, 2021}}</ref> According to economist ], the pandemic's "most significant outcome" will be rising economic inequality in the United States and between the developed and developing world.<ref>{{cite news |last=Joseph |first=Stiglitz|date=March 1, 2022 |title=COVID Has Made Global Inequality Much Worse|url=https://www.scientificamerican.com/article/covid-has-made-global-inequality-much-worse/|work=] |location= |access-date=August 3, 2022}}</ref> The 2024 Oxfam report found a significant increase in inequality as roughly five billion people have become poorer while at the same time the fortunes of the five richest individuals have doubled. The report warns that current trends are paving the way for the world's first trillionaire within a decade and global poverty eradication being postponed for 229 years.<ref>{{cite news |last=Neate|first=Rupert |date=January 14, 2024 |title=World's five richest men double their money as poorest get poorer|url=https://www.theguardian.com/inequality/2024/jan/15/worlds-five-richest-men-double-their-money-as-poorest-get-poorer|work=] |location= |access-date=January 15, 2024}}</ref>
There is a significant difference in the measured wealth distribution and the public’s understanding of wealth distribution. Michael Norton of the ] and Dan Ariely of the Departement of Psychology at ] found this to be true in their research, done in 2011. The actual wealth going to the top quintile in 2011 was around 84% where as the average amount of wealth that the general public estimated to go to the top quintile was around 58%.<ref>Norton, M., Dan Ariely (2011). , Perspectives on Psychological Science January,6: 9-12</ref>


{{ multiple image |total_width=450 |title=Net personal wealth in the U.S. since 1962
==Causes==
| image1= 1962- Net personal wealth - average in percentile ranges - linear scale - US.svg | caption1= The average personal wealth of people in the top 1% is more than a thousand times that of people in bottom 50%.<ref name=WID_through_2021/>
There are many reasons for economic inequality within societies. Recent growth in overall income inequality, at least within the OECD countries, has been driven mostly by increasing inequality in wages and salaries.<ref name="PR divided"/> Economist ], who specializes in the study of economic inequality, argues that widening economic disparity is an inevitable phenomenon of ] ] when the rate of return of capital (r) is greater than the rate of growth of the economy (g).<ref>] (2014). ''].'' ]. ISBN 067443000X p. 571</ref>
| image2= 1962- Net personal wealth - average in percentile ranges - logarithmic scale - US.svg | caption2= The logarithmic scale shows how wealth has increased for all percentile groups, though moreso for wealthier people.<ref name=WID_through_2021>{{cite web |title=Evolution of wealth indicators, USA, 1913–2019 |url=https://wid.world/country/usa/ |website=WID.world |publisher=World Inequality Database |access-date=September 6, 2023 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230705011218/https://wid.world/country/usa/ |archive-date=July 5, 2023 |date=2022 |url-status=live }}</ref>
}}
According to ], the top 400 richest Americans "have more wealth than half of all Americans combined."<ref name="PF-20110311">{{cite news |last1=Kertscher |first1=Tom |last2=Borowski |first2=Greg |title=The Truth-O-Meter Says: '''True''' – Michael Moore says 400 Americans have more wealth than half of all Americans combined |url=http://www.politifact.com/wisconsin/statements/2011/mar/10/michael-moore/michael-moore-says-400-americans-have-more-wealth-/ |date=March 10, 2011 |work=] |access-date=August 11, 2013 }}</ref><ref name="HP-20110306">{{cite news |last=Moore |first=Michael |author-link=Michael Moore |title=America Is Not Broke |url=https://www.huffingtonpost.com/michael-moore/america-is-not-broke_b_832006.html |date=March 6, 2011 |work=] |access-date=August 11, 2013 }}</ref><ref name="MM-20110307">{{cite web
| last = Moore | first = Michael | author-link = Michael Moore
| title = The Forbes 400 vs. Everybody Else
| url = http://www.michaelmoore.com/words/must-read/forbes-400-vs-everybody-else
| date = March 7, 2011
| work = michaelmoore.com
| access-date = August 11, 2013
| archive-date = March 9, 2011
| url-status = dead | archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20110309211959/http://www.michaelmoore.com/words/must-read/forbes-400-vs-everybody-else
}}</ref><ref name="CNN-20100922">{{cite news |last=Pepitone |first=Julianne |title=Forbes 400: The super-rich get richer |url=https://money.cnn.com/2010/09/22/news/companies/forbes_400/index.htm |date=September 22, 2010 |work=] |access-date=August 11, 2013 }}</ref> According to '']'' on July 22, 2014, the "richest 1 percent in the United States now own more wealth than the bottom 90 percent".<ref name="NYT-20140722">{{cite news |last=Kristof |first=Nicholas |title=An Idiot's Guide to Inequality |url=https://www.nytimes.com/2014/07/24/opinion/nicholas-kristof-idiots-guide-to-inequality-piketty-capital.html |date=July 22, 2014 |work=The New York Times |access-date=July 22, 2014 }}</ref> ] may help explain why many Americans who have become rich may have had a "substantial head start".<ref name="Salon-20140324">{{cite web |last=Bruenig |first=Matt |title=You call this a meritocracy? How rich inheritance is poisoning the American economy |url=http://www.salon.com/2014/03/24/death_of_meritocracy_how_inheritance_is_poisoning_the_american_economy/ |date=March 24, 2014 |work=] |access-date=August 24, 2014 }}</ref><ref name="ECO-20140318">{{cite news |title=Inequality – Inherited wealth |url=https://www.economist.com/blogs/buttonwood/2014/03/inequality |date=March 18, 2014 |newspaper=] |access-date=August 24, 2014 }}</ref> A 2017 report by the IPS said that three individuals, ], ] and ], own as much wealth as the bottom half of the population, or 160 million people, and that the growing disparity between the wealthy and the poor has created a "moral crisis", noting that "we have not witnessed such extreme levels of concentrated wealth and power since the first ] a century ago."<ref>{{cite news |last= Neate|first=Rupert|date=November 8, 2017 |title=Bill Gates, Jeff Bezos and Warren Buffett are wealthier than poorest half of US|url=https://www.theguardian.com/business/2017/nov/08/bill-gates-jeff-bezos-warren-buffett-wealthier-than-poorest-half-of-us|work=The Guardian |access-date= November 9, 2017}}</ref><ref>{{cite news |last=Taylor|first=Matt |date=November 9, 2017|title=The Paradise Papers Are Just a Glimpse at the Unreal Wealth Gap|url=https://www.vice.com/en_us/article/59yk75/the-paradise-papers-are-just-a-glimpse-at-the-unreal-wealth-gap|work=] |access-date=November 10, 2017}}</ref> In 2016, the world's billionaires increased their combined global wealth to a record $6 trillion.<ref>{{cite news |last= Neate|first=Rupert|date=October 26, 2017 |title=World's witnessing a new Gilded Age as billionaires' wealth swells to $6tn|url=https://www.theguardian.com/business/2017/oct/26/worlds-witnessing-a-new-gilded-age-as-billionaires-wealth-swells-to-6tn|work=The Guardian |access-date=October 27, 2017}}</ref> In 2017, they increased their collective wealth to 8.9 trillion.<ref>{{cite news |last=Neate |first=Rupert |date=October 26, 2018 |title=World's billionaires became 20% richer in 2017, report reveals|url=https://www.theguardian.com/news/2018/oct/26/worlds-billionaires-became-20-richer-in-2017-report-reveals|work=The Guardian |access-date=November 5, 2018 }}</ref> In 2018, U.S. income inequality reached the highest level ever recorded by the ].<ref>{{cite news |last= Telford|first=Taylor|date=September 26, 2019|title=Income inequality in America is the highest it's been since census started tracking it, data shows|url=https://www.washingtonpost.com/business/2019/09/26/income-inequality-america-highest-its-been-since-census-started-tracking-it-data-show|newspaper=] |access-date=September 30, 2019 }}</ref>


The existing data and estimates suggest a large increase in international (and more generally inter-macroregional) components between 1820 and 1960. It might have slightly decreased since that time at the expense of increasing inequality within countries.<ref name="see for example Novotny 2007">{{cite journal |doi=10.1007/s00168-007-0113-y |title=On the measurement of regional inequality: Does spatial dimension of income inequality matter? |journal=The Annals of Regional Science |volume=41 |issue=3 |pages=563–580 |year=2007 |last1=Novotný |first1=Josef |bibcode=2007ARegS..41..563N |s2cid=51753883 }}</ref> The ] in 2014 asserted that greater investments in social security, jobs, and laws that protect vulnerable populations are necessary to prevent widening income inequality.<ref>Mark Anderson (July 24, 2014). . ''].'' Retrieved July 24, 2014.</ref>
Common factors thought to impact economic inequality include:
* labor market outcomes<ref name="PR divided"/>
* ],<ref name="Meszaros1995" /> by:
** suppressing wages in low-skill jobs due to a surplus of low-skill labor in developing countries
** increasing the market size and the rewards for people and firms succeeding in a particular niche
** providing more investment opportunities for already-wealthy people
* policy reforms<ref name="PR divided"/>
* more ]ation<ref name=Piketty/>
* ]
* ]ization and increased technology,<ref name="Meszaros1995">{{cite book|last=MÉSZÁROS|first=István|title=Beyond Capital|year=1995|publisher=Merlin Press|location=London|isbn=978-85-7559-068-3}}</ref> which means more skills are required to obtain a moderate or high wage
* ]<ref name=UNRISD>{{cite web|title=Tackling Ethnic and Regional Inequalities|url=https://owlspace-ccm.rice.edu/access/content/group/HUMA-SOCI-280-001-F11/Course%20Readings/February%207/UNRISD%20CH.3%20total.pdf|work=Combating Poverty and Inequality: Structural Change, Social Polics, and Politi|publisher=United Nations Research Institute for Social Development|accessdate=October 18, 2011}}</ref>
* ]<ref name="bls 2009">U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Report 1025, June 2010.</ref>
* ]<ref>{{Cite pmid|8709080|noedit}}</ref>
* variation in natural ability<ref name="RawlsJustice">{{cite book |last=Rawls |first=John |authorlink=John Rawls |title=] |year=2005 |publisher=Belknap Press of Harvard University Press |isbn=978-0674017726}}</ref>
*]<ref>Vicente Navarro, ed. ''.'' Baywood Publishing Company, 2007. ISBN 0895033380 .</ref>
* Growing acceptance of very high CEO salaries, e.g. in the United States since the 1960s<ref>{{cite book|title=The Haves and the Have-Nots: A Brief and Idiosyncratic History of Global Inequality |author=Branko Milanovic |year=2012 |isbn=978-0465031412}}</ref>


There is a significant difference in the measured wealth distribution and the public's understanding of wealth distribution. ] of the ] and Dan Ariely of the Department of Psychology at ] found this to be true in their research conducted in 2011. The actual wealth going to the top quintile in 2011 was around 84%, whereas the average amount of wealth that the general public estimated to go to the top quintile was around 58%.<ref>{{cite journal |doi=10.1177/1745691610393524 |pmid=26162108 |title=Building a Better America – One Wealth Quintile at a Time |journal=Perspectives on Psychological Science |volume=6 |issue=1 |pages=9–12 |year=2011 |last1=Norton |first1=Michael I. |last2=Ariely |first2=Dan |s2cid=2013655 }}</ref>
===Theoretical frameworks===


According to a 2020 study, global earnings inequality has decreased substantially since 1970. During the 2000s and 2010s, the share of earnings by the world's poorest half doubled.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Hammar |first1=Olle |last2=Waldenström|first2=Daniel|title=Global Earnings Inequality, 1970–2018|journal=The Economic Journal|year=2020|volume=130|issue=632|pages=2526–2545|doi=10.1093/ej/ueaa109|s2cid=157907204|doi-access=free}}</ref> Two researchers claim that global income inequality is decreasing due to strong economic growth in developing countries.<ref>{{cite book|last1=Hellebrandt |first1=Tomáš |last2=Mauro |first2=Paolo |title=The Future of Worldwide Income Distribution |date=2015 |publisher=]}}</ref> According to a January 2020 report by the ], economic inequality between states had declined, but intrastate inequality has increased for 70% of the ] over the period 1990–2015.<ref>{{cite news |author=<!--Staff writer(s); no by-line.--> |date=January 21, 2020 |title=Rising inequality affecting more than two-thirds of the globe, but it's not inevitable: new UN report |url=https://news.un.org/en/story/2020/01/1055681 |work=UN News |access-date=September 6, 2020}}</ref> In 2015, the OECD reported in 2015 that income inequality is higher than it has ever been within OECD member nations and is at increased levels in many emerging economies.<ref>. ], May 21, 2015.</ref> According to a June 2015 report by the ] (IMF):
====Neoclassical economics====
] views inequalities in the distribution of income as arising from differences in productivity, and attribute rising inequality to rising differences in the productivity of different groups of workers. In this perspective, wages and profits are determined by the marginal productivity of each individual in the economy. Thus rising inequalities are merely a reflection of the productivity gap between highly-paid professions and lower-paid professions.<ref>{{cite book |last= Keen|first= Steve |title= Debunking Economics - Revised and Expanded Edition: The Naked Emperor Dethroned?|publisher=Zed Books|year= 2011 |isbn= 978-1848139923 |pages = 110|quote = The basis for this advice is the proposition that a person's income is determined by her contribution to production - or more precisely, by the marginal productivity of the 'factor of production' to which she contributes...The argument that highly paid workers - managers of major corporations, stock and money market traders, financial commentators, etc - deserve the high wages they receive compared to the less highly paid - nuclear physicists, rocket scientists, university professors, school teachers, etc. - is simply an extension of this argument to cover subgroups of workers. Members of the former group, we are told, are simply more productive than members of the latter, hence their higher salaries.}}</ref>


<blockquote>Widening income inequality is the defining challenge of our time. In advanced economies, the gap between the rich and poor is at its highest level in decades. Inequality trends have been more mixed in emerging markets and developing countries (EMDCs), with some countries experiencing declining inequality, but pervasive inequities in access to education, health care, and finance remain.<ref>Era Dabla-Norris; Kalpana Kochhar; Nujin Suphaphiphat; Frantisek Ricka; Evridiki Tsounta (June 15, 2015). . International Monetary Fund. Retrieved June 16, 2015.</ref></blockquote>
====Marxian economics====
In ], rising income inequality is an inherent feature of capitalism. In this analysis, capitalist firms increasingly substitute workers for capital equipment under competitive pressures to reduce costs and maximize profit. Over the long-term, this trend increases the ], meaning that less labor inputs (workers) are required in proportion to capital inputs, increasing unemployment and the size of the ]. This process exerts a downward pressure on wages. The substitution of labor for capital equipment (job automation) increases productivity per worker and thus profits for the capitalist class, resulting in a situation of relatively stagnant wages for the working class amidst rising levels of property income for the capitalist class.<ref>{{cite book |last= Wood|first= John Cunningham |author-link=John Cunningham Wood|title= Karl Marx's Economics: Critical Assessments I and II |publisher=Routledge|year= 1996 |isbn= 978-0415087148|pages = 214|quote =}}</ref>


In October 2017, the IMF warned that inequality within nations, in spite of global inequality falling in recent decades, has risen so sharply that it threatens economic growth and could result in further ]. The Fund's Fiscal Monitor report said that "progressive taxation and transfers are key components of efficient fiscal redistribution."<ref>{{cite news |last= Dunsmuir
Therefore, Marxian economics attributes rising inequality to both the ownership structure of capitalist economies and to rising job automation conflicting with the requirements of the wage labor system.
|first=Lindsay|date=October 11, 2017 |title=IMF calls for fiscal policies that tackle rising inequality|url=https://www.reuters.com/article/imf-g20-inequality/imf-calls-for-fiscal-policies-that-tackle-rising-inequality-idUSL2N1ML16B|work=] |access-date= October 30, 2017}}</ref>
In October 2018 ] published a ''Reducing Inequality Index'' which measured social spending, tax and workers' rights to show which countries were best at closing the gap between the rich and the poor.<ref>{{cite news |last1=Lawson |first1=Max |last2=Martin |first2=Matthew |title=The Commitment to Reducing Inequality Index 2018 |url=https://www.oxfam.org/en/research/commitment-reducing-inequality-index-2018 |access-date=November 13, 2018 |publisher=Oxfam |date=October 9, 2018}}</ref>


The 2022 ], a four-year research project organized by the economists ], ], ], and ], shows that "the world is marked by a very high level of income inequality and an extreme level of wealth inequality" and that these inequalities "seem to be about as great today as they were at the peak of ] in the early 20th century." According to the report, the bottom half of the population owns 2% of global wealth, while the top 10% owns 76% of it. The top 1% owns 38%.<ref>{{cite news |last1=Kaplan |first1=Juliana |last2= Kiersz |first2=Andy |date=December 7, 2021 |title=A huge study of 20 years of global wealth demolishes the myth of 'trickle-down' and shows the rich are taking most of the gains for themselves |url=https://www.businessinsider.com/how-bad-is-inequality-trickle-down-economics-thomas-piketty-economists-2021-12 |work=] |location= |access-date=December 8, 2021}}</ref><ref>{{cite news |last=Elliott |first=Larry |date=December 7, 2021 |title=Global inequality 'as marked as it was at peak of western imperialism' |url=https://www.theguardian.com/business/2021/dec/07/global-inequality-western-imperialism-super-rich |work=] |location= |access-date=December 8, 2021}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=https://wir2022.wid.world/ |title=World Inequality Report 2022 |access-date=December 8, 2021}}</ref>
===Labour market===
A major cause of economic inequality within modern ] is the determination of wages by the ]. Some small part of economic inequality is caused by the differences in the ] for different types of work. However, where competition is imperfect; information unevenly distributed; opportunities to acquire education and skills unequal; and since many such imperfect conditions exist in virtually every market, there is in fact little presumption that markets are in general efficient. This means that there is an enormous potential role for government to correct these market failures.<ref>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future (p. 34). Norton. Kindle Edition.</ref>


===Wealth distribution within individual countries===
In a purely ] (i.e. where professional and labor organizations cannot limit the number of workers) the workers wages will not be controlled by these organizations, or by the employer, but rather by the market. Wages work in the same way as prices for any other good. Thus, wages can be considered as a function of market price of skill. And therefore, inequality is driven by this price. Under the law of supply and demand, the price of skill is determined by a race between the demand for the skilled worker and the supply of the skilled worker. "On the other hand, markets can also concentrate wealth, pass environmental costs on to society, and abuse workers and consumers." "Markets, by themselves, even when they are stable, often lead to high levels of inequality, outcomes that are widely viewed as unfair."<ref>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future . Norton. Kindle Edition. p. 9.</ref> Employers who offer a below market wage will find that their business is chronically understaffed. Their competitors will take advantage of the situation by offering a higher wage to snatch up the best of their labor. For a businessman who has the ] as the prime interest, it is a losing proposition to offer below or above market wages to workers.<ref>{{cite book |last= Hazlitt |first= Henry | authorlink = Henry Hazlitt | title= ] |publisher= ] |date=December 1988|chapterurl=http://jim.com/econ/chap20p2.html|chapter=Chapter 20: Part 2|isbn= 978-0-517-54823-3}}</ref>
{{main|List of countries by wealth per adult#By country|Wealth distribution}}


The ] is calculated by various factors, for instance: ], ]s, ]s and their expected development, real estate prices, ], ]s and technical advancements, etc.
A job where there are many workers willing to work a large amount of time (high supply) competing for a job that few require (low demand) will result in a low ] for that job. This is because ] between workers drives down the wage. An example of this would be jobs such as dish-washing or customer service. Competition amongst workers tends to drive down wages due to the expendable nature of the worker in relation to his or her particular job. A job where there are few able or willing workers (low supply), but a large need for the positions (high demand), will result in high wages for that job. This is because competition between employers ''for employees'' will drive up the wage. Examples of this would include jobs that require highly developed skills, rare abilities, or a high level of ]. Competition amongst employers tends to drive up wages due to the nature of the job, since there is a relative shortage of workers for the particular position. Professional and labor organizations may limit the supply of workers which results in higher demand and greater incomes for members. Members may also receive higher wages through ], political influence, or corruption.<ref>{{cite book |last= Hazlitt |first= Henry | authorlink = Henry Hazlitt |title= ] |publisher= ] |date=December 1988 | chapterurl=http://jim.com/econ/chap20p1.html|chapter=Chapter 20: Part 1|isbn= 978-0-517-54823-3}}</ref>


===Income distribution within individual countries===
These supply and demand interactions result in a gradation of wage levels within society that significantly influence economic inequality. ] of wages does not explain the accumulation of wealth and very high incomes among the 1%. Joseph Stiglitz believes that "It is plain that markets must be tamed and tempered to make sure they work to the benefit of most citizens."<ref>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future . Norton. Kindle Edition. p. 8.</ref>
{{Main|List of countries by income equality|Income distribution}}
] values as of 2018.<ref name="auto"/>]]
Income inequality is measured by ] (expressed in percent %) that is a number between 0 and 1. Here 0 expresses perfect equality, meaning that everyone has the same income, whereas 1 represents perfect inequality, meaning that one person has all the income and others have none. A ] value above 50% is considered high; countries including Brazil, Colombia, South Africa, Botswana, and Honduras can be found in this category. A Gini index value of 30% or above is considered medium; countries including Vietnam, Mexico, Poland, the United States, Argentina, Russia and Uruguay can be found in this category. A Gini index value lower than 30% is considered low; countries including Austria, Germany, Denmark, Norway, Slovenia, Sweden, and Ukraine can be found in this category.<ref>{{cite web |title=Country Comparison: Distribution of family income – Gini index |website=The World Factbook |publisher=CIA |url=https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/rankorder/2172rank.html |access-date=May 8, 2017 |archive-date=June 4, 2011 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110604005151/http://www.forbes.com/feeds/afx/2007/06/12/afx3810988.html |url-status=dead}}</ref> In the low-income inequality category (below 30%) is a wide representation of countries previously being part of Soviet Union or its satellites, like Slovakia, Czech Republic, Ukraine and Hungary.


In 2012 the Gini index for income inequality for whole European Union was only 30.6%.
===Taxes===
Another cause is the rate at which ] coupled with the ] of the tax system. A ] is a tax by which the ] increases as the taxable base amount increases.<ref> (4b): increasing in rate as the base increases (a progressive tax)</ref><ref> (6). Increasing in rate as the taxable amount increases.</ref><ref>: Tax levied at a rate that increases as the quantity subject to taxation increases.</ref><ref>: (n) progressive tax (any tax in which the rate increases as the amount subject to taxation increases)</ref><ref name="Sommerfeld">Sommerfeld, Ray M., Silvia A. Madeo, Kenneth E. Anderson, Betty R. Jackson (1992), ''Concepts of Taxation'', Dryden Press: Fort Worth, TX</ref> In a progressive tax system, the level of the top tax rate will often have a direct impact on the level of inequality within a society, either increasing it or decreasing it, provided that income does not change as a result of the change in tax regime. Additionally, steeper tax progressivity applied to social spending can result in a ] across the board.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Alesina|first=Alberto|author2=Dani Rodrick|title=Distributive Politics and Economic Growth|journal=Quarterly Journal of Economics|date=May 1994|volume=109|issue=2|pages=465–90|doi=10.2307/2118470|url=http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/109/2/465.full.pdf|accessdate=October 17, 2013}}</ref> The difference between the ] for an income distribution before taxation and the Gini index after taxation is an indicator for the effects of such taxation.<ref>{{cite journal|title=More than a Dozen Alternative Ways of Spelling Gini|author=Shlomo Yitzhaki|journal=Economic Inequality|volume=8|year=1998|pages=13–30|url=http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTDECINEQ/Resources/morethan2002.pdf}}</ref>


Income distribution can differ from wealth distribution within each country. The wealth inequality is also measured in Gini index. There the higher Gini index signify greater inequality within the wealth distribution in country, 0 means total wealth equality and 1 represents situation, where everyone has no wealth, except an individual that has everything. &nbsp;For instance, countries like Denmark, Norway and Netherlands, all belonging to the last category (below 30%, low-income inequality) also have very high Gini index in wealth distribution, ranging from 70% up to 90%.
There is debate between politicians and economists over the role of tax policy in mitigating or exacerbating wealth inequality. Economists such as ], ], and ] have argued that tax policy in the post World War II era has indeed increased income inequality by enabling the wealthiest Americans far greater access to capital than lower-income ones.<ref name=Piketty>Piketty, Thomas, and Emmanuel Saez. INCOME INEQUALITY IN THE UNITED STATES, 1913–1998. Tech. 1st ed. Vol. CXVIII. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2003. Print.</ref>


===Consumption distribution within individual countries===
===Education===
{{Main|Consumption distribution}}
{{Refimprove section|date=June 2013}}
In ], the ''consumption distribution'' or ''consumption inequality'' is an alternative to the ] or ] for judging economic inequality, comparing levels of ] rather than ] or ].<ref>{{Cite book|url=https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/economics/framework-for-statistics-on-the-distribution-of-household-income-consumption-and-wealth_9789264194830-en|title=OECD Framework for Statistics on the Distribution of Household Income, Consumption and Wealth|date=2013|publisher=Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development|via=OECD iLibrary}}</ref> This is an important measure of inequality as the basic utility of the wealth or income is the expenditure.<ref>{{cite journal|title=Consumption Inequality |last1=Attanasio |first1=Orazio P. |last2=Pistaferri |first2=Luigi |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives |volume=30 |issue=2 |date=April 2016 |pages=3–28 |doi=10.1257/jep.30.2.3 |url=https://web.stanford.edu/~pista/JEP.pdf }}</ref> People ] the inequality directly in consumption, rather than income or wealth.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.jpmorganchase.com/institute/research/cities-local-communities/insight-consumption-inequality|title=Consumption Inequality: What's in Your Shopping Basket? &#124; JPMorgan Chase Institute|website=www.jpmorganchase.com}}</ref>
] existing during the ]. ]]


==Factors proposed to affect economic inequality{{anchor|Causes}}==
An important factor in the creation of inequality is variation in individuals' access to education.<ref name="becker">{{cite web| url=http://www.american.com/archive/2007/may-june-magazine-contents/the-upside-of-income-inequality | last=Becker | first=Gary S. |author2=Murphy, Kevin M. |title=The Upside of Income Inequality | publisher=The America | date=May 2007 | accessdate=January 8, 2014}}</ref> Education, especially in an area where there is a high demand for workers, creates high wages for those with this education,<ref>{{Cite report |first= Barry |last= Bosworth |first2= Gary |last2= Burtless |first3= C. Eugene |last3= Steuerle |date= December 1999 |title= Lifetime Earnings Patterns, the Distribution of Future Social Security Benefits, and the Impact of Pension Reform |type= report no. CRR WP 1999-06 |publisher= Center for Retirement Research at Boston College |location= Chestnut Hill, Massachusetts | url=http://urban.org/uploadedpdf/412137-lifetime-earnings.pdf |page= 43 |accessdate= October 1, 2012}}</ref> however, increases in education first increase and then decrease growth as well as income inequality. As a result, those who are unable to afford an education, or choose not to pursue optional education, generally receive much lower wages. The justification for this is that a lack of education leads directly to lower incomes, and thus lower aggregate savings and investment. In particular, the increase in family income and wealth inequality leads to greater dispersion of educational attainment, primarily because those at the bottom of the educational distribution have fallen further below the average level of education. Conversely, education raises incomes and promotes growth because it helps to unleash the productive potential of the poor.
There are various reasons for economic inequality within societies, including both global market functions (such as trade, development, and regulation) as well as social factors (including gender, race, and education).<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Neckerman|first1=Kathryn M.|last2=Torche|first2=Florencia|date=July 18, 2007|title=Inequality: Causes and Consequences|url=https://www.annualreviews.org/doi/10.1146/annurev.soc.33.040406.131755|journal=Annual Review of Sociology|volume=33|issue=1|pages=335–357|doi=10.1146/annurev.soc.33.040406.131755|issn=0360-0572}}</ref> Recent growth in overall income inequality, at least within the OECD countries, has been driven mostly by increasing inequality in wages and salaries.<ref name="PR divided"/>


Economist ] argues that widening economic disparity is an inevitable phenomenon of ] ] when the rate of return of capital (r) is greater than the rate of growth of the economy (g).<ref>] (2014). ''].'' ]. {{ISBN|067443000X}} p. 571</ref> According to an IMF report in 2016, after reviewing four decades of neoliberalism, it had warned that certain neoliberal policies including privatization, public spending cuts, and deregulation, have resulted in "increased inequality" and are stunting economic growth globally.<ref>{{Cite web |date=2016-05-27 |title=Neoliberalism is increasing inequality and stunting economic growth, the IMF says |url=https://www.independent.co.uk/news/uk/politics/neoliberalism-is-increasing-inequality-and-stunting-economic-growth-the-imf-says-a7052416.html |access-date=2023-08-20 |website=The Independent |language=en |first1=Jon |last1=Stone }}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |title=Neoliberalism: Oversold? |work=Finance & Development |date=June 2016 |first1=Jonathan D. |last1=Ostry |first2=Prakash |last2=Loungani |first3=Davide |last3=Furceri |url=https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2016/06/ostry.htm |access-date=2023-08-20 |publisher=International Monetary Fund}}</ref>
In 2014, economists with the Standard & Poor's rating agency concluded that the widening disparity between the U.S.'s wealthiest citizens and the rest of the nation had slowed its recovery from the 2008-2009 recession and made it more prone to boom-and-bust cycles. To partially remedy the wealth gap and the resulting slow growth, S&P recommended increasing access to education. It estimated that if the average United States worker had completed just one more year of school, it would add an additional $105 billion in growth to the country's economy over five years.<ref>
{{cite news
| last = Boak
| first = Josh
| title = S&P: Widening wealth gap slows economic recovery
| newspaper = Associated Press, as published in the Salt Lake Tribune
| page = A10
| date = August 6, 2014
| url = http://www.sltrib.com/sltrib/world/58264558-68/percent-growth-economy-gap.html.csp
| accessdate = August 10, 2014}}
</ref>


===Labour market===
During the mass high school education movement from 1910–1940, there was an increase in skilled workers, which led to a decrease in the price of skilled labor. High school education during the period was designed to equip students with necessary skill sets to be able to perform at work. In fact, it differs from the present high school education, which is regarded as a stepping-stone to acquire college and advanced degrees. This decrease in wages caused a period of compression and decreased inequality between skilled and unskilled workers. Education is very important for the growth of the economy, however educational inequality in gender also influence towards the economy. Lagerlof and Galor stated that gender inequality in education can result to low economic growth, and continued gender inequality in education, thus creating a poverty trap. It is suggested that a large gap in male and female education may indicate backwardness and so may be associated with lower economic growth, which can explain why there is economic inequality between countries.
{{main|Labour economics|Capitalism|Marxism|Neoclassical economics}}


In modern ], if competition is imperfect; information unevenly distributed; opportunities to acquire education and skills unequal; ] results. Many such imperfect conditions exist in virtually every market. According to ] this means that there is an enormous potential role for government to correct such market failures.<ref name="Stiglitz2012"/>
More of Barro studies also find that female secondary education is positively associated with growth. His findings show that countries with low female education; increasing it has little effect on economic growth, however in countries with high female education, increasing it significantly boosts economic growth. More and better education is a prerequisite for rapid economic development around the world. Education stimulates economic growth and improves people's lives through many channels.


In the United States, real wages are flat over the past 40 years for occupations across income and education levels, e.g., auto mechanics, cashiers, doctors, and software engineers.<ref name=":8">{{Cite journal |last=Kausik |first=B. N. |date=May 3, 2022 |title=Income Inequality, Cause and Cure |url=https://doi.org/10.1080/05775132.2022.2046883 |journal=Challenge |volume=65 |issue=3–4 |pages=93–105 |doi=10.1080/05775132.2022.2046883 |arxiv=2201.10726 |s2cid=246285783 |issn=0577-5132}}</ref> However, stock ownership favors higher income and education levels,<ref>{{Cite web |last1=Parker |first1=Kim |last2=Fry |first2=Richard |title=More than half of U.S. households have some investment in the stock market |website=Pew Research Center |date=March 25, 2020 |url=https://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2020/03/25/more-than-half-of-u-s-households-have-some-investment-in-the-stock-market/ |access-date=April 21, 2022}}</ref> thereby resulting in disparate investment income.
By increasing the efficiency of the labour force it create better conditions for good governance, improving health and enhancing equality. Labor market success is linked to schooling achievement, the consequences of widening disparities in schooling is likely to be further increases in earnings inequality


===Taxes===
===Neoliberalism, deregulation and decline of unions===
{{Main|Income tax|Progressive tax}}
John Schmitt and Ben Zipperer (2006) of the CEPR point to ] and the reduction of business ] along with the decline of ] as one of the causes of economic inequality. In an analysis of the effects of intensive Anglo-American ] policies in comparison to continental European neoliberalism, where unions have remained strong, they concluded "The U.S. economic and social model is associated with substantial levels of social exclusion, including high levels of income inequality, high relative and absolute poverty rates, poor and unequal educational outcomes, poor health outcomes, and high rates of crime and incarceration. At the same time, the available evidence provides little support for the view that U.S.-style labor-market flexibility dramatically improves labor-market outcomes. Despite popular prejudices to the contrary, the U.S. economy consistently affords a lower level of economic mobility than all the continental European countries for which data is available."<ref>Schmitt, John and Ben Zipperer. 2006. "" CEPR</ref>
]


Another cause is the rate at which ] coupled with the progressivity of the tax system. A ] is a tax by which the ] increases as the taxable base amount increases.<ref>: Tax levied at a rate that increases as the quantity subject to taxation increases.</ref><ref>{{dead link|date=September 2017 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}: (n) progressive tax (any tax in which the rate increases as the amount subject to taxation increases)</ref> In a progressive tax system, the level of the top tax rate will often have a direct impact on the level of inequality within a society, either increasing it or decreasing it, provided that income does not change as a result of the change in tax regime. Additionally, steeper tax progressivity applied to social spending can result in a ] across the board.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Alesina|first=Alberto|author2=Dani Rodrick|title=Distributive Politics and Economic Growth|journal=Quarterly Journal of Economics|date=May 1994|volume=109|issue=2|pages=465–490 |doi=10.2307/2118470|jstor=2118470|url=http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:4551798}}</ref> Tax credits such as the ] in the US can also decrease income inequality.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Hatch |first1=Megan E. |last2=Rigby |first2=Elizabeth |title=Laboratories of (In)equality? Redistributive Policy and Income Inequality in the American States |journal=Policy Studies Journal |date=2015 |volume=43 |issue=2 |pages=163–187 |doi=10.1111/psj.12094}}</ref> The difference between the ] for an income distribution before taxation and the Gini index after taxation is an indicator for the effects of such taxation.<ref>{{cite journal|title=More than a Dozen Alternative Ways of Spelling Gini|author=Shlomo Yitzhaki|journal=Economic Inequality|volume=8|year=1998|pages=13–30 |url=http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTDECINEQ/Resources/morethan2002.pdf}}</ref>
Sociologist Jake Rosenfield of the ] asserts that the decline of organized labor in the United States has played a more significant role in expanding the income gap than technological changes and globalization, which were also experienced by other industrialized nations that didn't experience steep surges in inequality. He points out that nations with high rates of unionization, particularly in Scandinavia, have very low levels of inequality, and concludes "the historical pattern is clear; the cross-national pattern is clear: high inequality goes hand-in-hand with weak labor movements and vice-versa."<ref>Doree Armstrong (February 12, 2014). . ''UW Today.'' Retrieved December 20, 2014. See also: Jake Rosenfeld, '','' (], 2014), ISBN 0674725115</ref>


===Globalization=== ===Education===
{{main|Education}}
] may shift economic inequality from a global to a domestic scale.<ref name=econ190408/> When rich countries trade with poor countries, the low-skilled workers in the rich countries may see reduced wages as a result of the competition, while low-skilled workers in the poor countries may see increased wages. Trade economist ] estimates that trade liberalisation has had a measurable effect on the rising inequality in the United States. He attributes this trend to increased trade with poor countries and the fragmentation of the ], resulting in low skilled jobs becoming more tradeable. However, he concedes that the effect of trade on inequality in America is minor when compared to other causes, such as technological innovation, a view shared by other experts. Lawrence Katz estimates that trade has only accounted for 5-15% of rising income inequality. ] argues that technological innovation and automation has meant that low-skilled jobs have been replaced by ] in wealthier nations, and that wealthier countries no longer have significant numbers of low-skilled manufacturing workers that could be affected by competition from poor countries.<ref name=econ190408>
{{multiple image | total_width=450
{{cite news
| image1=20230810 Ivy-Plus admission rates vs parent income percentile.svg |caption1=] university admissions rates vary with the income of the students' parents, with the acceptance rate of the top 0.1% income percentile being almost twice as much as other students.<ref name=OpportunityInsights_202307>{{cite web |last1=Chetty |first1=Raj |last2=Deming |first2=David J. |last3=Friedman |first3=John N. |title=Diversifying Society's Leaders? The Determinants and Consequences of Admission to Highly Selective Colleges |page=2 |url=https://opportunityinsights.org/wp-content/uploads/2023/07/CollegeAdmissions_Nontech.pdf |publisher=Opportunity Insights |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230731024342/https://opportunityinsights.org/wp-content/uploads/2023/07/CollegeAdmissions_Nontech.pdf |archive-date=July 31, 2023 |date=July 2023 |url-status=live}} Figure 3. "Ivy-Plus" refers to ] schools plus others with similar prestige, rankings or selectivity.</ref>
| title = Economic Focus:
| image2=Going up or down advertisement.jpg |caption2=A 1916 ad for a vocational school appealed to Americans' belief in the possibility of self-betterment, as well as threatening economic insecurity through lack of education and the consequences of downward mobility in the ] during the ]
| work = ]
| publisher = The Economist Group
| location = London
| page = 81
| date = April 19, 2008
}} }}
An important factor in the creation of inequality is variation in individuals' access to education.<ref name="becker">{{cite web|url=http://www.american.com/archive/2007/may-june-magazine-contents/the-upside-of-income-inequality|title=The Upside of Income Inequality|last=Becker|first=Gary S.|date=May 2007|publisher=The America|author2=Murphy, Kevin M.|access-date=January 8, 2014|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140102212816/http://www.american.com/archive/2007/may-june-magazine-contents/the-upside-of-income-inequality/|archive-date=January 2, 2014|url-status=dead}}</ref> Education, especially in an area where there is a high demand for workers, creates high wages for those with this education.<ref>{{Cite report |first1= Barry |last1= Bosworth |first2= Gary |last2= Burtless |first3= C. Eugene |last3= Steuerle |date= December 1999 |title= Lifetime Earnings Patterns, the Distribution of Future Social Security Benefits, and the Impact of Pension Reform |type= report no. CRR WP 1999-06 |publisher= Center for Retirement Research at Boston College |location= Chestnut Hill, MA |url= http://urban.org/uploadedpdf/412137-lifetime-earnings.pdf |page= 43 |access-date= October 1, 2012 |archive-date= July 19, 2010 |archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20100719054205/http://www.urban.org/UploadedPDF/412137-lifetime-earnings.pdf |url-status= dead }}</ref> However, increases in education first increase and then decrease growth as well as income inequality. As a result, those who are unable to afford an education, or choose not to pursue optional education, generally receive much lower wages. The justification for this is that a lack of education leads directly to lower incomes, and thus lower aggregate saving and investment. Conversely, ] raises incomes and promotes growth because it helps to unleash the productive potential of the poor.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Shealy |first=Craig N. |date=November 1, 2009 |title=An Interview With Education for Sustainable Development "Young Voices": Beliefs and Values From the Next Generation of ESD Leaders |url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1891/1942-0617.1.2.135 |journal=Beliefs and Values |volume=1 |issue=2 |pages=135–141 |doi=10.1891/1942-0617.1.2.135 |doi-broken-date=December 2, 2024 |issn=1942-0617}}</ref>
</ref>


Access to education was in turn influenced by land inequalities. In the less industrialized parts of 19th century Europe, for example, landowners still held more political power than industrialists. These landowners did not benefit from educating their workers as much as industrialists did, since "educated workers have more incentives to migrate to urban, industrial areas than their less educated counterparts."<ref name=":7">{{Cite journal|last1=Baten|first1=Jörg|last2=Hippe|first2=Ralph|date=2017|title=Geography, land inequality and regional numeracy in Europe in historical perspective|journal=Journal of Economic Growth}}</ref> Consequently, lower incentives to promote education in regions where land inequality was high led to lower levels of ] in these regions.<ref name=":7" />
===Gender===
] 2008<ref>]. . OECD, Paris, 2008, p. 358.</ref>]]
In many countries, there is a ] which favors males in the ]. For example, the median full-time salary for U.S. women is 77% of that of U.S. men. Several factors other than discrimination may contribute to this gap. On average, women are more likely than men to consider factors other than pay when looking for work, and may be less willing to travel or relocate.<ref name="Forbes 2006">{{cite news| url=http://www.forbes.com/ceonetwork/2006/05/12/women-wage-gap-cx_wf_0512earningmore.html | work=Forbes | title=Are Women Earning More Than Men? | date=May 12, 2006}}</ref><ref>{{cite news| url=http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2007/04/02/AR2007040201262.html | work=The Washington Post | title=A Bargain At 77 Cents To a Dollar | first=Carrie | last=Lukas | date=April 3, 2007 | accessdate=May 3, 2010}}</ref> ], in his book ], claims that this difference is due to women not taking jobs due to marriage or pregnancy, but income studies show that that does not explain the entire difference. A U.S. Census's report stated that in US once other factors are accounted for there is still a difference in earnings between women and men.<ref>http://www.census.gov/prod/2004pubs/censr-15.pdf</ref> The income gap in other countries ranges from 53% in Botswana to -40% in Bahrain.<ref></ref>


===Economic liberalism, deregulation and decline of unions===
] and discrimination is argued to cause and perpetuate poverty and vulnerability in society as a whole.<ref name=ODI3>Nicola Jones, Rebecca Holmes, Jessica Espey 2008. . London: ]</ref> ] seek to provide the tools to demonstrate this feature of equity.<ref name=ODI3/>
{{Main|Economic liberalism|Deregulation|Labor unions in the United States}}


John Schmitt and Ben Zipperer (2006) of the CEPR point to ] and the reduction of business ] along with the decline of ] as one of the causes of economic inequality. In an analysis of the effects of intensive Anglo-American ] policies in comparison to continental European liberalism, where unions have remained strong, they concluded "The U.S. economic and social model is associated with substantial levels of social exclusion, including high levels of income inequality, high relative and absolute poverty rates, poor and unequal educational outcomes, poor health outcomes, and high rates of crime and incarceration. At the same time, the available evidence provides little support for the view that U.S.-style ] dramatically improves labor-market outcomes. Despite popular prejudices to the contrary, the U.S. economy consistently affords a lower level of economic mobility than all the continental European countries for which data is available."<ref>Schmitt, John and Ben Zipperer. 2006. "" CEPR</ref>
19th century socialists like ], ], ] and ] argued that the economic inequality between genders was the leading cause of economic inequality; however ] and ] believed that the inequality between social classes was the larger cause of inequality.<ref>{{cite book|title=The Real Wealth of Nations: Creating a Caring Economics|author=Riane Eisler|date=2007|page=73}}</ref>


More recently, the ] has published studies which found that the decline of unionization in many advanced economies and the establishment of ] economics have fueled rising income inequality.<ref>Michael Hiltzik (March 25, 2015). . ''].'' Retrieved March 26, 2015.</ref><ref>. ''Business Insider.'' May 2016.</ref>
=== Economic development ===
]


Contrary to the proponents of neoliberalism, ] have been proven to not be effective in resolving economic inequalities but have instead worsened it.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Srikanth |first=Anagha |date=2020-12-17 |title=Huge new study shows trickle-down economics makes inequality worse, researchers say |url=https://thehill.com/changing-america/respect/poverty/530731-huge-new-study-shows-trickle-down-economics-makes-inequality/ |access-date=2023-08-20 |website=The Hill |language=en-US}}</ref>
{{Main|Kuznets curve}}
Economist ] argued that levels of economic inequality are in large part the result of stages of ]. According to Kuznets, countries with low levels of development have relatively equal distributions of wealth. As a country develops, it acquires more capital, which leads to the owners of this capital having more wealth and income and introducing inequality. Eventually, through various possible redistribution mechanisms such as ] programs, more developed countries move back to lower levels of inequality.


=== Technology ===
Plotting the relationship between level of income and inequality, Kuznets saw middle-income developing economies level of inequality bulging out to form what is now known as the ]. Kuznets demonstrated this relationship using ]. However, more recent testing of this theory with superior ] has shown it to be very weak. Kuznets' curve predicts that income inequality will eventually decrease given time. As an example, income inequality did fall in the United States during its ] from 1910 to 1940 and thereafter.{{citation needed|date=June 2014}} However, recent data shows that the level of income inequality began to rise after the 1970s. This does not necessarily disprove Kuznets' theory. It may be possible that another Kuznets' cycle is occurring, specifically the move from the manufacturing sector to the service sector. This implies that it may be possible for multiple Kuznets' cycles to be in effect at any given time.
{{main|Digital Revolution|Information Technology}}
The growth in importance of ] has been credited with increasing income inequality.<ref name="Basu-2016">{{cite web|last1=Basu|first1=Kaushik|title=Is technology making inequality worse?|url=https://www.weforum.org/agenda/2016/01/is-technology-making-inequality-worse/|website=World Economic Forum|access-date=November 17, 2017|date=January 6, 2016}}</ref> Technology has been called "the main driver of the recent increases in inequality" by Erik Brynjolfsson, of ].<ref name="Rotman-2014">{{cite journal|last1=Rotman|first1=David|title=Technology and Inequality|journal=MIT Technology Review|date=October 21, 2014|url=https://www.technologyreview.com/s/531726/technology-and-inequality/|access-date=November 17, 2017}}</ref> In arguing against this explanation, Jonathan Rothwell notes that if technological advancement is measured by high rates of invention, there is a negative correlation between it and inequality. Countries with high invention rates{{snd}}"as measured by patent applications filed under the Patent Cooperation Treaty"{{snd}}exhibit lower inequality than those with less. In one country, the United States, "salaries of engineers and software developers rarely reach" above $390,000/year (the lower limit for the top 1% earners).<ref name="NYT-17-11-2017">{{cite news|last1=Rothwell|first1=Jonathan|title=Myths of the 1 Percent: What's Putting People at the Top|newspaper=The New York Times |url=https://www.nytimes.com/2017/11/17/upshot/income-inequality-united-states.html?action=click&module=MoreInSection&pgtype=Article&region=Footer&contentCollection=The%20Upshot|access-date=November 17, 2017|agency=The New York Times|date=November 17, 2017}}</ref>


Some researchers, such as Juliet B. Schor, highlight the role of for-profit online sharing economy platforms as an accelerator of income inequality and calls into question their supposed contribution in empowering outsiders of the labour market.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Schor|first=Juliet B.|date=February 10, 2017|title=Does the sharing economy increase inequality within the eighty percent?: findings from a qualitative study of platform providers|journal=Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society|volume=10|issue=2|pages=263–279|doi=10.1093/cjres/rsw047|issn=1752-1378|doi-access=free}}</ref>
===Individual preferences===
Related to cultural issues, diversity of preferences within a society may contribute to economic inequality. When faced with the choice between working harder to earn more money or enjoying more leisure time, equally capable individuals with identical earning potential may choose different strategies.{{Citation needed|date=November 2012}} The trade-off between work and leisure is particularly important in the supply side of the labor market in ].{{citation needed|date=November 2012}}


Taking the example of TaskRabbit, a labour service platform, she shows that a large proportion of providers already have a stable full-time job and participate part-time in the platform as an opportunity to increase their income by diversifying their activities outside employment, which tends to restrict the volume of work remaining for the minority of platform workers.
Likewise, individuals in a society often have different levels of ]. When equally-able individuals undertake risky activities with the potential of large payoffs, such as starting new businesses, some ventures succeed and some fail. The presence of both successful and unsuccessful ventures in a society results in economic inequality even when all individuals are identical.{{Citation needed|date=November 2012}}


In addition, there is an important phenomenon of labour substitution as manual tasks traditionally performed by workers without a degree (or just a college degree) integrated into the labour market in the traditional economy sectors are now performed by workers with a high level of education (in 2013, 70% of TaskRabbit's workforce held a bachelor's degree, 20% a master's degree and 5% a PhD).<ref>{{Cite web|last=Newton|first=Casey|date=May 23, 2013 |title=Temping fate: can TaskRabbit go from side gigs to real jobs?|url=https://www.theverge.com/2013/5/23/4352116/taskrabbit-temp-agency-gig-economy|access-date=April 30, 2021|website=The Verge}}</ref> The development of platforms, which are increasingly capturing demand for these manual services at the expense of non-platform companies, may therefore benefit mainly skilled workers who are offered more earning opportunities that can be used as supplemental or transitional work during periods of unemployment.
===Wealth concentration===
{{Main|Wealth concentration}}
Wealth concentration is a {{According to whom|theoretical|date=July 2014}} process by which, under certain conditions, newly created ] concentrates in the possession of already-wealthy individuals or entities. According to this theory, those who already hold wealth have the means to ] in new sources of creating wealth or to otherwise leverage the accumulation of wealth, thus are the beneficiaries of the new wealth. Over time, wealth condensation can significantly contribute to the persistence of inequality within society. Thomas Piketty in his book '']'' argues that the fundamental force for divergence is the usually greater return of capital (r) than economic growth (g), and that larger fortunes generate higher returns


It has also been proposed that information technologies contribute to "winner take most" market concentration, reducing the need for labor across competing suppliers.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Autor |first1=David |last2=Dorn |first2=David |last3=Katz |first3=Lawrence F |last4=Patterson |first4=Christina |last5=Van Reenen |first5=John |date=May 1, 2020 |title=The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms* |journal=The Quarterly Journal of Economics |volume=135 |issue=2 |pages=645–709 |doi=10.1093/qje/qjaa004 |issn=0033-5533}}</ref> Market concentration drives down labor's share of the GDP, increasing the wealth of capital and thereby exacerbating inequality.
===Rent seeking===
Economist ] argues that rather than explaining concentrations of wealth and income, market forces should serve as a brake on such concentration, which may better be explained by the non-market force known as "]". While the market will bid up compensation for rare and desired skills to reward wealth creation, greater productivity, etc., it will also prevent successful entrepreneurs from earning excess profits by fostering competition to cut prices, profits and large compensation.<ref name=stiglitz.p35>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future (pp. 30–1, 35–6). Norton. Kindle Edition.</ref> A better explainer of growing inequality, according to Stiglitz, is the use of political power generated by wealth by certain groups to shape government policies financially beneficial to them. This process, known to economists as ], brings income not from creation of wealth but from "grabbing a larger share of the wealth that would otherwise have been produced without their effort"<ref name=stiglitz.p32>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future (p. 32). Norton. Kindle Edition.</ref>


==== Automation ====
Rent seeking is often thought to be the province of societies with weak institutions and weak rule of law, but Stiglitz believes there is no shortage of it in developed societies such as the United States. Examples of rent seeking leading to inequality include
Economists have linked ] to increases in economic inequality, as automation raises the returns to wealth and contributes to stagnating wages at the lower end of the wage distribution.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Moll |first1=Benjamin |last2=Rachel |first2=Lukasz |last3=Restrepo |first3=Pascual |date=2022 |title=Uneven Growth: Automation's Impact on Income and Wealth Inequality |url=https://www.econometricsociety.org/doi/10.3982/ECTA19417 |journal=Econometrica |language=en |volume=90 |issue=6 |pages=2645–2683 |doi=10.3982/ECTA19417 |issn=0012-9682}}</ref> Several economists have suggested that automation has increased income inequality by causing low skill jobs to be replaced with machines operated by technologically skilled workers, thereby reducing the demand for unskilled labor while increasing the demand for skilled labor.{{ r | Peterson_2017 | p=1 | q=Many explanations for the current increases in economic inequality have been offered. Autor (2014), Milanovic (2016), Atkinson (2015) and Deaton (2013) all point to skills-biased technological change as a major cause. Technological innovations in recent years have often led to the replacement of unskilled workers with computerized machines that require highly skilled operators. The result is that demand for skilled workers has increased driving up their wages while the opposite effect occurs for unskilled workers increasing the disparities in labor income. Skills depend on education so wage inequalities may also reflect differences in educational opportunities. }}
* the obtaining of public resources by "rent-collectors" at below market prices (such as ],<ref></ref> or selling mineral resources for a nominal price<ref></ref><ref>]</ref> in the US),
* selling services and products to the public at above market prices<ref name=stiglitz.p48>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality, p. 48.</ref> (] in the US that ] prices of drugs with the drug companies, costing the US government an estimated $50 billion or more per year),
* securing government tolerance of monopoly power (The richest person in the world in 2011, ], controlled Mexico's newly privatized telecommunication industry<ref name=stiglitz.p42>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality, p. 42.</ref>).


===Globalization===
Since rent seeking aims to "pluck the goose to obtain the largest amount of feathers with the least possible amount of hissing" – it is by nature obscure, avoiding public spotlight in legal fine print, or camouflaged its extraction with widely accepted rationalizations (markets are naturally competitive and so need no government regulation against monopolies<ref name=stiglitz.p44>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality, p. 44.</ref>).
{{main|Globalization|International inequality}}


]": Change in real income between 1988 and 2008 at various income percentiles of global income distribution.<ref name="heymancenter.org">{{Cite web|url=https://sofheyman.org/|title=SOF/Heyman &#124; The Society of Fellows and Heyman Center for the Humanities|website=SOF/Heyman}}</ref>]]{{Anchor|Elephant curve|Elephant chart}}
===Finance industry===
] may shift economic inequality from a global to a domestic scale.<ref name=econ190408>
Jamie Galbraith argues that countries with larger financial sectors have greater inequality, and the link is not an accident.<ref>James K. Galbraith, Inequality and Instability: A Study of the World Economy Just before the Great Crisis (New York: Oxford University Press, 2012).</ref><ref>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future, p. 334. Norton. Kindle Edition.</ref>
{{cite news

| title = Economic Focus
===Mitigating factors===
| newspaper = ]
Countries with a ] ] have lower levels of inequality.<ref>{{cite journal |last1= Bradley |first= David |last2= Huber |first2= Evelyne |last3= Moller |first3= Stephanie |last4= Nielsen |first4= François |last5= Stephens |first5= John D. |year= 2003 |title= Distribution and Redistribution in Post-Industrial Democracies |url= http://www.unc.edu/~jdsteph/documents/common/articles/World%20Politics%2003.pdf |journal= World Politics |volume= 55 |issue= 2 |pages= 193–228 |doi= 10.1353/wp.2003.0009 }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1= Huber |first1= Evelyne |last2= Nielsen |first2= François |last3= Pribble |first3= Jenny |last4= Stephens |first4= John D. |year= 2006 |title= Politics and Inequality in Latin America and the Caribbean |journal= ] |volume= 71 |issue= 6 |pages= 943–963 |quote= A strong record of democracy and a left-leaning legislative partisan balance are associated with lower levels of inequality. |jstor= 25472438 |doi= 10.1177/000312240607100604}}</ref> Many factors constrain economic inequality – they may be divided into two classes: government sponsored, and market driven. The relative merits and effectiveness of each approach is a subject of debate.
| location = London

| page = 81
Typical ] initiatives to reduce economic inequality include:
| date = April 19, 2008
* ]: increasing the supply of skilled labor and reducing income inequality due to education differentials.<ref>
{{cite journal |quote = this study shows that income distribution improves by ensuring that expenditures per primary-school student are adequately kept up with increases in cohort size to prevent education quality from deteriorating.
| url = http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_qa5501/is_201004/ai_n53077213/pg_9/?tag=content;col1
| title = HOW CAN EDUCATION POLICY IMPROVE INCOME DISTRIBUTION? AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF EDUCATION STAGES AND MEASURES ON INCOME INEQUALITY |journal = The Journal of Developing Areas |accessdate=May 24, 2010 |year = 2010 |last1= Keller |first1= K.R. }}
</ref>
* ]ation: the rich are taxed proportionally more than the poor, reducing the amount of income inequality in society if the change in taxation does not cause changes in income.<ref>
{{cite web |quote=While some degree of progressive income taxation may be a useful strategy for those who desire increased income equality, broader economic interventionism is not consistent with their desired goal. |url=http://www.thefreelibrary.com/The+impact+of+economic+growth,+tax+policy+and+economic+freedom+on+...-a0189290253
| title = The impact of economic growth, tax policy and economic freedom on income inequality – Conclusions
| accessdate = May 24, 2010
}} }}
</ref> When rich countries trade with poor countries, the low-skilled workers in the rich countries may see reduced wages as a result of the competition, while low-skilled workers in the poor countries may see increased wages. Trade economist Paul Krugman estimates that trade liberalisation has had a measurable effect on the rising ]. He attributes this trend to increased trade with poor countries and the fragmentation of the ], resulting in low skilled jobs becoming more tradeable.<ref>{{Cite web |work=Economic Issues |series=11 |title=Does Globalization Lower Wages and Export Jobs? |url=https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/issues11/ |access-date=June 18, 2022 |publisher=International Monetary Fund |language=en-US |date= September 1997 |first1= Matthew J. |last1=Slaughter |first2=Phillip |last2=Swagel }}</ref>
</ref>


Anthropologist ] contends that globalization and "]" set off the "]", a significant driver of surging global inequality. Another driver Hickel mentions is the ] system which advanced the need for structural adjustment in the first place.<ref>{{cite book |last= Hickel|first=Jason|date=2018 |title=The Divide: A Brief Guide to Global Inequality and its Solutions|publisher=Windmill Books|pages=175–176 |isbn=978-1786090034}}</ref>
] outside of government intervention that can reduce economic inequality include:
* ]: with rising wealth & income, a person may spend more. In an extreme example, if one person owned everything, they would immediately need to hire people to maintain their properties, thus reducing the ].<ref>García-Peñalosa (2006)</ref>


==Effects== ===Gender===
{{main|Gender inequality}}
Effects of inequality researchers have found include higher rates of health and social problems, and lower rates of social goods,<ref name=pickett.p5/> a lower level of economic utility in society from resources devoted on high-end consumption,<ref name=happiniess/> and even a lower level of economic growth when human capital is neglected for high-end consumption.<ref name=more/> For the top 21 industrialised countries, counting each person equally, ] is lower in more unequal countries (] = -.907).<ref>'''' J Epidemiol Community Health 2005;59:158-162.</ref> A similar relationship exists among US states (r = -.620).<ref>'''' BMJ 1996;312:999.</ref>


] 2015<ref>]. {{webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081206221033/http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/54/57/40846335.pdf |date=December 6, 2008 }}. OECD, Paris, 2008, p. 358.</ref>]]
2013 Economics Nobel prize winner ] said that rising inequality in the United States and elsewhere is the most important problem.<ref>{{cite news|last=Christoffersen|first=John|title=Rising inequality 'most important problem,' says Nobel-winning economist|url=http://www.stltoday.com/business/local/rising-inequality-most-important-problem-says-nobel-winning-economist/article_a5065957-05c3-5ac0-ba5b-dab91c22973a.html|accessdate=October 19, 2013|newspaper=St. Louis Post-Dispatch|date=October 14, 2013}}</ref> Increasing inequality harms economic growth. High and persistent ], in which inequality increases, has a negative effect on subsequent long-run economic growth. Unemployment can harm growth not only because it is a waste of resources, but also because it generates redistributive pressures and subsequent distortions, drives people to poverty, constrains liquidity limiting labor mobility, and erodes self-esteem promoting social dislocation, unrest and conflict. Policies aiming at controlling unemployment and in particular at reducing its inequality-associated effects support economic growth.<ref name=Castells-Quintana>{{cite journal|last=Castells-Quintana|first=David|author2=Vicente Royuela|title=Unemployment and long-run economic growth: The role of income inequality and urbanisation|journal=Investigaciones Regionales|year=2012|volume=12|issue=24|pages=153–173|url=http://diposit.ub.edu/dspace/bitstream/2445/33140/1/617293.pdf|accessdate=October 17, 2013}}</ref>
In many countries, there is a ] in favor of males in the ]. Several factors other than discrimination contribute to this gap. On average, women are more likely than men to consider factors other than pay when looking for work and may be less willing to travel or relocate.<ref name="Forbes 2006">{{cite news |work=Forbes |title=Are Women Earning More Than Men? |date=May 12, 2006 |url=https://www.forbes.com/ceonetwork/2006/05/12/women-wage-gap-cx_wf_0512earningmore.html |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081210154124/http://www.forbes.com/ceonetwork/2006/05/12/women-wage-gap-cx_wf_0512earningmore.html |url-status=dead |archive-date=December 10, 2008}}</ref><ref>{{cite news| url=https://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2007/04/02/AR2007040201262.html | newspaper=The Washington Post | title=A Bargain At 77 Cents To a Dollar | first=Carrie | last=Lukas | date=April 3, 2007 | access-date=May 3, 2010}}</ref> ], in his book '']'', claims that this difference is due to women not taking jobs due to marriage or pregnancy. A U.S. Census's report stated that in US once other factors are accounted for there is still a difference in earnings between women and men.<ref>{{cite web |title=Evidence From Census 2000 About Earnings by Detailed Occupation for Men and Women | last=Weinberg | first=Daniel H | url=https://www.census.gov/prod/2004pubs/censr-15.pdf |date= May 2004 |access-date=February 21, 2017}}</ref> A study done on three post-soviet countries ], ], and ] reveals that gender is one of the driving forces of income inequality, and being female has a significant negative effect on income when other factors are held equal. The results show more than 50% gender pay gap in all three countries.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Habibov |first=Nazim |date=2012 |title=Income inequality and its driving forces in transitional countries: evidence from Armenia, Azerbaijan and Georgia |url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/271672769 |journal=Journal of Comparative Social Welfare |volume=28 |issue=3 |pages=209–211 |doi=10.1080/17486831.2012.749504 |s2cid=153681101 |access-date=}}</ref> These findings are because usually employers tend to avoid hiring women because of possible maternity leave. Other reason for this can be ], which implies that women are usually accumulated in lower-paid positions and sectors, such as social services and education.


=== Race ===
The economic stratification of society into "elites" and "masses" played a central role in the collapse of other advanced civilizations such as the Roman, Han and Gupta empires.<ref>Safa Motesharrei, Jorge Rivas and Eugenia Kalnay (November 13, 2012). ''.'' ]. Retrieved March 19, 2014.</ref>
{{Main|Social inequality}}There is also a globally recognized disparity in the wealth, income, and ] of people of different races. In many nations, data exists to suggest that members of certain racial demographics experience lower wages, fewer opportunities for career and educational advancement, and ].<ref name=":3">{{Cite journal |date=April 5, 2017|editor-last=Brady|editor-first=David|editor2-last=Burton|editor2-first=Linda M.|title=The Oxford Handbook of the Social Science of Poverty|journal=Oxford Handbooks Online|isbn=978-0199914050 |doi=10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199914050.001.0001}}</ref> Studies have uncovered the emergence of what is called "ethnic capital", by which people belonging to a race that has experienced discrimination are born into a disadvantaged family from the beginning and therefore have less resources and opportunities at their disposal.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Becker|first1=Gary S.|last2=Tomes|first2=Nigel|date=December 1979|title=An Equilibrium Theory of the Distribution of Income and Intergenerational Mobility|journal=Journal of Political Economy|volume=87|issue=6|pages=1153–1189|doi=10.1086/260831|s2cid=153939481|issn=0022-3808}}</ref><ref name=":2">{{Cite report|last=Borjas |first=George|date=July 1991|title=Ethnic Capital and Intergenerational Mobility|location=Cambridge, MA|doi=10.3386/w3788|doi-access=free}}</ref> The universal lack of education, technical and cognitive skills, and inheritable wealth within a particular race is often passed down between generations, compounding in effect to make escaping these racialized ] increasingly difficult.<ref name=":2" /> Additionally, ethnic groups that experience significant disparities are often also minorities, at least in representation though often in number as well, in the nations where they experience the harshest disadvantage. As a result, they are often segregated either by government policy or social stratification, leading to ethnic communities that experience widespread gaps in wealth and aid.<ref>{{Cite book|date=2010|title=Economic Mobility Project: An Initiative of the Pew Charitable Trusts}}{{page?|date=August 2024}}{{ISBN?}}</ref>


Redlining intentionally excluded black Americans from accumulating intergenerational wealth. The effects of this exclusion on black Americans' health continue to play out daily, generations later, in the same communities. This is evident currently in the disproportionate effects that COVID-19 has had on the same communities which the HOLC redlined in the 1930s. Research published in September 2020 overlaid maps of the highly affected COVID-19 areas with the HOLC maps, showing that those areas marked "risky" to lenders because they contained minority residents were the same neighborhoods most affected by COVID-19. The Centers for Disease Control (CDC) looks at inequities in the social determinants of health like concentrated poverty and healthcare access that are interrelated and influence health outcomes with regard to COVID-19 as well as quality of life in general for minority groups. The CDC points to discrimination within health care, education, criminal justice, housing, and finance, direct results of systematically subversive tactics like redlining which led to chronic and toxic stress that shaped social and economic factors for minority groups, increasing their risk for COVID-19. Healthcare access is similarly limited by factors like a lack of public transportation, child care, and communication and language barriers which result from the spatial and economic isolation of minority communities from redlining. Educational, income, and wealth gaps that result from this isolation mean that minority groups' limited access to the job market may force them to remain in fields that have a higher risk of exposure to the virus, without options to take time off. Finally, a direct result of redlining is the overcrowding of minority groups into neighborhoods that do not boast adequate housing to sustain burgeoning populations, leading to crowded conditions that make prevention strategies for COVID-19 nearly impossible to implement.<ref>"Mapping Inequality." Digital Scholarship Lab, dsl.richmond.edu/panorama/redlining/.</ref><ref>{{cite web |last1=Richardson |first1=Jason |last2=Mitchell |first2=Bruce C. |last3=Meier |first3=Helen C.S. |last4=Lynch |first4=Emily |last5=Edlebi |first5=Jad |date=10 September 2020 |title=Redlining and Neighborhood Health |url=https://ncrc.org/holc-health/ |publisher=NCRC}}</ref><ref name="Myers, JoAnne 2020">{{cite book |last1=Myers |first1=JoAnne |title=The good citizen: the markers of privilege in America |date=2020 |isbn=978-1-351-00669-9 |doi=10.4324/9781351006705 |oclc=1111653987 |s2cid=211349002}}{{page needed|date=March 2022}}</ref><ref>{{cite news |last1=Badger |first1=Emily |date=10 May 2019 |title=Can the Racial Wealth Gap Be Closed Without Speaking of Race? |url=https://www.nytimes.com/2019/05/10/upshot/racial-wealth-gap-2020-candidates.html |work=The New York Times}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Danaei |first1=Goodarz |last2=Rimm |first2=Eric B. |last3=Oza |first3=Shefali |last4=Kulkarni |first4=Sandeep C. |last5=Murray |first5=Christopher J. L. |last6=Ezzati |first6=Majid |date=2010 |title=The Promise of Prevention: The Effects of Four Preventable Risk Factors on National Life Expectancy and Life Expectancy Disparities by Race and County in the United States |journal=PLOS Medicine |volume=7 |issue=3 |pages=e1000248 |doi=10.1371/journal.pmed.1000248 |pmc=2843596 |pmid=20351772 |doi-access=free}}</ref><ref>{{cite news |last1=Howell |first1=Brittani |date=24 June 2020 |title=How Redlining, Racism Harm Black Americans' Health |url=https://www.wyso.org/2020-06-24/how-redlining-racism-harm-black-americans-health |work=WYSO}}</ref><ref name=":52">{{Cite web |last=CDC |date=2020-04-30 |title=Communities, Schools, Workplaces, & Events |url=https://www.cdc.gov/coronavirus/2019-ncov/community/health-equity/race-ethnicity.html |access-date=2020-12-09 |website=Centers for Disease Control and Prevention|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200805071354/https://www.cdc.gov/coronavirus/2019-ncov/community/health-equity/race-ethnicity.html |archive-date=August 5, 2020 }}</ref>
===Health and social cohesion===
British researchers ] and ] have found higher rates of health and social problems (], ], ]s, ]s, ], child conflict, drug use), and lower rates of social goods (], educational performance, ], ], ], even numbers of ]s issued) in countries and states with higher inequality. Using statistics from 23 developed countries and the 50 states of the US, they found social/health problems lower in countries like ] and ] and states like ] and ] with high levels of equality, than in countries (] and ]) and states (] and ]) with large differences in household income.<ref></ref>
] in 282 metropolitan areas of the ]. Mortality is strongly associated with higher income inequality, but, within levels of income inequality, not with per capita income.]]


As a general rule, races which have been historically and systematically colonized (typically indigenous ethnicities) continue to experience lower levels of financial stability in the present day. The ] is considered to be particularly victimized by this phenomenon, though the exact socioeconomic manifestations change across different regions.<ref name=":3" />
For most of human history higher material living standards – full stomachs, access to clean water and warmth from fuel – led to better health and longer lives.<ref name=pickett.p5>Pickett and Wilkinson, ''The Spirit Level'', 2011, p. 5.</ref> This pattern of higher incomes-longer lives still holds among poorer countries, where life expectancy increases rapidly as per capita income increases, but in recent decades it has slowed down among middle income countries and plateaued among the richest thirty or so countries in the world.<ref>{{cite journal |last= Sapolsky|first=Robert|date=December 2005 |title=Sick of Poverty |journal=] |url= http://www.sciam.com/article.cfm?chanID=sa006&colID=1&articleID=0008B048-D21B-137C-8FA583414B7F0101 |accessdate=April 15, 2009 |doi= 10.1038/scientificamerican1205-92 |volume= 293 |issue= 6 |pages= 92 }}</ref> ] live no longer on average (about 77 years in 2004) than ] (78 years) or ] (78), though the USA has a higher GDP per capita. Life expectancy in Sweden (80 years) and Japan (82) – where income was more equally distributed – was longer.<ref>Pickett and Wilkinson, ''The Spirit Level'', 2011, p. 82.</ref><ref>(At the same time however, there is a strong connection between average income and health ''within'' countries. Example: Comparing average death rates in United States zip code areas organized by average income finds the highest income zip codes average a little over 90 deaths per 10,000, the poorest zip codes a little over 50 deaths and a "strikingly" regular gradient of death rates for income in between. source: Figure 1.4, Pickett and Wilkinson, ''The Spirit Level'', 2011, p. 13, Authors: "What is so striking about Figure 1.4 is how regular the health gradient is right across society". Data from G.D. Smith, J.D. Neaton, D. Wentworth, R. Stamler, J. Stamler, "Socioeconomic differentials in mortality risk among men screened for the Multiple Risk Factor Intervention Trial: 1. White men.", ''American Journal of Public Health'' (2008) 98 (4): 486–96)</ref>


==== Westernized Nations ====
In recent years the characteristic that has strongly correlated with health in developed countries is income inequality. Creating an index of "Health and Social Problems" from nine factors, authors Richard Wilkinson and Kate Pickett found health and social problems "more common in countries with bigger income inequalities",<ref>Pickett and Wilkinson, ''The Spirit Level'', 2011, pp. 306–9. Figure 2.2 found on p. 20 and </ref><ref>the authors found a Pearson Correlation Coefficient of 0.87 for the index and inequality among 20 developed countries for which data was available. Pickett and Wilkinson, ''The Spirit Level'', 2011, p. 310.</ref> and more common among states in the US with larger income inequalities.<ref>a coefficient of 0.59 for 40 US states for which data was available (the index for US states did not include a component for mobility in its index). For both populations the statistical significance p-value was >0.01. Pickett and Wilkinson, ''The Spirit Level'', 2011, p. 310.</ref> Other studies have confirmed this relationship. The ] index of "child well-being in rich countries", studying 40 indicators in 22 countries, correlates with greater equality but not per capita income.<ref>compare figures 2.6 and 2.7 in Pickett and Wilkinson, ''The Spirit Level'', 2011, pp. 23–4. Data from The United Nations Children’s Fund, 2007</ref>
While the progression of civil rights movements and justice reform has improved access to education and other economic opportunities in politically advanced nations, racial income and wealth disparity still exists.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Bloome|first1=D.|last2=Western|first2=B.|date=December 1, 2011 |title=Cohort Change and Racial Differences in Educational and Income Mobility|journal=Social Forces |volume=90|issue=2|pages=375–395|doi=10.1093/sf/sor002|s2cid=16514651|issn=0037-7732}}</ref> In the United States for example, African American populations are more likely to drop out of high school and college, are typically employed for fewer hours at lower wages, have lower than average intergenerational wealth, and are more likely to use welfare as young adults than their white counterparts.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Herring|first1=Cedric|last2=Conley|first2=Dalton |date=March 2000|title=Being Black, Living in the Red: Race, Wealth, and Social Policy in America |journal=Contemporary Sociology|volume=29|issue=2|pages=349|doi=10.2307/2654395|jstor=2654395|issn=0094-3061}}</ref> The racial wealth gap in the US has been maintained throughout history. In 1863, two years prior to emancipation from slavery, Black people owned 0.5 percent of the US national wealth, while in 2019 it is just over 1.5 percent.<ref>{{cite news |title=Why the racial wealth gap persists, more than 150 years after emancipation |url=https://www.washingtonpost.com/outlook/2019/06/19/why-racial-wealth-gap-persists-more-than-years-after-emancipation/ |access-date=July 5, 2024 |newspaper=The Washington Post}}</ref>


Mexican-Americans, while suffering less debilitating socioeconomic factors than black Americans, experience deficiencies in the same areas when compared to whites and have not assimilated financially to the level of stability experienced by white Americans as a whole.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Vallejo|first=Jody Agius |date=December 2010|title=Generations of exclusion: Mexican Americans, assimilation and race|journal=Latino Studies|volume=8|issue=4 |pages=572–574|doi=10.1057/lst.2010.45|s2cid=143814091|issn=1476-3435}}</ref> These experiences are the effects of the measured disparity due to race in countries like the US, where studies show that in comparison to whites, blacks suffer from drastically lower levels of upward ], higher levels of downward mobility, and poverty that is more easily transmitted to offspring as a result of the disadvantage stemming from the era of slavery and post-slavery ] that has been passed through racial generations to the present.<ref name=":4">{{Cite journal|last1=Bowles |first1=Samuel|last2=Gintis|first2=Herbert|date=August 1, 2002|title=The Inheritance of Inequality |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives|volume=16|issue=3|pages=3–30|doi=10.1257/089533002760278686 |issn=0895-3309|doi-access=free}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Bhattacharya|first1=Debopam|last2=Mazumder |first2=Bhashkar|date=2010|title=A Nonparametric Analysis of Black-White Differences in Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States|journal=Quantitative Economics|volume=2|issue=3|pages=335–379 |doi=10.2139/ssrn.1066819 |hdl=10419/150324|s2cid=55109224|issn=1556-5068|hdl-access=free}}</ref><ref>{{Citation|last=Hertz|first=Tom|editor1-first=Samuel|editor1-last=Bowles|editor2-first=Herbert|editor2-last=Gintis|editor3-first=Melissa|editor3-last=Osborne Groves|title=Chapter Five. Rags, Riches, and Race The Intergenerational Economic Mobility of Black and White Families in the United States|date=December 31, 2009|work=Unequal Chances|pages=165–191|place=Princeton |publisher=Princeton University Press |doi=10.1515/9781400835492.165|isbn=978-1400835492}}</ref> These are lasting financial inequalities that apply in varying magnitudes to most non-white populations in nations such as the US, the UK, France, Spain, Australia, etc.<ref name=":3" />
Pickett and Wilkinson argue that inequality and ] lead to higher levels of psychosocial ] and ] anxiety which can lead to depression, chemical dependency, less community life, parenting problems and stress-related diseases.<ref name=thinktanks>| Robert Booth| The Guardian| August 13, 2010</ref>


====Social cohesion==== ==== Latin America ====
In the countries of the Caribbean, Central America, and South America, many ethnicities continue to deal with the effects of European colonization, and in general nonwhites tend to be noticeably poorer than whites in this region. In many countries with significant populations of indigenous races and those of Afro-descent (such as Mexico, Colombia, Chile, etc.) income levels can be roughly half as high as those experiences by white demographics, and this inequity is accompanied by systematically unequal access to education, career opportunities, and poverty relief. This region of the world, apart from urbanizing areas like Brazil and Costa Rica, continues to be understudied and often the racial disparity is denied by Latin Americans who consider themselves to be living in post-racial and post-colonial societies far removed from intense social and economic stratification despite the evidence to the contrary.<ref>{{Cite book|last1=de Ferranti|first1=David|last2=Perry|first2=Guillermo E.|last3=Ferreira|first3=Francisco|last4=Walton |first4=Michael|year=2004|title=Inequality in Latin America|doi=10.1596/0-8213-5665-8|isbn=978-0821356654}}</ref>
{{Further|Social cohesion}}
Research has shown an inverse link between income inequality and social cohesion. In more equal societies, people are much more likely to ] each other, measures of ] (the benefits of goodwill, fellowship, mutual sympathy and social connectedness among groups who make up a social units) suggest greater community involvement, and ] rates are consistently lower.


==== Africa ====
Comparing results from the question "would others take advantage of you if they got the chance?" in ] and statistics on income inequality, Eric Uslaner and Mitchell Brown found there is a high correlation between the amount of trust in society and the amount of income equality.<ref> Eric Uslaner and Mitchell Brown, 2002</ref> A 2008 article by Andersen and Fetner also found a strong relationship between economic inequality within and across countries and tolerance for 35 democracies.
African countries, too, continue to deal with the effects of the ], which set back economic development as a whole for blacks of African citizenship more than any other region. The degree to which colonizers stratified their holdings on the continent on the basis of race has had a direct correlation in the magnitude of disparity experienced by nonwhites in the nations that eventually rose from their colonial status. Former French colonies, for example, see much higher rates of income inequality between whites and nonwhites as a result of the rigid hierarchy imposed by the French who lived in Africa at the time.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Bossuroy|first1=Thomas|last2=Cogneau |first2=Denis|date=April 18, 2013|title=Social Mobility in Five African Countries|journal=Review of Income and Wealth|volume=59|pages=S84–S110|doi=10.1111/roiw.12037|s2cid=154317227 |hdl=10.1111/roiw.12037|hdl-access=free|issn=0034-6586}}</ref> Another example is found in South Africa, which, still reeling from the socioeconomic impacts of ], experiences some of the highest racial income and wealth inequality in all of Africa.<ref name=":4" /> In these and other countries like Nigeria, Zimbabwe, and Sierra Leone, movements of civil reform have initially led to improved access to financial advancement opportunities, but data{{when|date=April 2021}} shows that for nonwhites this progress is either stalling or erasing itself in the newest generation of blacks that seek education and improved transgenerational wealth. The economic status of one's parents continues to define and predict the financial futures of African and minority ethnic groups.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Peil|first=Margaret|date=January 1990|title=Intergenerational mobility through education: Nigeria, Sierra Leone and Zimbabwe|journal=International Journal of Educational Development|volume=10|issue=4|pages=311–325|doi=10.1016/s0738-0593(09)90008-6|issn=0738-0593}}</ref>{{needs update|date=April 2021}}


==== Asia ====
In two studies ] established links between ] and economic inequality. His most important studies<ref> (Putnam, Leonardi, and Nanetti, 1993)</ref><ref>Robert Putnam, ]: The Collapse and Revival of American Community 2000</ref> established these links in both the ] and in ]. His explanation for this relationship is that
Asian regions and countries such as China, the Middle East, and Central Asia have been vastly understudied in terms of racial disparity, but even here the effects of Western colonization provide similar results to those found in other parts of the globe.<ref name=":3" /> Additionally, cultural and historical practices such as the ] in India leave their marks as well. While the disparity is greatly improving in the case of India, there still exists social stratification between peoples of lighter and darker skin tones that cumulatively result in income and wealth inequality, manifesting in many of the same poverty traps seen elsewhere.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Hnatkovska|first1=Viktoria |last2=Lahiri|first2=Amartya|last3=Paul|first3=Sourabh B.|date=2013|title=Breaking the Caste Barrier: Intergenerational Mobility in India|journal=Journal of Human Resources|volume=48|issue=2 |pages=435–473 |doi=10.1353/jhr.2013.0012|s2cid=13341683|issn=1548-8004}}</ref>


=== Economic development ===
<blockquote>
]
Community and equality are mutually reinforcing... Social capital and economic inequality moved in tandem through most of the twentieth century. In terms of the distribution of wealth and income, America in the 1950s and 1960s was more egalitarian than it had been in more than a century... hose same decades were also the high point of social connectedness and civic engagement. Record highs in equality and social capital coincided. Conversely, the last third of the twentieth century was a time of growing inequality and eroding social capital... The timing of the two trends is striking: somewhere around 1965–70 America reversed course and started becoming both less just economically and less well connected socially and politically.<ref>Robert Putnam, ]: The Collapse and Revival of American Community, 2000, pp. 359.</ref></blockquote>


{{Main|Kuznets curve}}
Albrekt Larsen has advanced this explanation by a comparative study of how trust increased in Denmark and Sweden in the latter part of the 20th century while it decreased in the US and UK. It is argued that inequality levels influence how citizens imagine the trustworthiness of fellow citizens. In this model social trust is not about relations to people you meet (as in Putnam's model) but about people you imagine.<ref>Albrekt Larsen, Christian (2013). The Rise and Fall of Social Cohesion: The Construction and De-construction of Social Trust in the US, UK, Sweden and Denmark. Oxford: Oxford University Press</ref>
Economist ] argued that levels of economic inequality are in large part the result of stages of ]. According to Kuznets, countries with low levels of development have relatively equal distributions of wealth. In the early stages, individual sectors or industries are developed first, which leads to an unequal distribution of income and wealth, resulting in growing inequality within a country. As the economy progresses and development takes place in more economic sectors, eventually attracting more workers, economic inequality decreases.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Korpi |first1=Walter |last2=Palme |first2=Joakim |date=1998 |title=The Paradox of Redistribution and Strategies of Equality: Welfare State Institutions, Inequality, and Poverty in the Western Countries |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/2657333 |journal=American Sociological Review |volume=63 |issue=5 |pages=661–687 |jstor=2657333 |issn=0003-1224}}</ref> Although the Kuznets curve described the development of inequality well at the time of its publication, there is now a growing number of critical voices questioning the link between inequality and development. <ref>{{Cite book |last=Milanović |first=Branko |title=Global inequality: a new approach for the age of globalization |date=2018 |publisher=The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press |isbn=978-0-674-98403-5 |edition=1st Harvard University Press paperback |location=Cambridge, MA; London}}</ref>


===Wealth concentration===
The economist ] has argued that economic inequality has led to distrust of business and government.<ref>The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future, Stiglitz, J.E., (2012) W.W. Norton & Company, ISBN 978-0393088694</ref>
{{Main|Wealth concentration|Billionaire|Oligarchy|l1 = }}
Wealth concentration is the process by which, under certain conditions, newly created ] concentrates in the possession of already-wealthy individuals or entities. Accordingly, those who already hold wealth have the means to ] in new sources of creating wealth or to otherwise leverage the accumulation of wealth, and thus they are the beneficiaries of the new wealth. Over time, wealth concentration can significantly contribute to the persistence of inequality within society. ] in his book '']'' argues that the fundamental force for divergence is the usually greater return of capital (r) than economic growth (g), and that larger fortunes generate higher returns.<ref>pp.&nbsp;384 Table 12.2, ''U.S. university endowment size vs. real annual rate of return''</ref>


====Crime==== ===Rent seeking===
{{main|Rent-seeking}}
] has also been shown to be correlated with inequality in society. Most studies looking into the relationship have concentrated on ]s – since homicides are almost identically defined across all nations and jurisdictions. There have been over fifty studies showing tendencies for violence to be more common in societies where income differences are larger. Research has been conducted comparing developed countries with undeveloped countries, as well as studying areas within countries. Daly et al. 2001<ref></ref> found that among ] ] and ] ] there is a tenfold difference in homicide rates related to inequality. They estimated that about half of all variation in homicide rates can be accounted for by differences in the amount of inequality in each province or state. Fajnzylber et al. (2002) found a similar relationship worldwide. Among comments in academic literature on the relationship between homicides and inequality are:
Economist ] argues that rather than explaining concentrations of wealth and income, market forces should serve as a brake on such concentration, which may better be explained by the non-market force known as "]". While the market will bid up compensation for rare and desired skills to reward wealth creation, greater productivity, etc., it will also prevent successful entrepreneurs from earning excess profits by fostering competition to cut prices, profits and large compensation.<ref name="stiglitz.p35">Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future (pp. 30–31, 35–36). Norton. Kindle Edition.</ref> A better explainer of growing inequality, according to Stiglitz, is the use of political power generated by wealth by certain groups to shape government policies financially beneficial to them. This process, known to economists as rent-seeking, brings income not from creation of wealth but from "grabbing a larger share of the wealth that would otherwise have been produced without their effort".<ref name="stiglitz.p32">Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2012). ''The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future'' (p. 32). Norton. Kindle Edition.</ref>
* The most consistent finding in cross-national research on homicides has been that of a positive association between income inequality and homicides.<ref>Jerome L Neapolitana, , ''Journal of Criminal Justice'', Volume 27, Issue 3, May–June 1999, pp. 260.</ref>
* Economic inequality is positively and significantly related to rates of homicide despite an extensive list of conceptually relevant controls. The fact that this relationship is found with the most recent data and using a different measure of economic inequality from previous research, suggests that the finding is very robust.<ref> ''Deviant Behavior'', Volume 20, Issue 1, 1999, pp. 50.</ref>


===Finance industry===
====Social, cultural, and civic participation====
] argues that countries with larger financial sectors have greater inequality, and the link is not an accident.<ref>James K. Galbraith, '''' (New York: Oxford University Press, 2012).</ref><ref>Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2012). ''The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future'', p. 334. Norton. Kindle Edition.</ref>{{why|date=July 2019}}
Higher income inequality led to less of all forms of social, cultural, and civic participation among the less wealthy.<ref>Bram Lancee and Hermanvande Werfhorst (2011) GINI Discussion Paper No. 6 (Amsterdam Centre for Inequality Studies)</ref> When inequality is higher the poor do not shift to less expensive forms of participation.<ref>The Equality Trust (2012) Research Update No. 4</ref>


===Utility, economic welfare, and distributive efficiency=== ===Global warming and climate change===
{{multiple image |total_width=450
Following the ] principle of seeking the greatest good for the greatest number – economic inequality is problematic. A house that provides less utility to a millionaire as a summer home than it would to a homeless family of five, is an example of reduced "]" within society, that ] ] of wealth and thus the sum total of personal ]. An additional dollar spent by a poor person will go to things providing a great deal of utility to that person, such as basic necessities like food, water, and healthcare; while, an additional dollar spent by a much richer person will very likely go to luxury items providing relatively less utility to that person. Thus, the ] of wealth per person ("the additional dollar") decreases as a person becomes richer. From this standpoint, for any given amount of wealth in society, a society with more equality will have higher aggregate utility. Some studies<ref name=happiniess> 2003</ref><ref>Blanchard and Oswald 2000, 2003</ref> have found evidence for this theory, noting that in societies where inequality is lower, population-wide satisfaction and happiness tend to be higher.
| image1=2021 Carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions per person versus GDP per person - scatter plot.svg |caption1=Scaling the effect of wealth to the national level: richer ] countries emit more {{CO2}} per person than poorer ] countries.<ref name=WashPost_20230301>{{cite news |last1=Stevens |first1=Harry |title=The United States has caused the most global warming. When will China pass it? |url=https://www.washingtonpost.com/climate-environment/interactive/2023/global-warming-carbon-emissions-china-us/ |newspaper=The Washington Post |date=1 March 2023 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230301130719/https://www.washingtonpost.com/climate-environment/interactive/2023/global-warming-carbon-emissions-china-us/ |archive-date=1 March 2023 |url-status=live }}</ref> Emissions are roughly proportional to ] per person, though the rate of increase diminishes with average GDP/pp of about $10,000.
| image2=2021 CO2 emissions by income decile - International Energy Agency IEA.svg |caption2=Though total {{CO2}} emissions (size of pie charts) differ substantially among high-emitting regions, the pattern of higher income classes emitting more than lower income classes is consistent across regions.<ref name=IEA_20230222/> The world's top 1% of emitters emit over 1000 times more than the bottom 1%.<ref name=IEA_20230222>{{cite web |last1=Cozzi |first1=Laura |last2=Chen |first2=Olivia |last3=Kim |first3=Hyeji |title=The world's top 1% of emitters produce over 1000 times more CO2 than the bottom 1% |url=https://www.iea.org/commentaries/the-world-s-top-1-of-emitters-produce-over-1000-times-more-co2-than-the-bottom-1 |website=iea.org |publisher=International Energy Agency (IEA) |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230303032020/https://www.iea.org/commentaries/the-world-s-top-1-of-emitters-produce-over-1000-times-more-co2-than-the-bottom-1 |archive-date=3 March 2023 |date=22 February 2023 |url-status=live }} "Methodological note: ... The analysis accounts for energy-related CO2, and not other greenhouse gases, nor those related to land use and agriculture."</ref>
}}
A 2019 study published in '']'' found that ] plays a role in increasing economic inequality between countries, boosting economic growth in developed countries while hampering such growth in developing nations of the ]. The study says that 25% of gap between the developed world and the developing world can be attributed to global warming.<ref>{{cite news |last= Uchoa|first=Pablo|date=May 6, 2019 |title=How global warming has made the rich richer |url=http://www.bbc.com/capital/story/20190502-how-global-warming-has-made-the-rich-richer|work=BBC |access-date=June 5, 2019 }}</ref>


A 2020 report by ] and the ] says that the wealthiest 10% of the global population were responsible for more than half of global carbon dioxide emissions from 1990 to 2015, which increased by 60%.<ref>{{cite news |last=Harvey |first=Fiona |author-link=Fiona Harvey |date=September 20, 2020 |title=World's richest 1% cause double CO2 emissions of poorest 50%, says Oxfam |url=https://www.theguardian.com/environment/2020/sep/21/worlds-richest-1-cause-double-co2-emissions-of-poorest-50-says-oxfam |access-date=September 22, 2020 |work=]}}</ref> According to a 2020 report by the ], ] by the rich is a significant driver of the ], and the wealthiest 1% of the world's population are responsible for more than double the greenhouse gas emissions of the poorest 50% combined. ], in the foreword to the report, said "this elite will need to reduce their footprint by a factor of 30 to stay in line with the Paris Agreement targets."<ref>{{cite news |last= McGrath |first=Matt |date=December 10, 2020 |title=Climate change: Global 'elite' will need to slash high-carbon lifestyles|url=https://www.bbc.com/news/science-environment-55229725 |work=BBC |access-date=December 11, 2020}}</ref> A 2022 report by Oxfam found that the business investments of the wealthiest 125 billionaires emit 393 million metric tonnes of greenhouse gas emissions annually.<ref>{{cite news |last=Ward-Glenton|first=Hannah|date=November 8, 2022 |title=Billionaires emit a million times more greenhouse gases than the average person: Oxfam|url=https://www.cnbc.com/2022/11/08/billionaires-emit-a-million-times-more-greenhouse-gases-than-the-average-person-oxfam.html|work=CNBC |location= |access-date=November 8, 2022}}</ref>
Economist ] argues that
<blockquote>
... it is evident that any transference of income from a relatively rich man to a relatively poor man of similar temperament, since it enables more intense wants, to be satisfied at the expense of less intense wants, must increase the aggregate sum of satisfaction. The old "law of diminishing utility" thus leads securely to the proposition: Any cause which increases the absolute share of real income in the hands of the poor, provided that it does not lead to a contraction in the size of the national dividend from any point of view, will, in general, increase economic welfare.<ref name=pigou>''''| ]</ref>
</blockquote>


In July 2023, a letter sent to the United Nations secretary general ] and World Bank president ] by a group of over 200 economists from 67 countries, including ], ] and Thomas Piketty, warned that if the sharp increase in economic inequality is not reversed, it will "entrench poverty and increase the risk of climate breakdown."<ref>{{cite news |last= Elliott|first=Larry|date= |title=Top economists call for action on runaway global inequality|url=https://www.theguardian.com/inequality/2023/jul/17/top-economists-call-for-action-global-inequality-rich-poor-poverty-climate-breakdown-un-world-bank|work=The Guardian |location= |access-date=July 19, 2023}}</ref>
Philosopher ] argues that maximizing the sum of individual utilities will harm incentives to produce.
<blockquote>A society that takes Joe Rich’s second unit is taking that unit away from someone who . . . has nothing better to do than plant it and giving it to someone who . . . does have something better to do with it. That sounds good, but in the process, the society takes seed corn out of production and diverts it to food, thereby cannibalizing itself.<ref> By David Schmidtz (2006)</ref></blockquote>


According to ]'s World Investment Report, poorer countries would need $4 trillion per year to accomplish the ] by 2030, up from $1.5 trillion in 2015. $1.7 trillion in green energy investment is required each year, while the majority of ] continues to flow to established nations. <ref>{{Cite web |title=WORLD INVESTMENT REPORT 2023 |url=https://unctad.org/publication/world-investment-report-2023 |website=UN Trade & development}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |title=UNSDG {{!}} Developing countries face staggering $4 trillion investment gap in SDGs |url=https://unsdg.un.org/latest/stories/developing-countries-face-staggering-4-trillion-investment-gap-sdgs,%20https://unsdg.un.org/latest/stories/developing-countries-face-staggering-4-trillion-investment-gap-sdgs |access-date=2024-06-27 |website=unsdg.un.org |language=en}}</ref>
However, in addition to the diminishing marginal utility of unequal distribution, Pigou and others point out that a "]" effect among the well off may lead to greater inequality and use of resources for ''no'' greater return in utility.
<blockquote>
a larger proportion of the satisfaction yielded by the incomes of rich people comes from their relative, rather than from their absolute, amount. This part of it will not be destroyed if the incomes of all rich people are diminished together. The loss of economic welfare suffered by the rich when command over resources is transferred from them to the poor will, therefore, be substantially smaller relatively to the gain of economic welfare to the poor than a consideration of the law of diminishing utility taken by itself suggests.<ref name=pigou/>
</blockquote>


===Politics===
When the goal is to own the biggest yacht – rather than a boat with certain features – there is no greater benefit from owning 100 metre long boat than a 20 m one as long as it is bigger than your rival.
] argues in '']'' (2012) that the economic inequality is inevitable and permanent, because it is caused by the great amount of political power the richest have.<ref name="Stiglitz2012">{{cite book |last=Stiglitz |first=Joseph E. |date=2012 |title=The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future |page=34 |publisher=Norton |isbn=9780393088694 |edition=Kindle |url=https://archive.org/details/priceofinequalit00stig}}</ref> He wrote, "While there may be underlying economic forces at play, politics have shaped the market, and shaped it in ways that advantage the top at the expense of the rest."
Economist ] compare the situation to that of male ]s who use their antlers to spar with other males for mating rights.
<blockquote>The pressure to have bigger ones than your rivals leads to an arms race that consumes resources that could have been used more efficiently for other things, such as fighting off disease. As a result, every male ends up with a cumbersome and expensive pair of antlers, ... and "life is more miserable for bull elk as a group."<ref name=antlers>{{cite web|last=Whitfield|first=John|title=Libertarians With Antlers|url=http://www.slate.com/articles/health_and_science/science/2011/09/libertarians_with_antlers.html|work=slate.com|date=28 September 2011|accessdate=6 November 2012}}</ref> </blockquote>


===Cognitive biases===
===Aggregate demand, consumption and debt===
Research has shown that biased decision-making does not alone explain a significant proportion of inequality, therefore inequality cannot be explained by cognitive biases of a specific sub-population, such as temporal discounting (i.e., not preferring immediate funds over larger future gains), overestimation (i.e. thinking you are better than you are at making decisions), over-placement (i.e. thinking you are better than the average person at making decisions), and extremeness aversion (i.e. taking the 'middle option' simply because it seems safer than the highest or lowest).<ref name="urlCognitive_Biases_Not_Explaining_Inequality | Nature.com">{{Cite journal|title=The persistence of cognitive biases in financial decisions across economic groups |first1=Kai |last1=Ruggeri |last2=Ashcroft-Jones |first2=S. |last3=Abate Romero Landini |first3=G. |journal=Scientific Reports |date=June 26, 2023 |volume=13 |issue=1 |page=10329 |doi=10.1038/s41598-023-36339-2 |pmid=37365245 |pmc=10293260 |bibcode=2023NatSR..1310329R }}</ref>
Income inequality lowers ], leading to increasingly large segments of formerly middle class consumers unable to afford as many luxury and essential goods and services.<ref name=Pigou>{{cite book|last1=Pigou|first1=Arthur C.|title=The Economics of Welfare|date=1932|publisher=Macmillan and Co.|location=London|edition=4th|url=http://www.econlib.org/library/NPDBooks/Pigou/pgEW8.html|accessdate=August 11, 2014|chapter=Part I, Chapter VIII}}</ref> This pushes production and overall employment down.<ref name=Castells-Quintana/>


==Mitigating factors==
Conservative researchers have argued that income inequality is not significant because consumption, rather than income should be the measure of inequality, and inequality of consumption is less extreme than inequality of income in the US. ] of the ] ] states that "the weight of the evidence shows that the run-up in consumption inequality has been considerably less dramatic than the rise in income inequality," and consumption is more important than income.<ref>, Will Wilkinson, ] 2009</ref> According to Johnson, Smeeding, and Tory, consumption inequality was actually lower in 2001 than it was in 1986.<ref>Johnson, Smeeding, Tory, "Economic Inequality" in Monthly Labor review of April 2005, table 3.</ref><ref>see also , by Kevin Hassett and Aparna Mathur, ''Wall Street Journal'', October 24, 2012</ref> The debate is summarized in "The Hidden Prosperity of the Poor" by journalist ].<ref name=hidden>{{cite news|last=Edsall|first=Thomas B.|title=The Hidden Prosperity of the Poor|url=http://opinionator.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/01/30/the-hidden-prosperity-of-the-poor/?src=me&ref=general|accessdate=January 2, 2013|newspaper=New York Times|date=January 30, 2013}}</ref> Other studies have not found consumption inequality less dramatic than household income inequality,<ref name=denial> by Timothy Noah ''The New Republic'' (October 25, 2012)</ref><ref>{{cite paper |title=The Evolution of Income, Consumption, and Leisure Inequality in The US, 1980–2010 |first=Orazio |last=Attanasio |first2=Erik |last2=Hurst |first3=Luigi |last3=Pistaferri |work=NBER Working Papers #17982 |year=2012 |ssrn=2035781 }}</ref> and the CBO's study found consumption data not "adequately" capturing "consumption by high-income households" as it does their income, though it did agree that household consumption numbers show more equal distribution than household income.<ref name=cbo.p5>. October 2011. p. 5</ref>
]
Countries with a ] ] generally have lower levels of inequality.<ref>{{cite journal |doi=10.1353/wp.2003.0009 |title=Distribution and Redistribution in Postindustrial Democracies |journal=World Politics |volume=55 |issue=2 |pages=193–228 |year=2011 |last1=Bradley |first1=David |last2=Huber |first2=Evelyne |last3=Moller |first3=Stephanie |last4=Nielsen |first4=François |last5=Stephens |first5=John D. |hdl=10419/160937 |s2cid=873271 |url=http://www.lisdatacenter.org/wps/liswps/265.pdf }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |doi=10.1177/000312240607100604 |jstor=25472438 |title=Politics and Inequality in Latin America and the Caribbean |journal=American Sociological Review |volume=71 |issue=6 |pages=943–963 |year=2006 |last1=Huber |first1=Evelyne |last2=Nielsen |first2=François |last3=Pribble |first3=Jenny |last4=Stephens |first4=John D. |s2cid=144270746 }}</ref> Many factors constrain economic inequality{{snd}}they may be divided into two classes: market driven, and government sponsored. The relative merits and effectiveness of each approach is a subject of debate:


] outside of government intervention that can reduce economic inequality include:
Others dispute the importance of consumption over income, pointing out that if middle and lower income are consuming more than they earn it is because they are saving less or going deeper into debt.<ref name=ignore> by Timothy Noah, ''Slate'' (September 16, 2010)</ref> Income inequality has been the driving factor in the growing household debt,<ref name=denial/><ref> By Daniel Alpert, Westwood Capital; Robert Hockett, Professor of Law, Cornell University; and Nouriel Roubini, Professor of Economics, New York University, New America Foundation, October 10, 2011</ref> as high earners bid up the price of real estate and middle income earners go deeper into debt trying to maintain what once was a middle class lifestyle.<ref name=plumer>{{cite web|last=Plumer|first=Brad|title=‘Trickle-down consumption’: How rising inequality can leave everyone worse off|url=http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2013/03/27/trickle-down-consumption-how-rising-inequality-can-leave-everyone-worse-off/|work=27 March 2013|publisher=Washington Post|accessdate=March 27, 2013}}</ref>
* ]: with rising wealth & income, a person may spend more. In an extreme example, if one person owned everything, they would immediately need to hire people to maintain their properties, thus reducing the ].<ref>{{cite journal |last1=García-Peñalosa |first1=Cecilia |author-link1=Cecilia Garcia-Penalosa |last2=Turnovsky |first2=Stephen J. |year=2007 |title=Growth, Income Inequality, and Fiscal Policy: What Are the Relevant Trade-offs? |journal=Journal of Money, Credit and Banking |volume=39 |issue=2–3 |pages=369–394 |citeseerx=10.1.1.186.2754 |doi=10.1111/j.0022-2879.2007.00029.x}}</ref> On the other hand, high-income persons have higher propensity to save.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Carroll |first1=Christopher |last2=Slacalek |first2=Jiri |last3=Kiichi |first3=Tokuoka |last4=White |first4=Matthew |date=2017 |title=The distribution of wealth and the marginal propensity to consume |journal=Quantitative Economics |volume=8 |issue=3 |pages=977–1020 |doi=10.3982/QE694 |doi-access=free}}</ref> Robin Maialeh then shows that increasing economic wealth decreases propensity to spend and increases propensity to invest which consequently leads to even greater growth rate of already rich agents.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Maialeh |first1=Robin |date=2019 |title=Why Market Imperatives Invigorate Economic Inequality? Cobb-Douglas Utility Remodelled |url=http://www.panoeconomicus.org/index.php/jorunal/article/view/695/524 |journal=Panoeconomicus |volume=66 |issue=2 |pages=145–163 |doi=10.2298/PAN160220031M |doi-access=free}}</ref>

Typical ] initiatives intended to reduce economic inequality include:
Central Banking economist ] argues that "systematic economic inequalities, within the United States and around the world, have created deep financial 'fault lines' that have made crises more likely to happen than in the past" – the ] being the most recent example.<ref name=Lo>{{cite web|last=Lo|first=Andrew W.|title=Reading About the Financial Crisis: A 21-Book Review|url=http://www.argentumlux.org/documents/JEL_6.pdf|work=2012|publisher=Journal of Economic Literature .|accessdate=November 27, 2013}}</ref> To compensate for stagnating and declining purchasing power, political pressure has developed to extend easier credit to the lower and middle income earners – particularly to buy homes – and easier credit in general to keep unemployment rates low. This has given the American economy a tendency to go "from bubble to bubble" fueled by unsustainable monetary stimulation.<ref name=KOEHN>{{cite news|last=Koehn|first=Nancy F.|title=A Call to Fix the Fundamentals (Review of ''Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy'' by Raghuram G. Rajan)|url=http://www.nytimes.com/2010/08/01/business/01shelf.html|accessdate=November 20, 2013|newspaper=New York Times|date=July 31, 2010}}</ref>
* ]: increasing the supply of skilled labor and reducing income inequality due to education differentials.<ref>{{cite journal |doi=10.1353/jda.0.0052 |jstor=40376250 |title=How Can Education Policy Improve Income Distribution?: An Empirical Analysis of Education Stages and Measures on Income Inequality |journal=The Journal of Developing Areas |volume=43 |issue=2 |pages=51–77 |year=2010 |last1=Keller |first1=Katarina R.I. |doi-access=free }}</ref>

* ]ation: the rich are taxed proportionally more than the poor, reducing the amount of income inequality in society if the change in taxation does not cause changes in income.<ref>
===Monopolization of labor, consolidation, and competition===
{{cite journal |ssrn=2566842 |title=The Impact of Economic Growth, Tax Policy and Economic Freedom on Income Inequality |first1=J. R. |last1=Clark |first2=Robert A. |last2=Lawson |journal=The Journal of Private Enterprise |year=2008 }}
Greater income inequality can lead to ] of the ], resulting in fewer employers requiring fewer workers.<ref name=Pigou/><ref name=Lynn>{{cite journal|last1=Lynn|first1=Barry C.|last2=Longman|first2=Phillip|title=Who Broke America’s Jobs Machine?|journal=Washington Monthly|date=March–April 2010|url=http://www.washingtonmonthly.com/features/2010/1003.lynn-longman.html|accessdate=August 11, 2014}}</ref> Remaining employers can ] and take advantage of the relative lack of competition, leading to less consumer choice, ]s, and relatively higher real prices.<ref name=Castells-Quintana/><ref name=Lynn/>

===Economic incentives===
Some modern ], such as the ] school, have suggested that a functioning economy entails a ] of ]. These theories argue that unemployment benefits must be below the ] level to provide an incentive to work, thereby mandating inequality. Such theories state additionally that the unemployment rate cannot reduce to zero.{{citation needed|date=November 2012}}

Many{{quantify|date=April 2014}} economists believe that one of the main reasons that inequality might induce economic incentive is because material well-being and ] relate to ]. In this view, high stratification of income (high inequality) creates high amounts of ], leading to greater competition for ].

One of the first writers to note this relationship, ], recognized "regard" as one of the major driving forces behind economic activity. From '']'' in 1759:

<blockquote>
hat is the end of avarice and ambition, of the pursuit of wealth, of power, and pre-eminence? Is it to supply the necessities of nature? The wages of the meanest labourer can supply them... hy should those who have been educated in the higher ranks of life, regard it as worse than death, to be reduced to live, even without labour, upon the same simple fare with him, to dwell under the same lowly roof, and to be clothed in the same humble attire? From whence, then, arises that emulation which runs through all the different ranks of men, and what are the advantages which we propose by that great purpose of human life which we call bettering our condition? To be observed, to be attended to, to be taken notice of with sympathy, complacency, and approbation, are all the advantages which we can propose to derive from it. It is the vanity, not the ease, or the pleasure, which interests us.<ref>]
</ref> </ref>
Research shows that since 1300, the only periods with significant declines in wealth inequality in Europe were the ] and the two World Wars.<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://voxeu.org/article/europe-s-rich-1300|title=The top rich in Europe in the long run of history (1300 to present day)|last=Alfani|first=Guido|date=January 15, 2017|website=VoxEU.org|access-date=January 16, 2017}}</ref> Historian ] posits that, since the Stone Age, only extreme violence, catastrophes and upheaval in the form of ], ]s, the ], pestilence and state collapse have significantly reduced inequality.<ref>{{cite news |last=Scheidel|first=Walter |date=February 23, 2017 |title=Inequality Has Historically Been Leveled Only By Terrible Violence And Upheaval|url=https://www.huffingtonpost.com/entry/inequality-violence_us_58ac8381e4b0c5148b041897|work=The Huffington Post |access-date= March 30, 2017}}</ref><ref name=":13">{{cite news |last=Taylor |first= Matt|date=February 22, 2017 |title=One Recipe for a More Equal World: Mass Death |url=https://www.vice.com/en_us/article/ypxw55/one-recipe-for-a-more-equal-world-mass-death|work=] |access-date=April 7, 2017 }}</ref> He has stated that "only all-out thermonuclear war might fundamentally reset the existing distribution of resources" and that "peaceful policy reform may well prove unequal to the growing challenges ahead."<ref>{{cite news |last=Porter|first=Eduardo |date=December 6, 2016 |title=A Dilemma for Humanity: Stark Inequality or Total War|work=The New York Times |url=https://www.nytimes.com/2016/12/06/business/economy/a-dilemma-for-humanity-stark-inequality-or-total-war.html |access-date=March 30, 2017}}</ref><ref>{{cite book| last=Scheidel| first=Walter| author-link=Walter Scheidel| title=The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century| publisher=]| location=Princeton| year=2017| isbn=978-0691165028 |url=http://press.princeton.edu/titles/10921.html|pages=438, 444}}</ref> However, Scheidel also stated that "There is certainly room for incremental change, that's what the example of Latin America shows in the past 15 years or so."<ref name=":13" />
</blockquote>


===Policy responses intended to mitigate===
Modern sociologists and economists such as ] and ] have studied the extent to which economic activity is fueled by the ability of consumption to represent social status. Schor, in ''The Overspent American'', argues that the increasing inequality during the 1980s and 1990s strongly accounts for increasing aspirations of income, increased consumption, decreased savings, and increased debt.
A 2011 OECD study makes a number of suggestions to its member countries, including:<ref name="oecd-dws"/>
* Well-targeted income-support policies.
* Facilitation and encouragement of access to employment.
* Better job-related training and education for the low-skilled (]) would help to boost their productivity potential and future earnings.
* Better access to formal education.


]ation reduces absolute income inequality when the higher rates on higher-income individuals are paid and not ], and ] and ]s result in progressive ].<ref>{{cite journal | last1 = Moyes | first1 = P | year = 1988| title = A note on minimally progressive taxation and absolute income inequality | journal = Social Choice and Welfare | volume = 5 | issue = 2–3| pages = 227–234 | doi = 10.1007/BF00735763 | s2cid = 189918945 }}</ref><ref>Pickett and Wilkinson, '']'', 2011</ref><ref>{{cite web|last=Duncan|first=Denvil, Klara Sabirianova Peter|title=Unequal Inequalities: Do Progressive Taxes Reduce Income Inequality?|url=http://ftp.iza.org/dp6910.pdf|publisher=Institute for the Study of Labor|date=October 2012}}</ref> ] legislation has also been proposed as a means of reducing income inequality. The ] asserts that public spending is vital in reducing the ever-expanding ].<ref name="OECD13">. ''].'' Retrieved May 14, 2013</ref>
In the book ''Luxury Fever'', Robert H. Frank argues that satisfaction with levels of income is much more strongly affected by how someone's income compares with others than its absolute level. Frank gives the example of instructions to a yacht architect by a customer – shipping magnate ] – to make Niarchos' new yacht 50 feet longer than that of rival magnate ]. Niarchos did not specify or reportedly even know the exact length of Onassis's yacht.<ref>
(excerpt)| milkeninstitute.org
</ref><ref>
MPR June 26, 2009, 12:00 p.m.</ref>


Deferred investment programs that increase stock ownership amongst lower income levels can supplement income to compensate wage stagnation.<ref name=":8" />
===Economic growth===
According to ] economists, inequality in wealth and income is negatively correlated with subsequent economic growth.<ref name="BergOstryEE" /> A strong demand for redistribution will occur in societies where much of the population does not have access to productive resources. Rational voters have to internalize this dynamic problem of social choice.<ref name=AlesinaRodrick1994>{{cite journal|last=Alesina|first=Alberto|first2=Dani | last2 = Rodrick|title=Distributive Politics and Economic Growth|journal=Quarterly Journal of Economics|date=May 1994|volume=109|issue=2|pages=465–90|doi=10.2307/2118470|url=http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/109/2/465.full.pdf|accessdate=17 October 2013}}</ref> 2013 Economics Nobel prize winner ], who shares the IMF's view, said that rising inequality in the United States and elsewhere is the most important problem being faced in the U.S. and elsewhere in the world.<ref>{{cite news|last=Christoffersen|first=John|title=Rising inequality 'most important problem,' says Nobel-winning economist|url=http://www.stltoday.com/business/local/rising-inequality-most-important-problem-says-nobel-winning-economist/article_a5065957-05c3-5ac0-ba5b-dab91c22973a.html|accessdate=19 October 2013|newspaper=St. Louis Post-Dispatch|date=October 14, 2013}}</ref> High levels of inequality prevent not just economic prosperity, but also the quality of a country's institutions and high levels of education.<ref name="biu.ac.il"/>


The economists ] and ] recommend much higher top marginal tax rates on the wealthy, up to 50 percent, 70 percent or even 90 percent.<ref>Annie Lowrey (April 16, 2012). . ''The New York Times.'' Retrieved August 17, 2013.</ref> ], ], the United Front Against Austerity, among others, call for a ] (also known as the ]) to bolster the social safety net and the public sector.<ref>] (April 18, 2013). . ''].'' Retrieved June 5, 2013.</ref><ref>Erika Eichelberger (October 30, 2013). . ''].'' Retrieved November 15, 2013.</ref>
According to economists David Castells-Quintana and Vicente Royuela, increasing inequality harms economic growth.<ref name=Castells-Quintana/> High and persistent ], in which inequality increases, has a negative effect on subsequent long-run economic growth according to research by David Castells-Quintana.<ref name=Castells-Quintana/> Unemployment can harm growth not only because it is a waste of resources, but also because it generates redistributive pressures and subsequent distortions, drives people to poverty, constrains liquidity limiting labor mobility, and erodes self-esteem promoting social dislocation, unrest and conflict.<ref name=Castells-Quintana/> Policies aiming at controlling unemployment and in particular at reducing its inequality-associated effects support economic growth.<ref name=Castells-Quintana>{{cite journal|last=Castells-Quintana|first=David|first2=Vicente | last2 = Royuela|title=Unemployment and long-run economic growth: The role of income inequality and urbanisation|journal=Investigaciones Regionales|year=2012|volume=12|issue=24|pages=153–173|url=http://diposit.ub.edu/dspace/bitstream/2445/33140/1/617293.pdf|accessdate=17 October 2013}}</ref>


'']'' wrote in December 2013: "A minimum wage, providing it is not set too high, could thus boost pay with no ill effects on jobs....America's federal minimum wage, at 38% of median income, is one of the rich world's lowest. Some studies find no harm to employment from federal or state minimum wages, others see a small one, but none finds any serious damage."<ref>{{Cite news|url=https://www.economist.com/news/leaders/21591593-moderate-minimum-wages-do-more-good-harm-they-should-be-set-technocrats-not|title=The logical floor|newspaper=]|date=December 14, 2013}}</ref>
] found that of the factors affecting the duration of growth spells in developed and developing countries, income equality is more beneficial than trade openness, sound political institutions, or foreign investment.<ref name=BergOstryEE /><ref name=BergOstrySD />]]


General limitations on and taxation of ] are popular across the political spectrum.<ref>{{cite news|last=Konczal|first=Mike|title=How an anti-rentier agenda might bring liberals, conservatives together|url=https://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2013/03/30/ow-an-anti-rentier-agenda-might-bring-liberals-conservatives-together/|access-date=April 6, 2013|newspaper=]|date=March 30, 2013}}</ref>
Some theories popular from the 1970s to 2011 stated that inequality had a positive effect on economic development.<ref name=BergOstryEE>{{Cite journal |last= Berg |first= Andrew G. |last2= Ostry |first2= Jonathan D. |year= 2011 |title= Equality and Efficiency |journal= Finance and Development |volume= 48 |issue= 3 |publisher= International Monetary Fund |url= http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2011/09/berg.htm |accessdate= July 13, 2014}}</ref><ref name=BergOstrySD /> Savings by the wealthy, which increases with inequality, was thought to offset reduced consumer demand.<ref>Kaldor, Nicoals, 1955, Alternative Theories of Distribution," Review of Economic Studies, 23(2), 83–100.</ref> A study by the ] found that the analysis based on comparing yearly equality figures to yearly growth rates was flawed and misleading because it takes several years for the effects of equality changes to manifest in economic growth changes.<ref name=BanerjeeDuflo>{{Cite journal |last= Banerjee |first= Abhijit V. |first2= Esther |last2= Duflo |year= 2003 |title= Inequality And Growth: What Can The Data Say? |journal= Journal of Economic Growth |volume= 8 |issue= 3 |pages= 267–99 |doi= 10.1023/A:1026205114860 |url= http://economics.mit.edu/files/753 |accessdate= September 25, 2012}}</ref> IMF economists Andrew G. Berg and Jonathan D. Ostry found a strong association between lower levels of inequality in developing countries and sustained periods of economic growth. Developing countries with high inequality have "succeeded in initiating growth at high rates for a few years" but "longer growth spells are robustly associated with more equality in the income distribution."<ref name=BergOstrySD>Andrew Berg and Jonathan Ostry. (2011) ''IMF Staff Discussion Note'' No. SDN/11/08 (International Monetary Fund)</ref>


Public policy responses addressing causes and effects of income inequality in the US include: ] ] adjustments, strengthening ] provisions such as ], ], the ], ], ], and ], ], increasing and reforming ] subsidies, increasing ] spending, and placing limits on and taxing ].<ref>{{cite news|last=Grusky|first=David B.|title=What to Do about Inequality|url=https://www.bostonreview.net/BR37.2/ndf_david_b_grusky_inequality.php|access-date=April 6, 2013|newspaper=]|date=March–April 2013|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130420175636/http://www.bostonreview.net/BR37.2/ndf_david_b_grusky_inequality.php|archive-date=April 20, 2013|url-status=dead}}</ref>
Economist ] presented evidence in 2009 review that both global inequality and inequality within countries prevent growth by limiting ].<ref name="ilo.org"/> A 1999 review in the ''Journal of Economic Literature'' states high inequality lowers growth, perhaps because it increases social and political instability.<ref name="The New Growth Evidence"/> A 1992 ] report published in the ''Journal of Development Economics'' said that inequality "is negatively, and robustly, correlated with growth. This result is not highly dependent upon assumptions about either the form of the growth regression or the measure of inequality."<ref name="www-wds.worldbank.org"/>


A 2017 study in the '']'' by ], ] and Thierry Verdier argues that American "cutthroat" capitalism and inequality gives rise to technology and innovation that more "cuddly" forms of capitalism cannot.<ref name=":1">{{cite journal |doi=10.1086/693038 |title=Asymmetric Growth and Institutions in an Interdependent World |journal=Journal of Political Economy |volume=125 |issue=5 |pages=1245–1305 |year=2017 |last1=Acemoglu |first1=Daron |last2=Robinson |first2=James A. |last3=Verdier |first3=Thierry |hdl=1721.1/118645 |s2cid=154662416 |hdl-access=free }}</ref> As a result, "the diversity of institutions we observe among relatively advanced countries, ranging from greater inequality and risk-taking in the United States to the more egalitarian societies supported by a strong safety net in Scandinavia, rather than reflecting differences in fundamentals between the citizens of these societies, may emerge as a mutually self-reinforcing world equilibrium. If so, in this equilibrium, 'we cannot all be like the Scandinavians,' because ] depends in part on the knowledge spillovers created by the more cutthroat American capitalism."<ref name=":1" /> A 2012 working paper by the same authors, making similar arguments, was challenged by ], who posited that, among other things, the Nordic countries are consistently ranked as some of the world's most innovative countries by the ]'s ], with Sweden ranking as the most innovative nation, followed by Finland, for 2012–2013; the U.S. ranked sixth.<ref>{{cite book | title = Social Democratic America | first1 = Kenworthy | last1 = Lane | author-link = Lane Kenworthy | date = 2015 | isbn = 978-0190230951 | publisher = ] | url=https://books.google.com/books?id=c4oUDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA88 | pages = 88–93 | location = US}}</ref>
In 1993, ] and Zeira showed that inequality in the presence of credit market imperfections has a long lasting detrimental effect on human capital formation and economic development.<ref>Galor, Oded and Joseph Zeira, 1993, "Income Distribution and Macroeconomics," Review of Economic Studies, 60(1), 35–52.</ref> A study by Perotti (1996) examines the channels through which inequality may affect economic growth. He shows that in accordance with the credit market imperfection approach, inequality is associated with lower level of human capital formation (education, experience, apprenticeship) and higher level of fertility, while lower level of human capital is associated with lower growth and lower levels of economic growth. In contrast, his examination of the political economy channel refutes the political economy mechanism. He demonstrates that inequality is associated with lower levels of taxation, while lower levels of taxation, contrary to the theories, are associated with lower level of economic growth<ref>Perotti, R. (1996) ''Journal of Economic Growth'' '''1'''(2): 149-187.</ref>


There are however global initiative like the United Nations ] which aims to garner international efforts in reducing economic inequality considerably by 2030.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Goal 10 targets |website=UNDP|url=https://www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/sustainable-development-goals/goal-10-reduced-inequalities/targets.html|access-date=September 23, 2020|url-status=dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20201127140337/https://www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/sustainable-development-goals/goal-10-reduced-inequalities/targets.html|archive-date=November 27, 2020}}</ref>
The political economy approach, developed by Alesina and Rodrik (1994) and Persson and Tabellini (1994), argues that inequality is harmful for economic development because inequality generates a pressure to adopt redistributive policies that have an adverse effect on investment and economic growth.<ref name=AlesinaRodrick1994/><ref>Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini, 1994, "Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?" American Economic Review 84(3), 600–621.</ref>


==Effects==
Research by economist Muhammad Dandume Yusuf on the relationship between income inequality and growth in Nigeria (2013) suggests that "economic growth rises with inequality of income".<ref>https://ideas.repec.org/p/pra/mprapa/52348.html</ref> According to economist Ruth-Aida Nahum, whose paper studied Swedish counties between 1960 and 2000, she found a positive impact of inequality on growth with lead times of five years or less, but no correlation after ten years.<ref>https://ideas.repec.org/p/hhs/ifswps/2005_003.html</ref> Studies of larger data sets have found no correlations for any fixed lead time,<ref name=BanerjeeDuflo/> and a negative impact on the duration of growth.<ref name=BergOstryEE/>
{{main|Effects of economic inequality}}
A lot of research has been done about the effects of economic inequality on different aspects in society:
* '''Health''': For long time the higher material living standards lead to longer life, as those people were able to get enough food, water and access to warmth. British researchers ] and ] have found higher rates of health and social problems (], ], ]s, ]s, ], child conflict, drug use) in countries and states with higher inequality.<ref name="The Spirit Level">{{cite web|url=http://www.equalitytrust.org.uk/resources/slides|title=The Spirit Level|work=equalitytrust.org.uk}}</ref><ref name="Income inequality and health: a cau">{{cite journal|last1=Pickett|first1=KE|last2=Wilkinson|first2=RG|title=Income inequality and health: a causal review.|journal=Social Science & Medicine|date=March 2015|volume=128|pages=316–326|doi=10.1016/j.socscimed.2014.12.031|pmid=25577953}}</ref> Their research included 24 developed countries, including most U.S. states, and found that in the more developed countries, such as Finland and Japan, the heath issues are much lower than in states with rather higher inequality rates, such as Utah and New Hampshire. Some studies link a surge in "]", suicide, drug overdoses and alcohol related deaths, to widening income inequality.<ref>{{cite news|last=Woodward|first=Aylin|date=November 30, 2019|title=Life expectancy in the US keeps going down, and a new study says America's worsening inequality could be to blame|url=https://www.businessinsider.my/us-life-expectancy-declined-for-third-year-in-a-row-2019-11/|work=]|access-date=December 18, 2019|archive-date=December 18, 2019|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191218004240/https://www.businessinsider.my/us-life-expectancy-declined-for-third-year-in-a-row-2019-11/|url-status=dead}}</ref><ref>{{cite news |last1= Coughlan|first1=Sean|last2= Brown|first2=David|date=May 14, 2019 |title=Inequality driving 'deaths of despair'|url=https://www.bbc.com/news/education-48229037|work=] |access-date=December 18, 2019 }}</ref> Conversely, other research did not find these effects or concluded that research suffered from issues of confounding variables.<ref>Antony, Jürgen, and Torben Klarl. "Estimating the income inequality-health relationship for the United States between 1941 and 2015: Will the relevant frequencies please stand up?." ''The Journal of the Economics of Ageing''. 17 (2020): 100275.</ref>
* '''Social goods''': British researchers ] and ] have found lower rates of social goods (], educational performance, ], ], ], even numbers of ]s issued) in countries and states with higher inequality.<ref name="The Spirit Level"/><ref name="Income inequality and health: a cau"/>
* '''Social cohesion''': Research has shown an inverse link between income inequality and social cohesion. In more equal societies, people are much more likely to ] each other, measures of ] (the benefits of goodwill, fellowship, mutual sympathy and social connectedness among groups who make up a social units) suggest greater community involvement.
* ''' Happiness''': According to the 2019 ], increasing socioeconomic inequality, along with rising healthcare costs, surging addiction rates, and an unhealthy ], are causes of unhappiness around the world.<ref>{{cite news |last= Conley |first=Julia|date=March 20, 2019
|title=Social Democratic Nations Rank Happiest on Global Index (Again). US Ranking Falls (Again)|url=https://www.truthdig.com/articles/social-democracies-top-global-happiness-index-again-u-s-falls-again/|work=] |access-date=August 21, 2023}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|url=https://s3.amazonaws.com/happiness-report/2019/WHR19.pdf|title=World Happiness Report 2019}}</ref>
* '''Crime''': The cross national research shows that in societies with less economic inequality the ] rates are consistently lower.<ref>{{cite journal |doi=10.1016/S0047-2352(98)00064-6 |title=A comparative analysis of nations with low and high levels of violent crime |journal=Journal of Criminal Justice |volume=27 |issue=3 |pages=259–274 |year=1999 |last1=Neapolitan |first1=Jerome L }}</ref> A 2016 study finds that interregional inequality increases terrorism.<ref>{{cite journal |doi=10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2016.01.004 |title=Terrorism and spatial disparities: Does interregional inequality matter? |journal=European Journal of Political Economy |volume=42 |pages=60–74 |year=2016 |last1=Ezcurra |first1=Roberto |last2=Palacios |first2=David }}</ref> Other research has argued inequality has little effect on crime rates.<ref>{{cite journal |doi=10.1007/s00148-015-0579-3 |title=Inequality and crime revisited: Effects of local inequality and economic segregation on crime |journal=Journal of Population Economics |volume=29 |issue=2 |pages=593–626 |year=2015 |last1=Kang |first1=Songman |s2cid=155852321 }}</ref><ref>Corvalana, Alejandro, and Matteo Pazzonab. "Does Inequality Really Increase Crime? Theory and Evidence." In Technical Report. 2019.</ref>
* '''Welfare''': Studies have found evidence that in societies where inequality is lower, population-wide satisfaction and happiness tend to be higher.<ref name="happiniess">{{cite web |author=Richard Layard |title=Happiness: Has Social Science A Clue? |work=Lionel Robbins Memorial Lectures |date=March 3–5, 2003 |url=http://stoa.org.uk/topics/happiness/Happiness%20-%20Has%20Social%20Science%20A%20Clue.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130603132909/http://stoa.org.uk/topics/happiness/Happiness%20-%20Has%20Social%20Science%20A%20Clue.pdf|archive-date=June 3, 2013 |url-status=dead}}</ref>{{sfnm|1a1=Blanchard|2a1=Oswald|1y=2000|2y=2003|2loc={{vn|date=November 2022|reason=garbled cite, 2 authors, 2 dates. My best guess follows.}}}}<ref>{{cite book |last=Blanchard |first=Olivier |year=2000 |title=Macroeconomics |edition=2nd |place=Upper Saddle River N.J |publisher=Prentice-Hall |oclc=42454429}}{{vn|date=November 2022|reason=This is a guess.}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last=Oswald |first=Andrew J. |title=How Much do External Factors Affect Wellbeing? A Way to Use 'Happiness Economics' to Decide |journal=The Psychologist |date=2003 |volume=16 |pages=140–141 |url=https://www.andrewoswald.com/docs/finalsentthepsychologistaug2002.pdf}}{{vn|date=November 2022|reason=This is a guess.}}</ref>
* '''Poverty:''' Study made by Jared Bernstein and Elise Gould suggest, that the poverty in the United States could have been reduced by the lowering of economic inequality for the past few decades.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Bernstein |first=Jared|date=January 13, 2014|title=Poverty and Inequality, in Charts |website=Economix Blog |url=https://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2014/01/13/poverty-and-inequality-in-charts/ |access-date=April 30, 2021}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|title=No Matter How We Measure Poverty, the Poverty Rate Would Be Much Lower If Economic Growth Were More Broadly Shared|website=Economic Policy Institute |url=https://www.epi.org/blog/matter-measure-poverty-poverty-rate-economic/ |access-date=April 30, 2021}}</ref>
* '''Debt''': Income inequality has been the driving factor in the growing ],<ref name=denial> by Timothy Noah ''The New Republic'' (October 25, 2012)</ref><ref> {{Webarchive |url=https://archive.today/20120711200159/http://newamerica.net/publications/policy/the_way_forward |date=July 11, 2012 }} By Daniel Alpert, Westwood Capital; Robert Hockett, Professor of Law, Cornell University; and Nouriel Roubini, Professor of Economics, New York University, New America Foundation, October 10, 2011</ref> as high earners bid up the price of real estate and middle income earners go deeper into debt trying to maintain what once was a middle class lifestyle.<ref name=plumer>{{cite news|last=Plumer |first=Brad|date=March 27, 2013|title='Trickle-down consumption': How rising inequality can leave everyone worse off |url=https://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2013/03/27/trickle-down-consumption-how-rising-inequality-can-leave-everyone-worse-off/|newspaper=Washington Post|access-date=March 27, 2013}}</ref>
* '''Economic growth''': A 2016 meta-analysis found that "the effect of inequality on growth is negative and more pronounced in less developed countries than in rich countries", though the average impact on growth was not significant. The study also found that wealth inequality is more pernicious to growth than income inequality.<ref name=":0"/>
* '''Civic participation''': Higher income inequality led to less of all forms of social, cultural, and civic participation among the less wealthy.<ref>Bram Lancee and Hermanvande Werfhorst (2011) GINI Discussion Paper No. 6 (Amsterdam Centre for Inequality Studies)</ref>
* '''Political instability''': Studies indicate that economic inequality leads to greater political instability, including an increased risk of democratic breakdown<ref name=":5" /><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Alesina|first1=Alberto |last2=Perotti|first2=Roberto|year=1996|title=Income distribution, political instability, and investment|url=http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:4553018 |journal=European Economic Review|volume=40|issue=6|pages=1203–1228 |doi=10.1016/0014-2921(95)00030-5 |s2cid=51838517}}</ref><ref name="Lieberman">{{Cite journal|author=Robert C. Lieberman|author2=Suzanne Mettler|author3=Thomas B. Pepinsky|author4=Kenneth M. Roberts|author5=Richard Valelly |date=June 2019|title=The Trump Presidency and American Democracy: A Historical and Comparative Analysis|journal=Perspectives on Politics|volume=17 |issue=2|pages=470–479|doi=10.1017/S1537592718003286|doi-access=free}}</ref><ref name=":22">{{Cite journal|author=Walder, D.|author2=Lust, E.|date=2018|title=Unwelcome Change: Coming to Terms with Democratic Backsliding|journal=Annual Review of Political Science|volume=21|issue=1|pages=93–113 |doi=10.1146/annurev-polisci-050517-114628|doi-access=free}}</ref><ref name=":42">{{Cite journal |last1=Huq|first1=Aziz|last2=Ginsburg|first2=Tom|date=2018|title=How to Lose a Constitutional Democracy |journal=UCLA Law Review|volume=65|pages=78–169|url=https://heinonline.org/HOL/Page?handle=hein.journals/uclalr65&div=5&g_sent=1&casa_token=&collection=journals&t=1558094508}}</ref> and civil conflict.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Baten|first1=Joerg |last2=Mumme|first2=Christina|date=December 1, 2013 |title=Does inequality lead to civil wars? A global long-term study using anthropometric indicators (1816–1999) |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0176268013000402 |journal=European Journal of Political Economy|volume=32|pages=56–79|doi=10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2013.06.007|issn=0176-2680}}</ref><ref name=":6" /> A significant impact of inequality on civil war probability has been found through anthropometric methods.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Christina Mumme and Jörg Baten|title=Civil War Determinants From a Long-Term Perspective: Was There Impact Of Anthropometric Deprivation From 1816–1999?|journal=European Review of Political Economy|volume=32 |date=2014 |pages=56–79}}</ref>
* '''Political party responses:''' One study finds that economic inequality prompts attempts by left-leaning politicians to pursue redistributive policies while right-leaning politicians seek to repress the redistributive policies.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Connell|first1=Brendan J.|last2=Dorr|first2=Dalton C. |last3=Shin|first3=Adrian J.|date=March 6, 2021|title=Inequality and the Partisan Political Economy|journal=Representation|volume=57|issue=4|pages=575–601 |doi=10.1080/00344893.2021.1883100 |s2cid=233845379|issn=0034-4893}}</ref>


====Mechanisms==== ==Perspectives==
According to economist ], while traditionally economists thought inequality was good for growth
<blockquote>"The view that income inequality harms growth – or that improved equality can help sustain growth – has become more widely held in recent years. ... The main reason for this shift is the increasing importance of human capital in development. When physical capital mattered most, savings and investments were key. Then it was important to have a large contingent of rich people who could save a greater proportion of their income than the poor and invest it in physical capital. But now that human capital is scarcer than machines, widespread education has become the secret to growth."<ref name=more>| Branko Milanovic| ''Finance & Development''| September 2011| Vol. 48, No. 3</ref></blockquote> "Broadly accessible education" is both difficult to achieve when income distribution is uneven and tends to reduce "income gaps between skilled and unskilled labor."


===Socialist perspectives===
The ] of the late twenty-oughts do not seem to be correlated to redistribution policies in Europe. With the exception of Ireland, the countries at risk of default in 2011 (Greece, Italy, Spain, Portugal) were notable for their high Gini-measured levels of income inequality compared to other European countries. As measured by the Gini index, Greece as of 2008 had more income inequality than the economically healthy Germany.<ref> by Timothy Noah, ''The New Republic'' December 20, 2011</ref>
]s attribute the vast disparities in wealth to the private ownership of the ] by a class of owners, creating a situation where a small portion of the population lives off ] property income by virtue of ownership titles in capital equipment, financial assets and corporate stock. By contrast, the vast majority of the population is dependent on income in the form of a wage or salary. In order to rectify this situation, socialists argue that the means of production should be ] so that income differentials would be reflective of ] to the social product.<ref>Barbara Goodwin. ''Using Political Ideas''. West Sussex, England: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., 2007. p. 107.</ref>


] attributes rising inequality to job automation and ] within capitalism. The process of job automation conflicts with the capitalist property form and its attendant system of ]. In this analysis, capitalist firms increasingly substitute capital equipment for labor inputs (workers) under competitive pressure to reduce costs and maximize profits. Over the long term, this trend increases the ], meaning that less workers are required in proportion to capital inputs, increasing unemployment (the "]"). This process exerts a downward pressure on wages. The substitution of capital equipment for labor (mechanization and automation) raises the productivity of each worker, resulting in a situation of relatively stagnant wages for the working class amidst rising levels of ] for the capitalist class.<ref>{{cite book |last= Wood|first= John Cunningham |author-link=John Cunningham Wood|title= Karl Marx's Economics: Critical Assessments I and II |publisher=Routledge|year= 1996 |isbn= 978-0415087148}}</ref>
===Housing===
A number of researchers (David Rodda,<ref name="Rodda 1994">
{{Cite thesis|title=Rich Man, Poor Renter: A Study of the Relationship Between the Income Distribution and Low Cost Rental Housing|author=David T Rodda|date=1994|publisher=Harvard University|pages=148}}</ref> Jacob Vigdor,<ref name="Vigdor 2002">{{cite web|author= Vigdor, Jacob|title= Does Gentrification Harm the Poor?| url =http://muse.jhu.edu/login?auth=0&type=summary&url=/journals/brookings-wharton_papers_on_urban_affairs/v2002/2002.1vigdor.html
| publisher = Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs|year= 2002}}</ref> and Janna Matlack), argue that a shortage of ] – at least in the US – is caused in part by income inequality.<ref name="MatlackVigdor2006">{{cite report|title=Do Rising Tides Lift All Prices? Income Inequality and Housing Affordability|author1=Janna L. Matlack|author2=Jacob L. Vigdor|number=NBER Working Paper No. 12331| date=June 2006 |url=http://www.nber.org/papers/w12331.pdf|format=PDF|publisher=National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER)|location=Cambridge, MA|accessdate= June 6, 2012}}page 1</ref> David Rodda<ref name="Rodda 1994"/><ref>(cited in Matlack ''Do Rising Tides Lift All Prices? Income Inequality and Housing Affordability'', 2006)</ref> noted that from 1984 and 1991, the number of quality rental units decreased as the demand for higher quality housing increased (Rhoda 1994:148).<ref name="Rodda 1994" /> Through ] of older neighbourhoods, for example, in East New York, rental prices increased rapidly as landlords found new residents willing to pay higher market rate for housing and left lower income families without rental units. The ] policy combined with rising prices made it difficult or impossible for low income residents to keep pace.<ref name=pushedout2009>{{cite report|title=Pushed Out: The Hidden Costs of Gentrification: Displacement and Homelessness|url=http://www.icphusa.org/PDF/reports/ICP%20Report_Pushed%20Out.pdf|format=PDF|year=2009|publisher=Institute for Children and Poverty}}</ref>


Marxist socialists ultimately predict the emergence of a ] based on the common ownership of the means of production, where each individual citizen would have free access to the articles of consumption ('']''). According to Marxist philosophy, equality in the sense of free access is essential for freeing individuals from dependent relationships, thereby allowing them to transcend ].<ref>{{cite web |url=http://econc10.bu.edu/okyn/OKpers/Income_Distribution/Edusex_indi/edusex_normative_view.htm |title=The Normative View of Marxian Theory on Income Distribution under Socialism |author=Oldrich Kyn |access-date=November 30, 2013 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150314185131/http://econc10.bu.edu/okyn/OKpers/Income_Distribution/Edusex_indi/edusex_normative_view.htm |archive-date=March 14, 2015 |url-status=dead }}</ref>
===Aspirational consumption and household risk===
Firstly, certain costs are difficult to avoid and are shared by everyone, such as the costs of ], ], ] and ].<ref name=ODI>Milo Vandemoortele 2010. . London: ]</ref> If the ] does not provide these services, then for those on lower incomes, the costs must be borrowed and often those on lower incomes are those who are worse equipped to manage their finances.<ref name=ODI/> Secondly, aspirational consumption describes the process of middle income earners aspiring to achieve the standards of living enjoyed by their wealthier counterparts and one method of achieving this aspiration is by taking on debt.<ref name=ODI/> The result leads to even greater inequality and potential economic instability.<ref name=ODI/>

===Poverty===
] asserts that worsening inequality is impeding the fight against global ]. A 2013 report from the group stated that the $240 billion added to the fortunes of the world's richest billionaires in 2012 was enough to end extreme poverty four times over. Oxfam Executive Director Jeremy Hobbs said that "We can no longer pretend that the creation of wealth for a few will inevitably benefit the many – too often the reverse is true."<ref name="OXF-20130119">{{cite web |last=Slater |first=John |title=Annual income of richest 100 people enough to end global poverty four times over |url=http://www.oxfam.org/en/pressroom/pressrelease/2013-01-19/annual-income-richest-100-people-enough-end-global-poverty-four-times |date=January 19, 2013 |work=] |accessdate=September 20, 2014 }}</ref><ref name="WP-20130120">{{cite news |last=Khazan |first=Olga |title=Can we fight poverty by ending extreme wealth? |url=http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/worldviews/wp/2013/01/20/oxfam-poverty-income-inequality/ |date=January 20, 2013 |work=] |accessdate=September 20, 2014 }}</ref><ref name="BBC-20130118">{{cite news |authors=BBC Staff |title=Oxfam seeks 'new deal' on inequality from world leaders |url=http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/uk-21094962 |date=January 18, 2013 |work=] |accessdate=September 20, 2014 }}</ref>

] and Elise Gould of the ] suggest that ] could have been significantly mitigated if inequality had not increased over the last few decades.<ref>Jared Bernstein (January 13, 2014). . '']'' Retrieved September 20, 2014.</ref><ref>Elise Gould (January 15, 2014). . ]. Retrieved September 20, 2014.</ref>

==Perspectives==

===Socialism and Marxism===
]s attribute the vast disparities in wealth and income to the private ownership of the ] by a class of owners, resulting in a situation where a small portion of the population receives ] in the form of ] by virtue of ownership titles in capital equipment, financial assets and corporate stock. In contrast, the vast majority of the population is dependent on income in the form of a wage or salary. In order to rectify this situation, socialists argue that the means of production should be publicly owned, so that income differentials would be reflective of ] to the social product.<ref>Barbara Goodwin. Using Political Ideas. West Sussex, England, UK: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., 2007. p. 107.</ref>

Marxists ultimately predict the emergence of a ] based on the common ownership of the means of production, where each individual citizen would have free access to the articles of consumption ('']'').<ref>{{cite web |url=http://econc10.bu.edu/okyn/OKpers/Income_Distribution/Edusex_indi/edusex_normative_view.htm |title=The Normative View of Marxian Theory on Income Distribution under Socialism |author=Oldrich Kyn |publisher= |accessdate=November 30, 2013}}</ref> According to Marxist philosophy, equality in this sense is essential for freedom because equal access to the output of the means of production frees individuals from dependent relationships, allowing them to transcend ].


===Meritocracy=== ===Meritocracy===
] favors an eventual society where an individual's success is a direct function of his merit, or contribution. Economic inequality would be a natural consequence of the wide range in individual skill, talent and effort in human population.{{citation needed|date=September 2014}} ] favors an eventual society where an individual's success is a direct function of his merit, or contribution. Economic inequality would be a natural consequence of the wide range in individual skill, talent and effort in human population. ] stated that the progression of Western economic development that led to the ] was facilitated by men advancing through their own merit rather than because of family or political connections.<ref>
{{cite book
|title=The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present
|last=Landes
|first= David. S.
|year= 1969|publisher =Press Syndicate of the University of Cambridge
|location= Cambridge & New York
|isbn= 978-0521094184
}}
</ref>


===Liberal perspectives=== ===Liberal perspectives===
Most modern ], including centrist or left-of-center political groups, believe that the capitalist economic system should be fundamentally preserved, but the status quo regarding the income gap must be reformed. Social liberals favor a capitalist system with active ] macroeconomic policies, ], and progressive taxation (to even out differences in income inequality). Most modern ], including centrist or left-of-center political groups, believe that the capitalist economic system should be fundamentally preserved, but the status quo regarding the income gap must be reformed. Social liberals favor a capitalist system with active ] macroeconomic policies and progressive taxation (to even out differences in income inequality). Research indicates that people who hold liberal beliefs tend to see greater income inequality as morally wrong.<ref>O'Donnell, Michael, and Serena Chen. "Political Ideology, the Moralizing of Income Inequality, and Its Social Consequences." Available at {{SSRN|3253666}} (2018).</ref>

However, contemporary ] and ] generally do not take a stance on wealth inequality, but believe in ] regardless of whether it leads to unequal wealth distribution. In 1966 ], a prominent figure in the ] of economic thought, explains:


However, contemporary ] and ] generally do not take a stance on wealth inequality, but believe in ] regardless of whether it leads to unequal wealth distribution. In 1966 ], a prominent figure in the ] of economic thought, explains:
<blockquote>The liberal champions of equality under the law were fully aware of the fact that men are born unequal and that it is precisely their inequality that generates social cooperation and civilization. Equality under the law was in their opinion not designed to correct the inexorable facts of the universe and to make natural inequality disappear. It was, on the contrary, the device to secure for the whole of mankind the maximum of benefits it can derive from it. Henceforth no man-made institutions should prevent a man from attaining that station in which he can best serve his fellow citizens.</blockquote> <blockquote>The liberal champions of equality under the law were fully aware of the fact that men are born unequal and that it is precisely their inequality that generates social cooperation and civilization. Equality under the law was in their opinion not designed to correct the inexorable facts of the universe and to make natural inequality disappear. It was, on the contrary, the device to secure for the whole of mankind the maximum of benefits it can derive from it. Henceforth no man-made institutions should prevent a man from attaining that station in which he can best serve his fellow citizens.</blockquote>


] argued that government redistributes wealth by force (usually in the form of taxation), and that the ideal moral society would be one where all individuals are free from force. However, Nozick recognized that some modern economic inequalities were the result of forceful taking of property, and a certain amount of redistribution would be justified to compensate for this force but not because of the inequalities themselves. ] argued in '']''<ref name="RawlsJustice"/> that inequalities in the distribution of wealth are only justified when they improve society as a whole, including the poorest members. Rawls does not discuss the full implications of his theory of justice. Some see Rawls's argument as a justification for ] since even the poorest members of society theoretically benefit from increased innovations under capitalism; others believe only a strong ] can satisfy Rawls's theory of justice. ] argued that government redistributes wealth by force (usually in the form of taxation), and that the ideal moral society would be one where all individuals are free from force. However, Nozick recognized that some modern economic inequalities were the result of forceful taking of property, and a certain amount of redistribution would be justified to compensate for this force but not because of the inequalities themselves.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Nozick |first=Robert|title=Anarchy, state, and utopia |title-link=Anarchy, State, and Utopia |date=1974|publisher=Blackwell Publishing|isbn=978-0631197805|oclc=1120103788}}</ref> ] argued in '']''<ref name="RawlsJustice">{{cite book |last=Rawls |first=John |author-link=John Rawls |title=A Theory of Justice |year=2005 |publisher=Belknap Press of Harvard University Press |isbn=978-0674017726|title-link=A Theory of Justice }}</ref> that inequalities in the distribution of wealth are only justified when they improve society as a whole, including the poorest members. Rawls does not discuss the full implications of his theory of justice. Some see Rawls's argument as a justification for ] since even the poorest members of society theoretically benefit from increased innovations under capitalism; others believe only a strong ] can satisfy Rawls's theory of justice.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Barry, Brian|url=|title=The liberal theory of justice : a critical examination of the principal doctrines in A theory of justice by John Rawls|date=1975|publisher=Clarendon Press|isbn=0198245092|oclc=476228713}}</ref>


Classical liberal ] believed that if government action is taken in pursuit of economic equality then political freedom would suffer. In a famous quote, he said: Classical liberal ] believed that if government action is taken in pursuit of economic equality then political freedom would suffer. In a famous quote, he said:


:A society that puts equality before freedom will get neither. A society that puts freedom before equality will get a high degree of both. <blockquote>A society that puts equality before freedom will get neither. A society that puts freedom before equality will get a high degree of both.</blockquote>


Economist ] has argued that though income inequality has increased within nations, globally it has fallen over the last 20 years. He argues that though income inequality may make individual nations worse off, overall, the world has improved as global inequality has been reduced.<ref>{{cite news|last1=Cowen|first1=Tyler|title=Income Inequality Is Not Rising Globally. It's Falling.|url=http://www.nytimes.com/2014/07/20/upshot/income-inequality-is-not-rising-globally-its-falling-.html|accessdate=July 26, 2014|publisher=New York Times|date=July 19, 2014}}</ref> Economist ] has argued that though income inequality has increased within nations, globally it has fallen over the 20 years leading up to 2014. He argues that though income inequality may make individual nations worse off, overall, the world has improved as global inequality has been reduced.<ref>{{cite news|last1=Cowen|first1=Tyler|title=Income Inequality Is Not Rising Globally. It's Falling.|url=https://www.nytimes.com/2014/07/20/upshot/income-inequality-is-not-rising-globally-its-falling-.html|access-date=July 26, 2014|work=The New York Times|date=July 19, 2014}}</ref>


===Social justice arguments=== ===Social justice arguments===
Patrick Diamond and Anthony Giddens (professors of Economics and Sociology, respectively) hold that 'pure ] is incoherent because, without redistribution, one generation's successful individuals would become the next generation's embedded caste, hoarding the wealth they had accumulated'. Patrick Diamond and Anthony Giddens (professors of Economics and Sociology, respectively) hold that 'pure ] is incoherent because, without redistribution, one generation's successful individuals would become the next generation's embedded caste, hoarding the wealth they had accumulated'.<ref>{{Cite thesis |last=Li |first=Robert |date=July 1, 2011 |title='KILLING THE NOOB' A thesis on Meritocracy and what it has to do with Massive Multiplayer Online Role Playing Games |publisher=Swinburne University of Technology |degree=Bachelor of Arts with Honours |url=https://www.academia.edu/6719442}}</ref>


They also state that ] requires redistribution of high incomes and large concentrations of wealth in a way that spreads it more widely, in order to "recognise the contribution made by all sections of the community to building the nation's wealth." (Patrick Diamond and ], June 27, 2005, New Statesman)<ref></ref> They also state that ] requires redistribution of high incomes and large concentrations of wealth in a way that spreads it more widely, in order to "recognize the contribution made by all sections of the community to building the nation's wealth." (Patrick Diamond and ], June 27, 2005, New Statesman)<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.newstatesman.com/200506270022 |work=New Statesman |author=Anthony Giddens |date=27 June 2005 |title=NS Essay – 'Accumulation of wealth is unjust where it arises not from hard work and risk-taking enterprise, but from ''brute luck'' factors such as returns from property. Inheritance is a form of brute-luck inequality' |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20071209055040/http://www.newstatesman.com/200506270022 |archive-date=2007-12-09}}</ref>


] stated in his '']'', that "as long as the problems of the poor are not radically resolved by rejecting the absolute autonomy of markets and financial speculation and by attacking the structural causes of inequality, no solution will be found for the world’s problems or, for that matter, to any problems."<ref>] (December 2, 2013). . ''].'' Retrieved December 8, 2013.</ref> He later declared that "inequality is the root of social evil."<ref>Andrew Brown (April 28, 2014). . ''The Guardian.'' Retrieved May 27, 2014.<!--Expanded quote from the ''Evangelii gaudium'' for clarification purposes: "Just as the commandment 'Thou shalt not kill' sets a clear limit in order to safeguard the value of human life, today we also have to say 'Thou shalt not' to an economy of exclusion and inequality. Such an economy kills Today everything comes under the laws of competition and the survival of the fittest, where the powerful feed upon the powerless. As a consequence, masses of people find themselves excluded and marginalised: without work, without possibilities, without any means of escape. Human beings are themselves considered consumer goods to be used and then discarded."--></ref> ] stated in his '']'', that "as long as the problems of the poor are not radically resolved by rejecting the absolute autonomy of markets and financial speculation and by attacking the structural causes of inequality, no solution will be found for the world's problems or, for that matter, to any problems."<ref>] (December 2, 2013). . ''].'' Retrieved December 8, 2013.</ref> He later declared that "inequality is the root of social evil."<ref>Andrew Brown (April 28, 2014). . ''The Guardian.'' Retrieved May 27, 2014.<!--Expanded quote from the ''Evangelii gaudium'' for clarification purposes: "Just as the commandment 'Thou shalt not kill' sets a clear limit in order to safeguard the value of human life, today we also have to say 'Thou shalt not' to an economy of exclusion and inequality. Such an economy kills ... Today everything comes under the laws of competition and the survival of the fittest, where the powerful feed upon the powerless. As a consequence, masses of people find themselves excluded and marginalised: without work, without possibilities, without any means of escape. Human beings are themselves considered consumer goods to be used and then discarded."--></ref>


When income inequality is low, ] will be relatively high, because more people who want ordinary ]s and services will be able to afford them, while the ] will not be as relatively ] by the wealthy.<ref name="pigou"/><ref name=BergOstrySD /> When income inequality is low, ] will be relatively high, because more people who want ordinary ]s and services will be able to afford them, while the ] will not be as relatively ] by the wealthy.<ref name=pigou>''''| ]</ref>


===Effects on social welfare=== ===Effects on social welfare===
In most western democracies, the desire to eliminate or reduce economic inequality is generally associated with the political left. One practical argument in favor of reduction is the idea that economic inequality reduces social cohesion and increases social unrest, thereby weakening the society. In most western democracies, the desire to eliminate or reduce economic inequality is generally associated with the ]. One practical argument in favor of reduction is the idea that economic inequality reduces ] and increases ], thereby weakening the society. There is evidence that this is true (see ]) and it is intuitive, at least for small face-to-face groups of people.<ref>{{Cite web |title=inequity - Traduction anglais-arabe {{!}} PONS |url=https://fr.pons.com/traduction/anglais-arabe/inequity |access-date=June 18, 2022 |website=fr.pons.com}}</ref> ], ], and Robert MacCulloch find that inequality negatively affects ] in Europe but not in the United States.<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.cepr.org/pubs/dps/DP2877.asp|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140201195135/http://www.cepr.org/pubs/dps/DP2877.asp|url-status=dead|title=Inequality and Happiness: Are Europeans and Americans Different?|archive-date=February 1, 2014}}</ref>


It has also been argued that economic inequality invariably translates to political inequality, which further aggravates the problem. Even in cases where an increase in economic inequality makes nobody economically poorer, an increased inequality of resources is disadvantageous, as increased economic inequality can lead to a power shift due to an increased inequality in the ability to participate in democratic processes.<ref>The relation between economic inequality and political inequality is explained by ] in the chapters ''The Presence of a Market Economy'' (p. 63), ''The Distribution of Political Resources'' (p. 84) und ''Market Capitalism and Human Dispositions'' (p. 87) in ''On Political Equality'', 2006, 120 pages, Yale University Press, {{ISBN|978-0300126877}}</ref> According to Paul and Moser, countries with high income inequality and poor unemployment protections experience worse mental health outcomes among the unemployed.<ref>{{Cite web |title=The toll of job loss |url=https://www.apa.org/monitor/2020/10/toll-job-loss |access-date=2023-11-26 |website=www.apa.org}}</ref>
There is evidence that this is true (see ]) and it is intuitive, at least for small face-to-face groups of people. ], ], and ] find that inequality negatively affects ] in Europe but not in the United States.<ref></ref>

It has also been argued that economic inequality invariably translates to political inequality, which further aggravates the problem. Even in cases where an increase in economic inequality makes nobody economically poorer, an increased inequality of resources is disadvantageous, as increased economic inequality can lead to a power shift due to an increased inequality in the ability to participate in democratic processes.<ref>The relation between economic inequality and political inequality is explained by ] in the chapters ''The Presence of a Market Economy'' (pp. 63), ''The Distribution of Political Resources'' (pp. 84) und ''Market Capitalism and Human Dispositions'' (pp. 87) in ''On Political Equality'', 2006, 120 pages, Yale University Press, ISBN 978-0-300-12687-7</ref>


===Capabilities approach=== ===Capabilities approach===
{{Further|Capability approach}} {{Further|Capability approach}}


The capabilities approach – sometimes called the human development approach – looks at income inequality and poverty as form of “capability deprivation”.<ref name="sen development">{{cite conference The capabilities approach – sometimes called the human development approach – looks at income inequality and poverty as form of "capability deprivation".<ref name="sen development">{{cite conference
| author = Amartya Sen | author = Amartya Sen
| year = 1999 | year = 1999
| title = Poverty as Capability Deprivation | title = Poverty as Capability Deprivation
| booktitle = Development as Freedom | book-title = Development as Freedom
| publisher = New York: Anchor Books | publisher = Anchor Books
| place = New York
}}</ref> Unlike ], which “defines well-being as utility maximization”, economic growth and income are considered a means to an end rather than the end itself.<ref name="fukuda-parr">Fukuda-Parr, Sakiko. 2003. “The Human Development Paradigm: Operationalizing Sen’s Ideas on Capabilities.” ''Feminist Economics'' 9(2/3): 301–17.</ref> Its goal is to “wid people’s choices and the level of their achieved well-being”<ref name="UNDP">, UNDP (1990) Human Deuelopment Report, Oxford University Press, New York</ref> through increasing functionings (the things a person values doing), capabilities (the freedom to enjoy functionings) and agency (the ability to pursue valued goals).<ref name=Deneulin_Alkire>{{Citation | last1 = Deneulin | first1 = Séverine | last2 = Alkire | first2 = Sabina | author-link1 = Séverine Deneulin| author-link2 = Sabina Alkire | contribution = The human development and capability approach | editor-last1 = Deneulin | editor-first1 = Séverine | editor-last2 = Shahani | editor-first2 = Lila | editor-link1 = Séverine Deneulin | title = An introduction to the human development and capability approach freedom and agency | pages = 22–48 | publisher = Earthscan International Development Research Centre | location = Sterling, Virginia Ottawa, Ontario | year = 2009 | isbn = 9781844078066 }}</ref>
}}</ref> Unlike ], which "defines well-being as utility maximization", economic growth and income are considered a means to an end rather than the end itself.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Fukuda-Parr |first1=Sakiko |title=The Human Development Paradigm: Operationalizing Sen's Ideas on Capabilities |journal=Feminist Economics |date=2003 |volume=9 |issue=2–3 |pages=301–317 |s2cid=18178004 |doi=10.1080/1354570022000077980}}</ref> Its goal is to "wid people's choices and the level of their achieved well-being"<ref name="UNDP">{{cite report |author=UNDP (United Nations Development Programme) |url=https://hdr.undp.org/system/files/documents//hdr1990encompletenostatspdf.pdf |date=January 1, 1990 |title=Human Deuelopment Report 1990 |publisher=Oxford University Press |place=Oxford & New York}} Via </ref> through increasing functioning (the things a person values doing), capabilities (the freedom to enjoy functionings) and agency (the ability to pursue valued goals).<ref name=Deneulin_Alkire>{{Citation |last1=Deneulin |first1=Séverine |last2=Alkire |first2=Sabina |author-link1=Séverine Deneulin| author-link2=Sabina Alkire |contribution=The human development and capability approach |editor-last1=Deneulin |editor-first1=Séverine |editor-last2=Shahani |editor-first2=Lila |editor-link1=Séverine Deneulin |title=An introduction to the human development and capability approach freedom and agency |pages=22–48 |publisher=Earthscan International Development Research Centre |location=Sterling, VA & Ottawa, Ontario |year=2009 |isbn=978-1844078066}}</ref>

When a person’s capabilities are lowered, they are in some way deprived of earning as much income as they would otherwise. An old, ill man cannot earn as much as a healthy young man; ]s and customs may prevent a woman from receiving an education or working outside the home. There may be an epidemic that causes widespread panic, or there could be rampant violence in the area that prevents people from going to work for fear of their lives.<ref name="sen development" /> As a result, income and economic inequality increases, and it becomes more difficult to reduce the gap without additional aid. To prevent such inequality, this approach believes it’s important to have political freedom, economic facilities, social opportunities, transparency guarantees, and protective security to ensure that people aren’t denied their functionings, capabilities, and agency and can thus work towards a better relevant income.

==Policy responses intended to mitigate==
]ation reduces absolute income inequality when the higher rates on higher-income individuals are paid and not ], and ] and ]s result in progressive ].<ref>Moyes, P. Social Choice and Welfare, Volume 5, Numbers 2-3 (1988), 227–234, DOI: 10.1007/BF00735763. Accessed: May 19, 2012.</ref><ref>Pickett and Wilkinson, '']'', 2011</ref><ref>{{cite web|last=Duncan|first=Denvil, Klara Sabirianova Peter|title=Unequal Inequalities: Do Progressive Taxes Reduce Income Inequality?|url=http://ftp.iza.org/dp6910.pdf|publisher=Institute for the Study of Labor|date=October 2012}}</ref> ] legislation has also been proposed as a means of reducing income inequality. The ] asserts that public spending is vital in reducing the ever expanding wealth gap.<ref name="OECD13">. ''].'' Retrieved May 14, 2013</ref>

The economists ] and ] recommend much higher top marginal tax rates on the wealthy, up to 50 percent, or 70 percent or even 90 percent.<ref>Annie Lowrey (April 16, 2012). . ''].'' Retrieved August 17, 2013.</ref> ], ], the United Front Against Austerity, among others, call for a ] (also known as the ]) to bolster the social safety net and the public sector.<ref>] (April 18, 2013). . ''].'' Retrieved June 5, 2013.</ref><ref>. UFAA.</ref><ref>Erika Eichelberger (October 30, 2013). . ''].'' Retrieved November 15, 2013.</ref>


When a person's capabilities are lowered, they are in some way deprived of earning as much income as they would otherwise. An old, ill man cannot earn as much as a healthy young man; ]s and customs may prevent a woman from receiving an education or working outside the home. There may be an epidemic that causes widespread panic, or there could be rampant violence in the area that prevents people from going to work for fear of their lives.<ref name="sen development" /> As a result, income inequality increases, and it becomes more difficult to reduce the gap without additional aid.
'']'' wrote in December 2013: "A minimum wage, providing it is not set too high, could thus boost pay with no ill effects on jobs....America's federal minimum wage, at 38% of median income, is one of the rich world's lowest. Some studies find no harm to employment from federal of state minimum wages, others see a small one, but none finds any serious damage."<ref></ref>


=== Societal acceptance ===
General limitations on and taxation of ] are popular across the political spectrum.<ref>{{cite news|last=Konczal|first=Mike|title=How an anti-rentier agenda might bring liberals, conservatives together|url=http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2013/03/30/ow-an-anti-rentier-agenda-might-bring-liberals-conservatives-together/|accessdate=April 6, 2013|newspaper=Washington Post|date=March 30, 2013}}</ref>
A 2022 study published in ] found that in countries where neoliberal institutions have significant influence over policies, the psychology of those population are shaped to have both a higher tolerance of large levels of income inequality, and prefer it over more egalitarian outcomes.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Communications |first=NYU Web |title=Neoliberal Policies, Institutions Have Prompted Preference for Greater Inequality, New Study Finds |url=http://www.nyu.edu/content/nyu/en/about/news-publications/news/2022/may/neoliberal-policies--institutions-have-prompted-preference-for-g |access-date=2023-08-20 |website=www.nyu.edu |language=en}}</ref>


=== Arguments that economic inequality is not a problem ===
Public policy responses addressing causes and effects of income inequality in the US include: ] ] adjustments, strengthening ] provisions such as ], ], the ], ], ], and ], increasing and reforming ] subsidies, increasing ] spending, and placing limits on and taxing ].<ref>{{cite news|last=Grusky|first=David B.|title=What to Do about Inequality|url=http://www.bostonreview.net/BR37.2/ndf_david_b_grusky_inequality.php|accessdate=April 6, 2013|newspaper=Boston Review|date=March–April 2013}}</ref>
The majority of researchers who analyze economic inequality argue that today's levels are problematic and deserve some mitigation.<ref name=Peterson_2017>{{Cite journal |last=Peterson |first=E. Wesley F. |date=December 2017 |title=Is Economic Inequality Really a Problem? A Review of the Arguments |journal=Social Sciences |language=en |volume=6 |issue=4 |pages=147 |doi=10.3390/socsci6040147 |issn=2076-0760 |doi-access=free }}</ref> There are however, some who disagree, and feel that current levels of inequality are necessary because it encourages individuals to gain useful skills and take risks, thereby encouraging growth and innovation, which are necessary for progress.{{ r | Peterson_2017 }} Some have also argued that economic inequality is a natural and fair outcome in market economies, in which the rewards are distributed based on different economic contributions because individuals have different attitudes and talents.{{r|Peterson_2017}} Many who feel that economic inequality is not a significant issue are associated with conservative or ] think tanks funded by corporations and the wealthy<ref>{{cite book |last=Stilwell|first=Frank |author-link=Frank Stilwell (economist)|date=2019 |title=The Political Economy of Inequality|url= |location= |publisher=]|pages=240–241 |isbn=978-1509528653}}</ref> like ], the ], the ] or the ], who may also feel that policies which would reduce inequality are direct attacks on their favored version of capitalism, ].{{ r | Peterson_2017 | p=1 | q=While the majority of analysts appear to believe that economic inequality is a significant issue requiring some form of remediation, some disagree. Many of these critics are associated with conservative think tanks such as the Heritage Foundation, the Manhattan Institute, the Cato Institute or the American Enterprise Institute (Furchtgoff-Roth 2014; Mayer 2015; Azerrad and Hederman 2012; Hassett and Mathur 2012). The fact that many of the worries about inequality carry with them implicit criticisms of capitalist economic systems may be one of the reasons conservative writers, who generally favor laissez-faire capitalism, have felt compelled to seek ways to counter arguments about the harmfulness of inequality. Another reason may be the fear that policies to reduce economic inequality may cause significant damage to the economy or to favored groups such as high-income innovators or productive business enterprises. ... Watson (2015), Conard (2016), and Watkins and Brook (2016) see danger in the concerns about economic inequality, arguing that efforts to reduce inequality will cause great harm to economic systems that have brought great prosperity to many. Conard (2016) suggests that high salaries for those at the top provide the incentives for talented individuals to obtain useful skills and to take risks that pay off handsomely for the rest of society. ... According to Mayer (2015, p. 115), " world without wealth and income inequality is in fact a world of universal poverty". From these perspectives, economic inequality is broadly beneficial because it encourages growth and innovation. }} In addition, some feel that economic inequality has not actually increased significantly.{{r|Peterson_2017}}


==See also== ==See also==
{{div col|colwidth=22em}}
{{cmn|2|
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ], disproportionate economic advancement of Europe * ], disproportionate economic advancement of Europe
* ] * ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* '']''
* ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ] and ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ]
}}
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
{{div col end}}


==References== ==References==
{{Reflist|colwidth=30em}} {{reflist|30em}}


==Further reading== ==Further reading==
;Books ;Books
* {{Cite book|last1=Alfani|first1=Guido|last2=Tullio|first2=Matteo Di|date=2019|title=The Lion's Share: Inequality and the Rise of the Fiscal State in Preindustrial Europe|url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/books/lions-share/EF7F07CCC52B674403391EF4BA8384D2|publisher=Cambridge University Press|pages=|doi=10.1017/9781108568043 |isbn=978-1-108-56804-3 }}
* Wiemer Salverda, Brian Nolan, Timothy M. Smeeding (editors, 2009): ''The Oxford Handbook of Economic Inequality''. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-923137-9
* {{cite book | last1 = Atkinson | first1 = Anthony B. | last2 = Bourguignon | first2 = François | author-link1 = Tony Atkinson | author-link2 = François Bourguignon | title = Handbook of income distribution | publisher = Elsevier | location = Amsterdam & New York | year = 2000 | isbn = 978-0444816313 }}
* {{cite book |last=von Braun |first=Joachim |author2=Eugenio Diaz-Bonilla |title=Globalization of Food and Agriculture and the Poor |year=2007 |publisher=Oxford University Press |url=http://www.ifpri.org/PUBS/otherpubs/globalpoor.asp}}
* ] (2015). '''' Cambridge, Massachusetts: ]. {{ISBN|0674504763}}
* Patrick Diamond and Anthony Giddens (2005), ''The New Egalitarianism'', Polity Press
* {{cite book | last1 = Barro | first1 = Robert J. | last2 = Sala-i-Martin | first2 = Xavier | author-link1 = Robert Barro | author-link2 = Xavier Sala-i-Martin |title=Economic growth |year=2003 | orig-year = 1995 |publisher=] |location= Massachusetts | edition = 2nd |isbn= 978-0262025539 }}
* A.B. Atkinsons and F. Bourguignon (1998), ''Handbook of Income Distribution'', Elsevier
* {{cite book |last1=Giddens |first1=Anthony |last2=Diamond |first2=Patrick |author-link1=Anthony Giddens |author-link2=Patrick Diamond |title=The new egalitarianism |publisher=Polity |year=2005 |isbn=978-0745634319}}
* Peter Lambert (2002). ''Distribution and Redistribution of Income''. Manchester University Press, 3rd edition. ISBN 0-7190-5732-9
* {{cite book |last=Gilens |first=Martin |title=Affluence and influence: Economic inequality and political power in America |publisher=Princeton University Press |year=2012 |isbn=978-0691162423}}
* ] and ] (2002), '']'', University of Helsinki, Westport, CT: Praeger. ISBN 0-275-97510-X
* {{cite book | editor-last1 = Gradín | editor-first1 = Carlos | editor-last2 = Leibbrandt | editor-first2 = Murray | editor-last3 =Tarp | editor-first3 = Finn| title = Inequality In The Developing World | series = WIDER Studies in Development Economics | publisher = Oxford University Press |url=https://global.oup.com/academic/product/inequality-in-the-developing-world-9780198863960?facet_narrowbypubdate_facet=Next\%203\%20months\&lang=en\&cc=fi$\#$ | year = 2021 | isbn = 978-0198863960 }}
* ]. . I.VIII.3.
* {{Cite book|last1=John|first1=K|date=2023|title=Foundations of Real-World Economics (3rd Edition) Section 9.1|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=eResEAAAQBAJ|publisher=Routledge|pages=|isbn=978-1-000-84789-5}}
* Benjamin I. Page and Lawrence R. Jacobs (2009), ''Class War?: What Americans Really Think about Economic Inequality'', University of Chicago Press ISBN 978-0-226-64455-4
* {{cite book |last=Schmidtz |first=David |authorlink=David Schmidtz |title=The Elements of Justice |year=2006 |publisher=Cambridge University Press |isbn=0-521-53936-6 }} * {{cite book | last = Lambert | first = Peter J. | title = The distribution and redistribution of income | publisher = Manchester University Press Palgrave | location = Manchester, NY| year = 2001 | edition = 3rd | isbn = 978-0719057328 }}
* {{cite book | last1 = Page | first1 = Benjamin I. | last2 = Jacobs | first2 = Lawrence R. | title = Class war?: What Americans really think about economic inequality | publisher = University of Chicago Press | location = Chicago | year = 2009 | isbn = 978-0226644554 }}
* ] and James Foster (1997). ''On Economic Inequality'' (Radcliffe Lectures). Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-828193-5.
* Ribeiro, Marcelo Byrro (2020). . . {{ISBN|978-1107092532}}.
* ] (2005), ''The Impact of Inequality – how to make sick societies healthier'', The New Press, ISBN 1-56584-925-6 (hc.)
* {{cite book | last1 = Salverda | first1 = Wiemer | last2 = Nolan | first2 = Brian | last3 = Smeeding | first3 = Timothy M. | title = The Oxford handbook of economic inequality | publisher = Oxford University Press | location = Oxford & New York | year = 2009 | isbn = 978-0199231379 }}
* ] and Kate Pickett (2009), ''The Spirit Level: Why more equal societies almost always do better'', Allen Lane, ISBN 978-1-846-14039-6
* {{cite book | last = Scheidel| first = Walter | author-link =Walter Scheidel| title =The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century | publisher = ]| location =Princeton| year =2017 | isbn =978-0691165028 }}
* {{cite web |url=http://economics.sbs.ohio-state.edu/jmcb/jmcb/05027/05027.pdf |title=Growth, Income Inequality, and Fiscal Policy: What are the Relevant Tradeoffs? |accessdate=December 14, 2006 |last=García-Peñalosa |first=Cecilia |author2=Stephen J. Turnovsky |date= January 2006 |format=PDF}}
* {{cite book |last=von Mises |first=Ludwig |authorlink=Ludwig von Mises |title=Human Action: A Treatise on Economics |chapter=chapter XXXV: The Welfare Principle versus the Market Principle |year=1996 |publisher=Foundation for Economic Education |url=https://www.mises.org/resources/3250|isbn=1-57246-021-0 }} * {{cite book |last=Schmidtz |first=David |author-link=David Schmidtz |title=The elements of justice |year=2006 |publisher=Cambridge University Press | location = Cambridge & New York |isbn=978-0521539364 }}
* {{cite book | last = Sen | first = Amartya | author-link = Amartya Sen | title = Development as Freedom | publisher = Oxford University Press | location = New York | year = 1999 | isbn = 978-0198297581 | title-link = Development as Freedom }}
* Séverine Deneulin and Lila Shahani (2009). ''An Introduction to the Human Development and Capability Approach''. Sterling, VA: Earthscan.
* {{cite book | last1 = Sen | first1 = Amartya | last2 = Foster | first2 = James E. | author-link1 = Amartya Sen | title = On economic inequality | publisher = Clarendon Press Oxford University Press | location = Oxford & New York | year = 1997 | series = Radcliffe Lectures | isbn = 978-0198281931 }}
* ] (1999). ''Development as Freedom''. New York: Anchor Books.
* {{cite book | last = Wilkinson | first = Richard G. | author-link = Richard G. Wilkinson | title = The impact of inequality: how to make sick societies healthier | publisher = Routledge | location = London | year = 2005 | isbn = 978-0415372695 }}
* Martin Gilens. . Princeton University Press and the Russell Sage Foundation, 2012.
* {{cite book | last1 = Wilkinson | first1 = Richard G. | last2 = Pickett | first2 = Kate | author-link1 = Richard G. Wilkinson | author-link2 = Kate Pickett | title = The spirit level: why more equal societies almost always do better | publisher = Allen Lane | location = London | year = 2009 | isbn = 978-1846140396 | title-link = The Spirit Level: Why More Equal Societies Almost Always Do Better }}
* Barro, R. 1991. "Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Countries". ''Quarterly Journal of Economics'' 106: 407–43.
* Barro, R. and X. Sala-i-Martin. 1995. ''Economic Growth''. New York: McGraw-Hill.
* Dollar, D. and R. Gatti. 1999. ''Gender Inequality, Income, and Growth: Are Good Times good for Women?'' Washington DC: The World Bank.
* Lagerlöf, N. 1999. ‘'Gender Inequality, Fertility, and Growth’'. Department of Economics, University of Sydney
* Seguino, S. 1998. ''Gender Inequality and Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Analysis''. University of Vermont.
* Solow, R. 1956. "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth". ''Quarterly Journal of Economics'' 70: 65–94


;Articles
;Papers
* {{cite magazine |author-link=Liaquat Ahamed |last=Ahamed |first=Liaquat |title=Widening Gyre: The rise and fall and rise of economic inequality |magazine=] |date=September 2, 2019 |pages=26–29 |quote=here seems to some sort of cap on inequality – a limit to the economic divisions a country can ultimately cope with.}}
* Kaldor, N., 1955, "Alternative Theories of Distribution", ''Review of Economic Studies'', 23(2), 83–100.
* {{cite journal |doi=10.1016/j.jpubeco.2003.07.006 |title=Inequality and happiness: Are Europeans and Americans different? |journal=Journal of Public Economics |volume=88 |issue=9–10 |pages=2009–2042 |year=2004 |last1=Alesina |first1=Alberto |last2=Di Tella |first2=Rafael |last3=MacCulloch |first3=Robert |citeseerx=10.1.1.203.664 }}
* Galor, O., and J., Zeira, 1993, "Income Distribution and Macroeconomics," ''Review of Economic Studies'', 60(1), 35–52.
* {{cite journal | last1 = Andersen | first1 = Robert | year = 2012 | title = Support for Democracy in Cross-national Perspective: The Detrimental Effect of Economic Inequality | url = http://archive.uva-aias.net/uploaded_files/publications/DP47-Andersen.pdf | journal = Research in Social Stratification and Mobility | volume = 30 | issue = 4 | pages = 389–402 | doi = 10.1016/j.rssm.2012.04.002 | access-date = May 12, 2019 | archive-date = June 24, 2021 | archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20210624200223/http://archive.uva-aias.net/uploaded_files/publications/DP47-Andersen.pdf | url-status = dead }}
* Maavak, Mathew. "", ''Journal of Futures Studies'', December 2012, 17(2): 15–36
* {{cite journal |doi=10.1111/j.1540-5907.2008.00352.x |jstor=25193859 |title=Economic Inequality and Intolerance: Attitudes toward Homosexuality in 35 Democracies |journal=American Journal of Political Science |volume=52 |issue=4 |pages=942–958 |year=2008 |last1=Andersen |first1=Robert |last2=Fetner |first2=Tina |hdl=11375/22293 |hdl-access=free }}
* {{Cite journal | first1=A. | last1=Alesina | first2=Rafael | first3=Robert | last3=MacCulloch | title=Inequality and Happiness: Are Americans and Europeans Different? | journal=Journal of Public Economics | year=2004 |volume=88 | pages=2009–2042 | last2=Di Tella |url=http://www.cepr.org/pubs/dps/DP2877.asp | doi=10.1016/j.jpubeco.2003.07.006 | postscript=<!--None--> | issue=9–10 }}.
* {{cite journal |doi=10.2307/2937943 |jstor=2937943 |title=Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries |journal=The Quarterly Journal of Economics |volume=106 |issue=2 |pages=407–443 |year=1991 |last1=Barro |first1=Robert J. |citeseerx=10.1.1.312.3126 }}
* Andersen, Robert and Tina Fetner. 2008. "Economic Inequality and Intolerance: Attitudes toward Homosexuality in 35 Democracies", ''American Journal of Political Science'', 52 (4): 942–58.
* {{Cite journal | first=Robert | last=Barro | authorlink=Robert Barro | title=Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries | journal=Journal of Economic Growth | year=2000 |volume=7 |issue=1 | url=http://post.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/barro/papers/p_inequalitygrw.pdf | postscript=<!--None--> }}.{{dead link|date=August 2013}} * {{cite journal |doi=10.1023/A:1009850119329 |title=Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries |year=2000 |last1=Barro |first1=Robert J. |journal=Journal of Economic Growth |volume=5 |issue=1 |pages=5–32 |s2cid=2089406 }}
* Cousin, Bruno; Chauvin, Sébastien (2021). ''Sociology Compass'' '''15''' (6): 1–15.
* Ravallion, Martin (2005). ], 5 May, Policy Research Working Paper no. WPS 3579,
* Cousin, Bruno; ]; ] (2018). '']'' '''16''' (2): 225–249.
* Sala-Martin, Xavier (2006). "," ''Quarterly Journal of Economics'', 121(2), May, pp.&nbsp;351–397.
* {{cite journal |doi=10.2307/2297811 |jstor=2297811 |title=Income Distribution and Macroeconomics |journal=The Review of Economic Studies |volume=60 |issue=1 |pages=35–52 |year=1993 |last1=Galor |first1=Oded |last2=Zeira |first2=Joseph |citeseerx=10.1.1.636.8225 }}
* {{Cite web | first1=Eric. | last1=Uslaner | first2=Brown. | last2=Mitchell | title=Inequality, Trust, and Civic Engagement | year=2002| url=http://www.bsos.umd.edu/gvpt/uslaner/uslanerrussellsage.pdf | postscript=<!--None--> }}
* Godechot, Olivier et al. (2024). "". ''American Journal of Sociology''.
* Fukuda-Parr, Sakiko. 2003. “The Human Development Paradigm: Operationalizing Sen’s Ideas on Capabilities.” ''Feminist Economics'' 9(2/3): 301–17.
* {{cite journal |last1=Goudarzi|first1=Shahrzad |last2=Badaan|first2=Vivienne |last3=Knowles|first3=Eric D. |date=May 10, 2022|title=Neoliberalism and the Ideological Construction of Equity Beliefs|url= https://psyarxiv.com/pc8zy/|journal=]|volume=17 |issue=5 |pages= 1431–1451|doi=10.1177/17456916211053311|pmid=35536556 |s2cid=237727224 |access-date=}}
* Kenworthy, Lane. "." ''Challenge'' 53.6 (2010): 93–109.
* {{cite journal |last1=Hatch |first1=Megan E. |last2=Rigby |first2=Elizabeth |title=Laboratories of (In)equality? Redistributive Policy and Income Inequality in the American States |journal=Policy Studies Journal |date=2015 |volume=43 |issue=2 |pages=163–187 |doi=10.1111/psj.12094}}
* Sawhill, Isabel. "" The Economics of Inequality, Poverty, and Discrimination in the 21st Century Ed. Robert S. Rycroft. The University of Mary Washington, 2012.
* {{cite journal |doi=10.2307/2296292 |jstor=2296292 |title=Alternative Theories of Distribution |journal=The Review of Economic Studies |volume=23 |issue=2 |pages=83–100 |year=1955 |last1=Kaldor |first1=Nicholas }}
* Smeeding, Timothy and Thompson, Jeffrey. . ''Who Loses in the Downturn? Economic Crisis, Employment and Income Distribution'' (Research in Labor Economics, 32), Ed. Herwig Immervoll, Andreas Peichl, Konstantinos Tatsiramos. Emerald Group Publishing Limited, 2011. 1–50.
* {{cite journal |doi=10.2753/0577-5132530606 |jstor=27896630 |title=Rising Inequality, Public Policy, and America's Poor |journal=Challenge |volume=53 |issue=6 |pages=93–109 |year=2010 |last1=Kenworthy |first1=Lane |s2cid=154630590 }}
* Smeeding, Timothy and Thompson, Jeffrey. . FRDB International Income Inequality Project (July 2011). Working paper.
* {{cite journal |doi=10.1177/0094306116681789 |title=Why the Surge in Income Inequality? |journal=Contemporary Sociology |volume=46 |issue=1 |pages=1–9 |year=2017 |last1=Kenworthy |first1=Lane |s2cid=151979382 |url=https://escholarship.org/uc/item/6t26836w }}
* Voitchovsky, Sarah. "." Working paper.
* {{cite journal |doi=10.1111/j.0022-2879.2007.00029.x |title=Growth, Income Inequality, and Fiscal Policy: What Are the Relevant Trade-offs? |journal=Journal of Money, Credit and Banking |volume=39 |issue=2–3 |pages=369–394 |year=2007 |last1=García-Peñalosa |first1=Cecilia | author-link1=Cecilia Garcia-Penalosa |last2=Turnovsky |first2=Stephen J. |citeseerx=10.1.1.186.2754 }}
* {{citation | last1= Pigou | first1 = Arthur C. | author-link = Arthur Cecil Pigou | contribution = Part I, Chapter VIII: Economic welfare and changes in the distribution of the national dividend ''(section I.VIII.3)'' | editor-last1 = Pigou | editor-first1 = Arthur C. | editor-link = Arthur Cecil Pigou | title = The economics of welfare | publisher = Macmillan and Co. | location = London | year = 1932 | orig-year = 1920 | edition = 4th | oclc = 302702 | url = http://www.econlib.org/library/NPDBooks/Pigou/pgEW8.html | postscript = .}}
* {{cite journal |doi=10.1162/qjec.2006.121.2.351 |jstor=25098796 |title=The World Distribution of Income: Falling Poverty and ... Convergence, Period |journal=The Quarterly Journal of Economics |volume=121 |issue=2 |pages=351–397 |year=2006 |last1=Sala-i-Martin |first1=X. }}
* {{cite journal |doi=10.1016/S0305-750X(00)00018-8 |title=Gender Inequality and Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Analysis |journal=World Development |volume=28 |issue=7 |pages=1211–1230 |year=2000 |last1=Seguino |first1=Stephanie }}
* {{cite book |doi=10.1108/S0147-9121(2011)0000032004 |chapter=Recent Trends in Income Inequality |title=Who Loses in the Downturn? Economic Crisis, Employment and Income Distribution |volume=32 |pages=1–50 |series=Research in Labor Economics |year=2011 |last1=Smeeding |first1=Timothy M. |last2=Thompson |first2=Jeffrey P. |isbn=978-0857247490 |url=http://www.emeraldinsight.com/10.1108/S0147-9121(2011)0000032004?WT.mc_id=RePEc |editor1-first=Herwig |editor1-last=Immervoll |editor2-first=Andreas |editor2-last=Peichl |editor3-first=Konstantinos |editor3-last=Tatsiramos }}
* {{cite journal |doi=10.2307/1884513 |jstor=1884513 |title=A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth |journal=The Quarterly Journal of Economics |volume=70 |issue=1 |pages=65–94 |year=1956 |last1=Solow |first1=Robert M. |url=http://rcin.org.pl/Content/39010 |hdl=10338.dmlcz/143862 |hdl-access=free }}
* {{cite journal |last1= Stewart |first1=Alexander J. |last2= McCarty |first2=Nolan |last3= Bryson |first3=Joanna J. |date=2020 |title=Polarization under rising inequality and economic decline |journal=] |volume=6 |issue=50 |pages= eabd4201|doi=10.1126/sciadv.abd4201 |pmid=33310855 |pmc=7732181 |arxiv=1807.11477 |bibcode=2020SciA....6.4201S |s2cid=216144890 |doi-access=free }}

=== Historical ===
* {{Cite journal|last1=Crayen|first1=Dorothee|last2=Joerg|first2=Baten|date=2010|title=New evidence and new methods to measure human capital inequality before and during the industrial revolution: France and the US in the seventeenth to nineteenth centuries.|url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227350073|journal=Economic History Review|volume = 63|issue=2 |pages=452–478|doi=10.1111/j.1468-0289.2009.00499.x }}
* {{Cite journal|last1=Hoffman|first1=Philip T.|date=2002|title=Real inequality in Europe since 1500|url=http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.824.3130&rep=rep1&type=pdf|journal=Journal of Economic History |volume =62|issue=2 |pages=322–355|doi=10.1017/S0022050702000529 |doi-broken-date=November 1, 2024 |citeseerx=10.1.1.824.3130 }}
* {{Cite journal|last1=Lindert|first1=Peter H.|last2=Steven|first2=Nafziger|date=2014|title=Russian inequality on the eve of revolution|url=http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.701.8331&rep=rep1&type=pdf|journal=Journal of Economic History |volume =74|issue=3 |pages=767–798|doi=10.1017/S002205071400059X |citeseerx=10.1.1.701.8331 }}
* Milanovic, Branko (2024). "". ''Explorations in Economic History''. '''93''': 101592.
* {{Cite journal|last1=Morrisson|first1=Christian|last2=Wayne|first2=Snyder|date=2000|title=The income inequality of France in historical perspective|journal=European Review of Economic History |volume =4|issue=1 |pages=59–83|doi=10.1017/S1361491600000149 |s2cid=33000439 }}
* {{cite journal | last1 = Nicolini | first1 = Esteban A. | last2 = Ramos Palencia | first2 = Fernando | year = 2016 | title = Decomposing income inequality in a backward pre-industrial economy: Old Castile (Spain) in the middle of the eighteenth century | journal = Economic History Review | volume = 69 | issue = 3| pages = 747–772 | doi = 10.1111/ehr.12122 | s2cid = 154988112 }}
* {{Cite journal|last1=Piketty|first1=Thomas|last2=Emmanuel|first2=Saez|date=2006|title=The evolution of top incomes: a historical and international perspective|url=http://unpan1.un.org/intradoc/groups/public/documents/APCITY/UNPAN027111.pdf|journal=American Economic Review |volume =96|issue=2 |pages=200–205|doi=10.1257/000282806777212116 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20111226010420/http://unpan1.un.org/intradoc/groups/public/documents/APCITY/UNPAN027111.pdf |archive-date=December 26, 2011 }}
* {{Cite journal|last1=Piketty|first1=Thomas|last2=Emmanuel|first2=Saez|date=2003|title=Income inequality in the United States, 1913–1998|url=http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.160.1932&rep=rep1&type=pdf|journal=Quarterly Journal of Economics |volume =118|issue=1 |pages=1–41|doi=10.1162/00335530360535135 |citeseerx=10.1.1.160.1932 }}
* {{Cite journal|last1=Saito|first1=Osamu|date=2015|title=Growth and inequality in the great and little divergence debate: a Japanese perspective; Covers 1600–1868 with comparison to Stuart England and Mughal India|url=http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.160.1932&rep=rep1&type=pdf|journal=Economic History Review |volume =68|issue=2 |pages=399–419|doi=10.1111/ehr.12071 |citeseerx=10.1.1.160.1932 }}
* {{Cite journal|last1=Stewart|first1=Frances|date=2016|title=Changing perspectives on inequality and development|url=|journal=Studies in Comparative International Development|volume = 51|issue=1 |pages=60–80|doi=10.1007/s12116-016-9222-x }}
* {{Cite journal|last1=Sutch|first1=Richard|date=2017|title=The One Percent across Two Centuries: A Replication of Thomas Piketty's Data on the Concentration of Wealth in the United States|url=http://economics.ucr.edu/repec/ucr/wpaper/201602.pdf|journal=Social Science History |volume =41|issue=4 |pages=587–613|doi=10.1017/ssh.2017.27 }}
* {{Cite journal|last1=Van|first1=Zanden|last2=Jan|first2=Luiten|date=1995|title=Tracing the beginning of the Kuznets curve: Western Europe during the early modern period|url=http://economics.ucr.edu/repec/ucr/wpaper/201602.pdf|journal=Economic History Review |volume =48|issue=4 |pages=643–664|doi=10.2307/2598128 |jstor=2598128 }}
* {{Cite journal|last1=Wei|first1=Yehua Dennis|date=2017|title=Geography of inequality in Asia|url=http://economics.ucr.edu/repec/ucr/wpaper/201602.pdf|journal=Geographical Review |volume =107|issue=2 |pages=263–275|doi=10.1111/j.1931-0846.2016.12212.x |bibcode=2017GeoRv.107..263W }}


==External links== ==External links==
{{Wikiquote}}
* {{commons category inline}}
{{Commons category|position=left}}
* {{cite encyclopedia |last1=Levy |first1=Frank |editor= ] (ed.) |encyclopedia=] |title=Distribution of Income |url=http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/DistributionofIncome.html |year=2008 |edition= 2nd |publisher=] |location=Indianapolis |isbn=978-0865976658 |oclc=237794267}}
* {{Cite journal|last1=Bowles|first1=Samuel|last2=Carlin|first2=Wendy|title=Inequality as experienced difference: A reformulation of the Gini coefficient|journal=Economics Letters|volume=186|pages=108789|doi=10.1016/j.econlet.2019.108789|issn=0165-1765|year=2020|doi-access=free}}
*
{{wealth}}
*
* explores some aspects of inequality using online, downloadable maps and graphics.
* ] – group seeking to improve health by addressing inequality.
* {{cite web
| author = Russell Sage Foundation
| url = http://www.russellsage.org/programs/main/inequality/program_view
| title = Social Inequality | work=Working Papers
| format = Web page | accessdate= March 2, 2006 |archiveurl = http://web.archive.org/web/20060529093606/http://www.russellsage.org/programs/main/inequality/program_view <!--None--> |archivedate = May 29, 2006}}
* {{cite web
| author = Leigh, A. and Jencks, C. | year=2005
| url = http://www.nber.org/%7Econfer/2005/si2005/he/leigh.pdf
| title = Inequality and Health: Long-Run Evidence from a Panel of Countries
| format = PDF | accessdate= November 30, 2005 }}
* {{cite web
| author = Clarkwest, A and Jencks, C. | year=2003
| url = http://www.popcenter.umd.edu/events/rsf/papers/Jencks.pdf
| title = Inequality and Mortality in Rich Countries: Who Owns the Null Hypothesis?
| format = PDF | accessdate= November 30, 2005 |archiveurl = http://web.archive.org/web/20060528042212/http://www.popcenter.umd.edu/events/rsf/papers/Jencks.pdf <!--None--> |archivedate = May 28, 2006}}
* United Nations Report on the World Social Situation 2005
*
* Accessed 2007-06-11.
* studies the trade-offs between earning income and enjoying leisure
*
* from the ]
*
* ] presentation based on '']''
* (] - January 2014).
* Asian Development Bank
* . ''].'' 23 January 2015.


{{DEFAULTSORT:Economic Inequality}} {{DEFAULTSORT:Economic Inequality}}
]
]
]
]
]
]
] ]
]
]
]
]
]
] ]
]

Latest revision as of 07:42, 2 December 2024

Distribution of income or wealth between different groups For the more general social form, see Social inequality. For other uses, see Inequality. "Rich and poor" redirects here. For other uses, see Rich and Poor.

Share of income of the top 1% for selected developed countries, 1975 to 2015
Differences in national income equality around the world as measured by the national Gini coefficient as of 2018. The Gini coefficient is a number between 0 and 100, where 0 corresponds with perfect equality (where everyone has the same income) and 100 corresponds with absolute inequality (where one person has all the income, and everyone else has zero income).
Global share of wealth by wealth group, Credit Suisse, 2021
Wealth disparity in major citiesSkid row tentsTents of the homeless on the sidewalk in Skid Row, Los Angelesa Beverly Hills mansionAn affluent house in Holmby Hills, Los Angeles, roughly 12 miles from downtown

Economic inequality is an umbrella term for a) income inequality or distribution of income (how the total sum of money paid to people is distributed among them), b) wealth inequality or distribution of wealth (how the total sum of wealth owned by people is distributed among the owners), and c) consumption inequality (how the total sum of money spent by people is distributed among the spenders). Each of these can be measured between two or more nations, within a single nation, or between and within sub-populations (such as within a low-income group, within a high-income group and between them, within an age group and between inter-generational groups, within a gender group and between them etc, either from one or from multiple nations).

Income inequality metrics are used for measuring income inequality, the Gini coefficient being a widely used one. Another type of measurement is the Inequality-adjusted Human Development Index, which is a statistic composite index that takes inequality into account. Important concepts of equality include equity, equality of outcome, and equality of opportunity.

Historically, there has been a long-run trend towards greater economic inequality over time. The exceptions to this during the modern era are the declines in economic inequality during the two World Wars and amid the creation of modern welfare states after World War II. Whereas globalization has reduced the inequality between nations, it has increased the inequality within the population in most nations. Income inequality between nations peaked in the 1970s, when world income was distributed bimodally into "rich" and "poor" countries. Since then, income levels across countries have been converging, with most people now living in middle-income countries. However, inequality within the population in most has risen significantly in the last 30 years, particularly among advanced countries.

Research has generally linked economic inequality to political and social instability, including revolution, democratic breakdown and civil conflict. Research suggests that greater inequality hinders economic growth and macroeconomic stability, and that land and human capital inequality reduce growth more than inequality of income. Inequality is at the center stage of economic policy debate across the globe, as government tax and spending policies have significant effects on income distribution. In advanced economies, taxes and transfers decrease income inequality by one-third, with most of this being achieved via public social spending (such as pensions and family benefits). While the "optimum" amount of economic inequality is widely debated, there is a near-universal belief that complete economic equality (Gini of zero) would be undesirable and unachieveable.

Measurements

Main articles: Income inequality metrics and List of countries by income equality

In 1820, the ratio between the income of the top and bottom 20 percent of the world's population was three to one. By 1991, it was eighty-six to one. A 2011 study titled "Divided we Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising" by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) sought to explain the causes for this rising inequality by investigating economic inequality in OECD countries; it concluded that the following factors played a role:

  • Changes in the structure of households can play an important role. Single-headed households in OECD countries have risen from an average of 15% in the late 1980s to 20% in the mid-2000s, resulting in higher inequality.
  • Assortative mating refers to the phenomenon of people marrying people with similar background, for example doctors marrying other doctors rather than nurses. OECD found out that 40% of couples where both partners work belonged to the same or neighbouring earnings deciles compared with 33% some 20 years before.
  • In the bottom percentiles, number of hours worked has decreased.
  • The main reason for increasing inequality seems to be the difference between the demand for and supply of skills.

The study made the following conclusions about the level of economic inequality:

  • Income inequality in OECD countries is at its highest level for the past half century. The ratio between the bottom 10% and the top 10% has increased from 1:7 to 1:9 in 25 years.
  • There are tentative signs of a possible convergence of inequality levels towards a common and higher average level across OECD countries.
  • With very few exceptions (France, Japan, and Spain), the wages of the 10% best-paid workers have risen relative to those of the 10% lowest paid.

A 2011 OECD study investigated economic inequality in Argentina, Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Russia, and South Africa. It concluded that key sources of inequality in these countries include "a large, persistent informal sector, widespread regional divides (e.g., urban-rural), gaps in access to education, and barriers to employment and career progression for women."

Countries by total wealth (2022)Countries by the inequality-adjusted Human Development Index.

A study by the World Institute for Development Economics Research at United Nations University reported that the richest 1% of adults alone owned 40% of global assets in the year 2000. The three richest people in the world possess more financial assets than the lowest 48 nations combined. The combined wealth of the "10 million dollar millionaires" grew to nearly $41 trillion in 2008.

Oxfam's 2021 report on global inequality said that the COVID-19 pandemic has increased economic inequality substantially; the wealthiest people across the globe were impacted the least by the pandemic and their fortunes recovered quickest, with billionaires seeing their wealth increase by $3.9 trillion, while at the same time the number of people living on less than $5.50 a day likely increased by 500 million. According to economist Joseph Stiglitz, the pandemic's "most significant outcome" will be rising economic inequality in the United States and between the developed and developing world. The 2024 Oxfam report found a significant increase in inequality as roughly five billion people have become poorer while at the same time the fortunes of the five richest individuals have doubled. The report warns that current trends are paving the way for the world's first trillionaire within a decade and global poverty eradication being postponed for 229 years.

Net personal wealth in the U.S. since 1962The average personal wealth of people in the top 1% is more than a thousand times that of people in bottom 50%.The logarithmic scale shows how wealth has increased for all percentile groups, though moreso for wealthier people.

According to PolitiFact, the top 400 richest Americans "have more wealth than half of all Americans combined." According to The New York Times on July 22, 2014, the "richest 1 percent in the United States now own more wealth than the bottom 90 percent". Inherited wealth may help explain why many Americans who have become rich may have had a "substantial head start". A 2017 report by the IPS said that three individuals, Jeff Bezos, Bill Gates and Warren Buffett, own as much wealth as the bottom half of the population, or 160 million people, and that the growing disparity between the wealthy and the poor has created a "moral crisis", noting that "we have not witnessed such extreme levels of concentrated wealth and power since the first gilded age a century ago." In 2016, the world's billionaires increased their combined global wealth to a record $6 trillion. In 2017, they increased their collective wealth to 8.9 trillion. In 2018, U.S. income inequality reached the highest level ever recorded by the Census Bureau.

The existing data and estimates suggest a large increase in international (and more generally inter-macroregional) components between 1820 and 1960. It might have slightly decreased since that time at the expense of increasing inequality within countries. The United Nations Development Programme in 2014 asserted that greater investments in social security, jobs, and laws that protect vulnerable populations are necessary to prevent widening income inequality.

There is a significant difference in the measured wealth distribution and the public's understanding of wealth distribution. Michael Norton of the Harvard Business School and Dan Ariely of the Department of Psychology at Duke University found this to be true in their research conducted in 2011. The actual wealth going to the top quintile in 2011 was around 84%, whereas the average amount of wealth that the general public estimated to go to the top quintile was around 58%.

According to a 2020 study, global earnings inequality has decreased substantially since 1970. During the 2000s and 2010s, the share of earnings by the world's poorest half doubled. Two researchers claim that global income inequality is decreasing due to strong economic growth in developing countries. According to a January 2020 report by the United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, economic inequality between states had declined, but intrastate inequality has increased for 70% of the world population over the period 1990–2015. In 2015, the OECD reported in 2015 that income inequality is higher than it has ever been within OECD member nations and is at increased levels in many emerging economies. According to a June 2015 report by the International Monetary Fund (IMF):

Widening income inequality is the defining challenge of our time. In advanced economies, the gap between the rich and poor is at its highest level in decades. Inequality trends have been more mixed in emerging markets and developing countries (EMDCs), with some countries experiencing declining inequality, but pervasive inequities in access to education, health care, and finance remain.

In October 2017, the IMF warned that inequality within nations, in spite of global inequality falling in recent decades, has risen so sharply that it threatens economic growth and could result in further political polarization. The Fund's Fiscal Monitor report said that "progressive taxation and transfers are key components of efficient fiscal redistribution." In October 2018 Oxfam published a Reducing Inequality Index which measured social spending, tax and workers' rights to show which countries were best at closing the gap between the rich and the poor.

The 2022 World Inequality Report, a four-year research project organized by the economists Lucas Chancel, Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez, and Gabriel Zucman, shows that "the world is marked by a very high level of income inequality and an extreme level of wealth inequality" and that these inequalities "seem to be about as great today as they were at the peak of western imperialism in the early 20th century." According to the report, the bottom half of the population owns 2% of global wealth, while the top 10% owns 76% of it. The top 1% owns 38%.

Wealth distribution within individual countries

Main articles: List of countries by wealth per adult § By country, and Wealth distribution

The wealth is calculated by various factors, for instance: liabilities, debts, exchange rates and their expected development, real estate prices, human resources, natural resources and technical advancements, etc.

Income distribution within individual countries

Main articles: List of countries by income equality and Income distribution
Countries' income inequality according to their most recent reported Gini index values as of 2018.

Income inequality is measured by Gini coefficient (expressed in percent %) that is a number between 0 and 1. Here 0 expresses perfect equality, meaning that everyone has the same income, whereas 1 represents perfect inequality, meaning that one person has all the income and others have none. A Gini index value above 50% is considered high; countries including Brazil, Colombia, South Africa, Botswana, and Honduras can be found in this category. A Gini index value of 30% or above is considered medium; countries including Vietnam, Mexico, Poland, the United States, Argentina, Russia and Uruguay can be found in this category. A Gini index value lower than 30% is considered low; countries including Austria, Germany, Denmark, Norway, Slovenia, Sweden, and Ukraine can be found in this category. In the low-income inequality category (below 30%) is a wide representation of countries previously being part of Soviet Union or its satellites, like Slovakia, Czech Republic, Ukraine and Hungary.

In 2012 the Gini index for income inequality for whole European Union was only 30.6%.

Income distribution can differ from wealth distribution within each country. The wealth inequality is also measured in Gini index. There the higher Gini index signify greater inequality within the wealth distribution in country, 0 means total wealth equality and 1 represents situation, where everyone has no wealth, except an individual that has everything.  For instance, countries like Denmark, Norway and Netherlands, all belonging to the last category (below 30%, low-income inequality) also have very high Gini index in wealth distribution, ranging from 70% up to 90%.

Consumption distribution within individual countries

Main article: Consumption distribution

In economics, the consumption distribution or consumption inequality is an alternative to the income distribution or wealth distribution for judging economic inequality, comparing levels of consumption rather than income or wealth. This is an important measure of inequality as the basic utility of the wealth or income is the expenditure. People experience the inequality directly in consumption, rather than income or wealth.

Factors proposed to affect economic inequality

There are various reasons for economic inequality within societies, including both global market functions (such as trade, development, and regulation) as well as social factors (including gender, race, and education). Recent growth in overall income inequality, at least within the OECD countries, has been driven mostly by increasing inequality in wages and salaries.

Economist Thomas Piketty argues that widening economic disparity is an inevitable phenomenon of free market capitalism when the rate of return of capital (r) is greater than the rate of growth of the economy (g). According to an IMF report in 2016, after reviewing four decades of neoliberalism, it had warned that certain neoliberal policies including privatization, public spending cuts, and deregulation, have resulted in "increased inequality" and are stunting economic growth globally.

Labour market

Main articles: Labour economics, Capitalism, Marxism, and Neoclassical economics

In modern market economies, if competition is imperfect; information unevenly distributed; opportunities to acquire education and skills unequal; market failure results. Many such imperfect conditions exist in virtually every market. According to Joseph Stiglitz this means that there is an enormous potential role for government to correct such market failures.

In the United States, real wages are flat over the past 40 years for occupations across income and education levels, e.g., auto mechanics, cashiers, doctors, and software engineers. However, stock ownership favors higher income and education levels, thereby resulting in disparate investment income.

Taxes

Main articles: Income tax and Progressive tax
Total effective tax rates (includes all taxes: federal+state income tax, sales tax, property tax, etc) for the richest Americans declined by 2018 to a level beneath that of the bottom 50% of earners, contributing to economic inequality. Analysis by economists Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman.

Another cause is the rate at which income is taxed coupled with the progressivity of the tax system. A progressive tax is a tax by which the tax rate increases as the taxable base amount increases. In a progressive tax system, the level of the top tax rate will often have a direct impact on the level of inequality within a society, either increasing it or decreasing it, provided that income does not change as a result of the change in tax regime. Additionally, steeper tax progressivity applied to social spending can result in a more equal distribution of income across the board. Tax credits such as the Earned Income Tax Credit in the US can also decrease income inequality. The difference between the Gini index for an income distribution before taxation and the Gini index after taxation is an indicator for the effects of such taxation.

Education

Main article: Education Ivy-Plus university admissions rates vary with the income of the students' parents, with the acceptance rate of the top 0.1% income percentile being almost twice as much as other students.A 1916 ad for a vocational school appealed to Americans' belief in the possibility of self-betterment, as well as threatening economic insecurity through lack of education and the consequences of downward mobility in the income inequality during the Industrial Revolution

An important factor in the creation of inequality is variation in individuals' access to education. Education, especially in an area where there is a high demand for workers, creates high wages for those with this education. However, increases in education first increase and then decrease growth as well as income inequality. As a result, those who are unable to afford an education, or choose not to pursue optional education, generally receive much lower wages. The justification for this is that a lack of education leads directly to lower incomes, and thus lower aggregate saving and investment. Conversely, quality education raises incomes and promotes growth because it helps to unleash the productive potential of the poor.

Access to education was in turn influenced by land inequalities. In the less industrialized parts of 19th century Europe, for example, landowners still held more political power than industrialists. These landowners did not benefit from educating their workers as much as industrialists did, since "educated workers have more incentives to migrate to urban, industrial areas than their less educated counterparts." Consequently, lower incentives to promote education in regions where land inequality was high led to lower levels of numeracy in these regions.

Economic liberalism, deregulation and decline of unions

Main articles: Economic liberalism, Deregulation, and Labor unions in the United States

John Schmitt and Ben Zipperer (2006) of the CEPR point to economic liberalism and the reduction of business regulation along with the decline of union membership as one of the causes of economic inequality. In an analysis of the effects of intensive Anglo-American liberal policies in comparison to continental European liberalism, where unions have remained strong, they concluded "The U.S. economic and social model is associated with substantial levels of social exclusion, including high levels of income inequality, high relative and absolute poverty rates, poor and unequal educational outcomes, poor health outcomes, and high rates of crime and incarceration. At the same time, the available evidence provides little support for the view that U.S.-style labor market flexibility dramatically improves labor-market outcomes. Despite popular prejudices to the contrary, the U.S. economy consistently affords a lower level of economic mobility than all the continental European countries for which data is available."

More recently, the International Monetary Fund has published studies which found that the decline of unionization in many advanced economies and the establishment of neoliberal economics have fueled rising income inequality.

Contrary to the proponents of neoliberalism, trickle-down economics have been proven to not be effective in resolving economic inequalities but have instead worsened it.

Technology

Main articles: Digital Revolution and Information Technology

The growth in importance of information technology has been credited with increasing income inequality. Technology has been called "the main driver of the recent increases in inequality" by Erik Brynjolfsson, of MIT. In arguing against this explanation, Jonathan Rothwell notes that if technological advancement is measured by high rates of invention, there is a negative correlation between it and inequality. Countries with high invention rates – "as measured by patent applications filed under the Patent Cooperation Treaty" – exhibit lower inequality than those with less. In one country, the United States, "salaries of engineers and software developers rarely reach" above $390,000/year (the lower limit for the top 1% earners).

Some researchers, such as Juliet B. Schor, highlight the role of for-profit online sharing economy platforms as an accelerator of income inequality and calls into question their supposed contribution in empowering outsiders of the labour market.

Taking the example of TaskRabbit, a labour service platform, she shows that a large proportion of providers already have a stable full-time job and participate part-time in the platform as an opportunity to increase their income by diversifying their activities outside employment, which tends to restrict the volume of work remaining for the minority of platform workers.

In addition, there is an important phenomenon of labour substitution as manual tasks traditionally performed by workers without a degree (or just a college degree) integrated into the labour market in the traditional economy sectors are now performed by workers with a high level of education (in 2013, 70% of TaskRabbit's workforce held a bachelor's degree, 20% a master's degree and 5% a PhD). The development of platforms, which are increasingly capturing demand for these manual services at the expense of non-platform companies, may therefore benefit mainly skilled workers who are offered more earning opportunities that can be used as supplemental or transitional work during periods of unemployment.

It has also been proposed that information technologies contribute to "winner take most" market concentration, reducing the need for labor across competing suppliers. Market concentration drives down labor's share of the GDP, increasing the wealth of capital and thereby exacerbating inequality.

Automation

Economists have linked automation to increases in economic inequality, as automation raises the returns to wealth and contributes to stagnating wages at the lower end of the wage distribution. Several economists have suggested that automation has increased income inequality by causing low skill jobs to be replaced with machines operated by technologically skilled workers, thereby reducing the demand for unskilled labor while increasing the demand for skilled labor.

Globalization

Main articles: Globalization and International inequality
"Elephant curve": Change in real income between 1988 and 2008 at various income percentiles of global income distribution.

Trade liberalization may shift economic inequality from a global to a domestic scale. When rich countries trade with poor countries, the low-skilled workers in the rich countries may see reduced wages as a result of the competition, while low-skilled workers in the poor countries may see increased wages. Trade economist Paul Krugman estimates that trade liberalisation has had a measurable effect on the rising inequality in the United States. He attributes this trend to increased trade with poor countries and the fragmentation of the means of production, resulting in low skilled jobs becoming more tradeable.

Anthropologist Jason Hickel contends that globalization and "structural adjustment" set off the "race to the bottom", a significant driver of surging global inequality. Another driver Hickel mentions is the debt system which advanced the need for structural adjustment in the first place.

Gender

Main article: Gender inequality
The gender gap in median earnings of full-time employees according to the OECD 2015

In many countries, there is a gender pay gap in favor of males in the labor market. Several factors other than discrimination contribute to this gap. On average, women are more likely than men to consider factors other than pay when looking for work and may be less willing to travel or relocate. Thomas Sowell, in his book Knowledge and Decisions, claims that this difference is due to women not taking jobs due to marriage or pregnancy. A U.S. Census's report stated that in US once other factors are accounted for there is still a difference in earnings between women and men. A study done on three post-soviet countries Armenia, Georgia, and Azerbaijan reveals that gender is one of the driving forces of income inequality, and being female has a significant negative effect on income when other factors are held equal. The results show more than 50% gender pay gap in all three countries. These findings are because usually employers tend to avoid hiring women because of possible maternity leave. Other reason for this can be occupational segregation, which implies that women are usually accumulated in lower-paid positions and sectors, such as social services and education.

Race

Main article: Social inequality

There is also a globally recognized disparity in the wealth, income, and economic welfare of people of different races. In many nations, data exists to suggest that members of certain racial demographics experience lower wages, fewer opportunities for career and educational advancement, and intergenerational wealth gaps. Studies have uncovered the emergence of what is called "ethnic capital", by which people belonging to a race that has experienced discrimination are born into a disadvantaged family from the beginning and therefore have less resources and opportunities at their disposal. The universal lack of education, technical and cognitive skills, and inheritable wealth within a particular race is often passed down between generations, compounding in effect to make escaping these racialized cycles of poverty increasingly difficult. Additionally, ethnic groups that experience significant disparities are often also minorities, at least in representation though often in number as well, in the nations where they experience the harshest disadvantage. As a result, they are often segregated either by government policy or social stratification, leading to ethnic communities that experience widespread gaps in wealth and aid.

Redlining intentionally excluded black Americans from accumulating intergenerational wealth. The effects of this exclusion on black Americans' health continue to play out daily, generations later, in the same communities. This is evident currently in the disproportionate effects that COVID-19 has had on the same communities which the HOLC redlined in the 1930s. Research published in September 2020 overlaid maps of the highly affected COVID-19 areas with the HOLC maps, showing that those areas marked "risky" to lenders because they contained minority residents were the same neighborhoods most affected by COVID-19. The Centers for Disease Control (CDC) looks at inequities in the social determinants of health like concentrated poverty and healthcare access that are interrelated and influence health outcomes with regard to COVID-19 as well as quality of life in general for minority groups. The CDC points to discrimination within health care, education, criminal justice, housing, and finance, direct results of systematically subversive tactics like redlining which led to chronic and toxic stress that shaped social and economic factors for minority groups, increasing their risk for COVID-19. Healthcare access is similarly limited by factors like a lack of public transportation, child care, and communication and language barriers which result from the spatial and economic isolation of minority communities from redlining. Educational, income, and wealth gaps that result from this isolation mean that minority groups' limited access to the job market may force them to remain in fields that have a higher risk of exposure to the virus, without options to take time off. Finally, a direct result of redlining is the overcrowding of minority groups into neighborhoods that do not boast adequate housing to sustain burgeoning populations, leading to crowded conditions that make prevention strategies for COVID-19 nearly impossible to implement.

As a general rule, races which have been historically and systematically colonized (typically indigenous ethnicities) continue to experience lower levels of financial stability in the present day. The global South is considered to be particularly victimized by this phenomenon, though the exact socioeconomic manifestations change across different regions.

Westernized Nations

While the progression of civil rights movements and justice reform has improved access to education and other economic opportunities in politically advanced nations, racial income and wealth disparity still exists. In the United States for example, African American populations are more likely to drop out of high school and college, are typically employed for fewer hours at lower wages, have lower than average intergenerational wealth, and are more likely to use welfare as young adults than their white counterparts. The racial wealth gap in the US has been maintained throughout history. In 1863, two years prior to emancipation from slavery, Black people owned 0.5 percent of the US national wealth, while in 2019 it is just over 1.5 percent.

Mexican-Americans, while suffering less debilitating socioeconomic factors than black Americans, experience deficiencies in the same areas when compared to whites and have not assimilated financially to the level of stability experienced by white Americans as a whole. These experiences are the effects of the measured disparity due to race in countries like the US, where studies show that in comparison to whites, blacks suffer from drastically lower levels of upward mobility, higher levels of downward mobility, and poverty that is more easily transmitted to offspring as a result of the disadvantage stemming from the era of slavery and post-slavery racism that has been passed through racial generations to the present. These are lasting financial inequalities that apply in varying magnitudes to most non-white populations in nations such as the US, the UK, France, Spain, Australia, etc.

Latin America

In the countries of the Caribbean, Central America, and South America, many ethnicities continue to deal with the effects of European colonization, and in general nonwhites tend to be noticeably poorer than whites in this region. In many countries with significant populations of indigenous races and those of Afro-descent (such as Mexico, Colombia, Chile, etc.) income levels can be roughly half as high as those experiences by white demographics, and this inequity is accompanied by systematically unequal access to education, career opportunities, and poverty relief. This region of the world, apart from urbanizing areas like Brazil and Costa Rica, continues to be understudied and often the racial disparity is denied by Latin Americans who consider themselves to be living in post-racial and post-colonial societies far removed from intense social and economic stratification despite the evidence to the contrary.

Africa

African countries, too, continue to deal with the effects of the Trans-Atlantic Slave Trade, which set back economic development as a whole for blacks of African citizenship more than any other region. The degree to which colonizers stratified their holdings on the continent on the basis of race has had a direct correlation in the magnitude of disparity experienced by nonwhites in the nations that eventually rose from their colonial status. Former French colonies, for example, see much higher rates of income inequality between whites and nonwhites as a result of the rigid hierarchy imposed by the French who lived in Africa at the time. Another example is found in South Africa, which, still reeling from the socioeconomic impacts of Apartheid, experiences some of the highest racial income and wealth inequality in all of Africa. In these and other countries like Nigeria, Zimbabwe, and Sierra Leone, movements of civil reform have initially led to improved access to financial advancement opportunities, but data shows that for nonwhites this progress is either stalling or erasing itself in the newest generation of blacks that seek education and improved transgenerational wealth. The economic status of one's parents continues to define and predict the financial futures of African and minority ethnic groups.

Asia

Asian regions and countries such as China, the Middle East, and Central Asia have been vastly understudied in terms of racial disparity, but even here the effects of Western colonization provide similar results to those found in other parts of the globe. Additionally, cultural and historical practices such as the caste system in India leave their marks as well. While the disparity is greatly improving in the case of India, there still exists social stratification between peoples of lighter and darker skin tones that cumulatively result in income and wealth inequality, manifesting in many of the same poverty traps seen elsewhere.

Economic development

A Kuznets curve
Main article: Kuznets curve

Economist Simon Kuznets argued that levels of economic inequality are in large part the result of stages of development. According to Kuznets, countries with low levels of development have relatively equal distributions of wealth. In the early stages, individual sectors or industries are developed first, which leads to an unequal distribution of income and wealth, resulting in growing inequality within a country. As the economy progresses and development takes place in more economic sectors, eventually attracting more workers, economic inequality decreases. Although the Kuznets curve described the development of inequality well at the time of its publication, there is now a growing number of critical voices questioning the link between inequality and development.

Wealth concentration

Main articles: Wealth concentration, Billionaire, and Oligarchy

Wealth concentration is the process by which, under certain conditions, newly created wealth concentrates in the possession of already-wealthy individuals or entities. Accordingly, those who already hold wealth have the means to invest in new sources of creating wealth or to otherwise leverage the accumulation of wealth, and thus they are the beneficiaries of the new wealth. Over time, wealth concentration can significantly contribute to the persistence of inequality within society. Thomas Piketty in his book Capital in the Twenty-First Century argues that the fundamental force for divergence is the usually greater return of capital (r) than economic growth (g), and that larger fortunes generate higher returns.

Rent seeking

Main article: Rent-seeking

Economist Joseph Stiglitz argues that rather than explaining concentrations of wealth and income, market forces should serve as a brake on such concentration, which may better be explained by the non-market force known as "rent-seeking". While the market will bid up compensation for rare and desired skills to reward wealth creation, greater productivity, etc., it will also prevent successful entrepreneurs from earning excess profits by fostering competition to cut prices, profits and large compensation. A better explainer of growing inequality, according to Stiglitz, is the use of political power generated by wealth by certain groups to shape government policies financially beneficial to them. This process, known to economists as rent-seeking, brings income not from creation of wealth but from "grabbing a larger share of the wealth that would otherwise have been produced without their effort".

Finance industry

Jamie Galbraith argues that countries with larger financial sectors have greater inequality, and the link is not an accident.

Global warming and climate change

Scaling the effect of wealth to the national level: richer (developed) countries emit more CO2 per person than poorer (developing) countries. Emissions are roughly proportional to GDP per person, though the rate of increase diminishes with average GDP/pp of about $10,000.Though total CO2 emissions (size of pie charts) differ substantially among high-emitting regions, the pattern of higher income classes emitting more than lower income classes is consistent across regions. The world's top 1% of emitters emit over 1000 times more than the bottom 1%.

A 2019 study published in PNAS found that global warming plays a role in increasing economic inequality between countries, boosting economic growth in developed countries while hampering such growth in developing nations of the Global South. The study says that 25% of gap between the developed world and the developing world can be attributed to global warming.

A 2020 report by Oxfam and the Stockholm Environment Institute says that the wealthiest 10% of the global population were responsible for more than half of global carbon dioxide emissions from 1990 to 2015, which increased by 60%. According to a 2020 report by the UNEP, overconsumption by the rich is a significant driver of the climate crisis, and the wealthiest 1% of the world's population are responsible for more than double the greenhouse gas emissions of the poorest 50% combined. Inger Andersen, in the foreword to the report, said "this elite will need to reduce their footprint by a factor of 30 to stay in line with the Paris Agreement targets." A 2022 report by Oxfam found that the business investments of the wealthiest 125 billionaires emit 393 million metric tonnes of greenhouse gas emissions annually.

In July 2023, a letter sent to the United Nations secretary general António Guterres and World Bank president Ajay Banga by a group of over 200 economists from 67 countries, including Jayati Ghosh, Joseph Stiglitz and Thomas Piketty, warned that if the sharp increase in economic inequality is not reversed, it will "entrench poverty and increase the risk of climate breakdown."

According to UNCTAD's World Investment Report, poorer countries would need $4 trillion per year to accomplish the SDGs by 2030, up from $1.5 trillion in 2015. $1.7 trillion in green energy investment is required each year, while the majority of green foreign direct investment continues to flow to established nations.

Politics

Joseph Stiglitz argues in The Price of Inequality (2012) that the economic inequality is inevitable and permanent, because it is caused by the great amount of political power the richest have. He wrote, "While there may be underlying economic forces at play, politics have shaped the market, and shaped it in ways that advantage the top at the expense of the rest."

Cognitive biases

Research has shown that biased decision-making does not alone explain a significant proportion of inequality, therefore inequality cannot be explained by cognitive biases of a specific sub-population, such as temporal discounting (i.e., not preferring immediate funds over larger future gains), overestimation (i.e. thinking you are better than you are at making decisions), over-placement (i.e. thinking you are better than the average person at making decisions), and extremeness aversion (i.e. taking the 'middle option' simply because it seems safer than the highest or lowest).

Mitigating factors

Social connectedness to people of higher income levels is a strong predictor of upward income mobility. However, data shows substantial social segregation correlating with economic income groups.

Countries with a left-leaning legislature generally have lower levels of inequality. Many factors constrain economic inequality – they may be divided into two classes: market driven, and government sponsored. The relative merits and effectiveness of each approach is a subject of debate:

Market forces outside of government intervention that can reduce economic inequality include:

  • propensity to spend: with rising wealth & income, a person may spend more. In an extreme example, if one person owned everything, they would immediately need to hire people to maintain their properties, thus reducing the wealth concentration. On the other hand, high-income persons have higher propensity to save. Robin Maialeh then shows that increasing economic wealth decreases propensity to spend and increases propensity to invest which consequently leads to even greater growth rate of already rich agents.

Typical government initiatives intended to reduce economic inequality include:

  • Public education: increasing the supply of skilled labor and reducing income inequality due to education differentials.
  • Progressive taxation: the rich are taxed proportionally more than the poor, reducing the amount of income inequality in society if the change in taxation does not cause changes in income.

Research shows that since 1300, the only periods with significant declines in wealth inequality in Europe were the Black Death and the two World Wars. Historian Walter Scheidel posits that, since the Stone Age, only extreme violence, catastrophes and upheaval in the form of total war, Communist revolutions, the French Revolution, pestilence and state collapse have significantly reduced inequality. He has stated that "only all-out thermonuclear war might fundamentally reset the existing distribution of resources" and that "peaceful policy reform may well prove unequal to the growing challenges ahead." However, Scheidel also stated that "There is certainly room for incremental change, that's what the example of Latin America shows in the past 15 years or so."

Policy responses intended to mitigate

A 2011 OECD study makes a number of suggestions to its member countries, including:

  • Well-targeted income-support policies.
  • Facilitation and encouragement of access to employment.
  • Better job-related training and education for the low-skilled (on-the-job training) would help to boost their productivity potential and future earnings.
  • Better access to formal education.

Progressive taxation reduces absolute income inequality when the higher rates on higher-income individuals are paid and not evaded, and transfer payments and social safety nets result in progressive government spending. Wage ratio legislation has also been proposed as a means of reducing income inequality. The OECD asserts that public spending is vital in reducing the ever-expanding wealth gap.

Deferred investment programs that increase stock ownership amongst lower income levels can supplement income to compensate wage stagnation.

The economists Emmanuel Saez and Thomas Piketty recommend much higher top marginal tax rates on the wealthy, up to 50 percent, 70 percent or even 90 percent. Ralph Nader, Jeffrey Sachs, the United Front Against Austerity, among others, call for a financial transaction tax (also known as the Robin Hood tax) to bolster the social safety net and the public sector.

The Economist wrote in December 2013: "A minimum wage, providing it is not set too high, could thus boost pay with no ill effects on jobs....America's federal minimum wage, at 38% of median income, is one of the rich world's lowest. Some studies find no harm to employment from federal or state minimum wages, others see a small one, but none finds any serious damage."

General limitations on and taxation of rent-seeking are popular across the political spectrum.

Public policy responses addressing causes and effects of income inequality in the US include: progressive tax incidence adjustments, strengthening social safety net provisions such as Aid to Families with Dependent Children, welfare, the food stamp program, Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid, organizing community interest groups, increasing and reforming higher education subsidies, increasing infrastructure spending, and placing limits on and taxing rent-seeking.

A 2017 study in the Journal of Political Economy by Daron Acemoglu, James Robinson and Thierry Verdier argues that American "cutthroat" capitalism and inequality gives rise to technology and innovation that more "cuddly" forms of capitalism cannot. As a result, "the diversity of institutions we observe among relatively advanced countries, ranging from greater inequality and risk-taking in the United States to the more egalitarian societies supported by a strong safety net in Scandinavia, rather than reflecting differences in fundamentals between the citizens of these societies, may emerge as a mutually self-reinforcing world equilibrium. If so, in this equilibrium, 'we cannot all be like the Scandinavians,' because Scandinavian capitalism depends in part on the knowledge spillovers created by the more cutthroat American capitalism." A 2012 working paper by the same authors, making similar arguments, was challenged by Lane Kenworthy, who posited that, among other things, the Nordic countries are consistently ranked as some of the world's most innovative countries by the World Economic Forum's Global Competitiveness Index, with Sweden ranking as the most innovative nation, followed by Finland, for 2012–2013; the U.S. ranked sixth.

There are however global initiative like the United Nations Sustainable Development Goal 10 which aims to garner international efforts in reducing economic inequality considerably by 2030.

Effects

Main article: Effects of economic inequality

A lot of research has been done about the effects of economic inequality on different aspects in society:

  • Health: For long time the higher material living standards lead to longer life, as those people were able to get enough food, water and access to warmth. British researchers Richard G. Wilkinson and Kate Pickett have found higher rates of health and social problems (obesity, mental illness, homicides, teenage births, incarceration, child conflict, drug use) in countries and states with higher inequality. Their research included 24 developed countries, including most U.S. states, and found that in the more developed countries, such as Finland and Japan, the heath issues are much lower than in states with rather higher inequality rates, such as Utah and New Hampshire. Some studies link a surge in "deaths of despair", suicide, drug overdoses and alcohol related deaths, to widening income inequality. Conversely, other research did not find these effects or concluded that research suffered from issues of confounding variables.
  • Social goods: British researchers Richard G. Wilkinson and Kate Pickett have found lower rates of social goods (life expectancy by country, educational performance, trust among strangers, women's status, social mobility, even numbers of patents issued) in countries and states with higher inequality.
  • Social cohesion: Research has shown an inverse link between income inequality and social cohesion. In more equal societies, people are much more likely to trust each other, measures of social capital (the benefits of goodwill, fellowship, mutual sympathy and social connectedness among groups who make up a social units) suggest greater community involvement.
  • Happiness: According to the 2019 World Happiness Report, increasing socioeconomic inequality, along with rising healthcare costs, surging addiction rates, and an unhealthy work–life balance, are causes of unhappiness around the world.
  • Crime: The cross national research shows that in societies with less economic inequality the homicide rates are consistently lower. A 2016 study finds that interregional inequality increases terrorism. Other research has argued inequality has little effect on crime rates.
  • Welfare: Studies have found evidence that in societies where inequality is lower, population-wide satisfaction and happiness tend to be higher.
  • Poverty: Study made by Jared Bernstein and Elise Gould suggest, that the poverty in the United States could have been reduced by the lowering of economic inequality for the past few decades.
  • Debt: Income inequality has been the driving factor in the growing household debt, as high earners bid up the price of real estate and middle income earners go deeper into debt trying to maintain what once was a middle class lifestyle.
  • Economic growth: A 2016 meta-analysis found that "the effect of inequality on growth is negative and more pronounced in less developed countries than in rich countries", though the average impact on growth was not significant. The study also found that wealth inequality is more pernicious to growth than income inequality.
  • Civic participation: Higher income inequality led to less of all forms of social, cultural, and civic participation among the less wealthy.
  • Political instability: Studies indicate that economic inequality leads to greater political instability, including an increased risk of democratic breakdown and civil conflict. A significant impact of inequality on civil war probability has been found through anthropometric methods.
  • Political party responses: One study finds that economic inequality prompts attempts by left-leaning politicians to pursue redistributive policies while right-leaning politicians seek to repress the redistributive policies.

Perspectives

Socialist perspectives

Socialists attribute the vast disparities in wealth to the private ownership of the means of production by a class of owners, creating a situation where a small portion of the population lives off unearned property income by virtue of ownership titles in capital equipment, financial assets and corporate stock. By contrast, the vast majority of the population is dependent on income in the form of a wage or salary. In order to rectify this situation, socialists argue that the means of production should be socially owned so that income differentials would be reflective of individual contributions to the social product.

Marxian economics attributes rising inequality to job automation and capital deepening within capitalism. The process of job automation conflicts with the capitalist property form and its attendant system of wage labor. In this analysis, capitalist firms increasingly substitute capital equipment for labor inputs (workers) under competitive pressure to reduce costs and maximize profits. Over the long term, this trend increases the organic composition of capital, meaning that less workers are required in proportion to capital inputs, increasing unemployment (the "reserve army of labour"). This process exerts a downward pressure on wages. The substitution of capital equipment for labor (mechanization and automation) raises the productivity of each worker, resulting in a situation of relatively stagnant wages for the working class amidst rising levels of property income for the capitalist class.

Marxist socialists ultimately predict the emergence of a communist society based on the common ownership of the means of production, where each individual citizen would have free access to the articles of consumption (From each according to his ability, to each according to his need). According to Marxist philosophy, equality in the sense of free access is essential for freeing individuals from dependent relationships, thereby allowing them to transcend alienation.

Meritocracy

Meritocracy favors an eventual society where an individual's success is a direct function of his merit, or contribution. Economic inequality would be a natural consequence of the wide range in individual skill, talent and effort in human population. David Landes stated that the progression of Western economic development that led to the Industrial Revolution was facilitated by men advancing through their own merit rather than because of family or political connections.

Liberal perspectives

Most modern social liberals, including centrist or left-of-center political groups, believe that the capitalist economic system should be fundamentally preserved, but the status quo regarding the income gap must be reformed. Social liberals favor a capitalist system with active Keynesian macroeconomic policies and progressive taxation (to even out differences in income inequality). Research indicates that people who hold liberal beliefs tend to see greater income inequality as morally wrong.

However, contemporary classical liberals and libertarians generally do not take a stance on wealth inequality, but believe in equality under the law regardless of whether it leads to unequal wealth distribution. In 1966 Ludwig von Mises, a prominent figure in the Austrian School of economic thought, explains:

The liberal champions of equality under the law were fully aware of the fact that men are born unequal and that it is precisely their inequality that generates social cooperation and civilization. Equality under the law was in their opinion not designed to correct the inexorable facts of the universe and to make natural inequality disappear. It was, on the contrary, the device to secure for the whole of mankind the maximum of benefits it can derive from it. Henceforth no man-made institutions should prevent a man from attaining that station in which he can best serve his fellow citizens.

Robert Nozick argued that government redistributes wealth by force (usually in the form of taxation), and that the ideal moral society would be one where all individuals are free from force. However, Nozick recognized that some modern economic inequalities were the result of forceful taking of property, and a certain amount of redistribution would be justified to compensate for this force but not because of the inequalities themselves. John Rawls argued in A Theory of Justice that inequalities in the distribution of wealth are only justified when they improve society as a whole, including the poorest members. Rawls does not discuss the full implications of his theory of justice. Some see Rawls's argument as a justification for capitalism since even the poorest members of society theoretically benefit from increased innovations under capitalism; others believe only a strong welfare state can satisfy Rawls's theory of justice.

Classical liberal Milton Friedman believed that if government action is taken in pursuit of economic equality then political freedom would suffer. In a famous quote, he said:

A society that puts equality before freedom will get neither. A society that puts freedom before equality will get a high degree of both.

Economist Tyler Cowen has argued that though income inequality has increased within nations, globally it has fallen over the 20 years leading up to 2014. He argues that though income inequality may make individual nations worse off, overall, the world has improved as global inequality has been reduced.

Social justice arguments

Patrick Diamond and Anthony Giddens (professors of Economics and Sociology, respectively) hold that 'pure meritocracy is incoherent because, without redistribution, one generation's successful individuals would become the next generation's embedded caste, hoarding the wealth they had accumulated'.

They also state that social justice requires redistribution of high incomes and large concentrations of wealth in a way that spreads it more widely, in order to "recognize the contribution made by all sections of the community to building the nation's wealth." (Patrick Diamond and Anthony Giddens, June 27, 2005, New Statesman)

Pope Francis stated in his Evangelii gaudium, that "as long as the problems of the poor are not radically resolved by rejecting the absolute autonomy of markets and financial speculation and by attacking the structural causes of inequality, no solution will be found for the world's problems or, for that matter, to any problems." He later declared that "inequality is the root of social evil."

When income inequality is low, aggregate demand will be relatively high, because more people who want ordinary consumer goods and services will be able to afford them, while the labor force will not be as relatively monopolized by the wealthy.

Effects on social welfare

In most western democracies, the desire to eliminate or reduce economic inequality is generally associated with the political left. One practical argument in favor of reduction is the idea that economic inequality reduces social cohesion and increases social unrest, thereby weakening the society. There is evidence that this is true (see inequity aversion) and it is intuitive, at least for small face-to-face groups of people. Alberto Alesina, Rafael Di Tella, and Robert MacCulloch find that inequality negatively affects happiness in Europe but not in the United States.

It has also been argued that economic inequality invariably translates to political inequality, which further aggravates the problem. Even in cases where an increase in economic inequality makes nobody economically poorer, an increased inequality of resources is disadvantageous, as increased economic inequality can lead to a power shift due to an increased inequality in the ability to participate in democratic processes. According to Paul and Moser, countries with high income inequality and poor unemployment protections experience worse mental health outcomes among the unemployed.

Capabilities approach

Further information: Capability approach

The capabilities approach – sometimes called the human development approach – looks at income inequality and poverty as form of "capability deprivation". Unlike neoliberalism, which "defines well-being as utility maximization", economic growth and income are considered a means to an end rather than the end itself. Its goal is to "wid people's choices and the level of their achieved well-being" through increasing functioning (the things a person values doing), capabilities (the freedom to enjoy functionings) and agency (the ability to pursue valued goals).

When a person's capabilities are lowered, they are in some way deprived of earning as much income as they would otherwise. An old, ill man cannot earn as much as a healthy young man; gender roles and customs may prevent a woman from receiving an education or working outside the home. There may be an epidemic that causes widespread panic, or there could be rampant violence in the area that prevents people from going to work for fear of their lives. As a result, income inequality increases, and it becomes more difficult to reduce the gap without additional aid.

Societal acceptance

A 2022 study published in Perspectives on Psychological Science found that in countries where neoliberal institutions have significant influence over policies, the psychology of those population are shaped to have both a higher tolerance of large levels of income inequality, and prefer it over more egalitarian outcomes.

Arguments that economic inequality is not a problem

The majority of researchers who analyze economic inequality argue that today's levels are problematic and deserve some mitigation. There are however, some who disagree, and feel that current levels of inequality are necessary because it encourages individuals to gain useful skills and take risks, thereby encouraging growth and innovation, which are necessary for progress. Some have also argued that economic inequality is a natural and fair outcome in market economies, in which the rewards are distributed based on different economic contributions because individuals have different attitudes and talents. Many who feel that economic inequality is not a significant issue are associated with conservative or libertarian think tanks funded by corporations and the wealthy like The Heritage Foundation, the Manhattan Institute, the Cato Institute or the American Enterprise Institute, who may also feel that policies which would reduce inequality are direct attacks on their favored version of capitalism, laissez-faire capitalism. In addition, some feel that economic inequality has not actually increased significantly.

See also

References

  1. ^ "GINI index (World Bank estimate) | Data". data.worldbank.org. Retrieved July 23, 2020.
  2. Ventura, Luca (June 6, 2023). "World Wealth Distribution And Income Inequality 2022". Global Finance Magazine.
  3. Trapeznikova, Ija (2019). "Measuring income inequality". IZA World of Labor. doi:10.15185/izawol.462.
  4. Human Development Reports. Inequality-adjusted Human Development Index (IHDI) Archived July 12, 2019, at the Wayback Machine. United Nations Development Programme. Retrieved: March 3, 2019.
  5. Alfani, Guido (2023). As Gods Among Men: A History of the Rich in the West. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-22712-2.
  6. ^ "Introduction to Inequality". IMF. Retrieved May 9, 2022.
  7. ^ Bourguignon, François (2015). The Globalization of Inequality. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0691160528. Retrieved August 19, 2017.
  8. ^ Hung, Ho-Fung (2021). "Recent Trends in Global Economic Inequality". Annual Review of Sociology. 47 (1): 349–367. doi:10.1146/annurev-soc-090320-105810. ISSN 0360-0572. S2CID 235574406.
  9. ^ Flaherty, Thomas M.; Rogowski, Ronald (2021). "Rising Inequality As a Threat to the Liberal International Order". International Organization. 75 (2): 495–523. doi:10.1017/S0020818321000163. ISSN 0020-8183.
  10. "Parametric estimations of the world distribution of income". January 22, 2010.
  11. MacCulloch, Robert (2005). "Income Inequality and the Taste for Revolution". The Journal of Law and Economics. 48 (1): 93–123. doi:10.1086/426881. JSTOR 10.1086/426881. S2CID 154993058.
  12. ^ Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James A. (2005). Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511510809. ISBN 978-0521855266.
  13. ^ Cederman, Lars-Erik; Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede; Buhaug, Halvard (2013). Inequality, Grievances, and Civil War. Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9781139084161. ISBN 978-1107017429.
  14. ^ Neves, Pedro Cunha; Afonso, Óscar; Silva, Sandra Tavares (2016). "A Meta-Analytic Reassessment of the Effects of Inequality on Growth". World Development. 78: 386–400. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.10.038.
  15. ^ Peterson, E. Wesley F. (December 2017). "Is Economic Inequality Really a Problem? A Review of the Arguments". Social Sciences. 6 (4): 147. doi:10.3390/socsci6040147. ISSN 2076-0760.
  16. Hunt, Michael (2004). The World Transformed: 1945 to the Present. Boston: Bedford/St. Martin's. pp. 442. ISBN 978-0312245832.
  17. ^ Gurría, Angel (December 5, 2011). Press Release for Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising (Report). OECD. doi:10.1787/9789264119536-en. ISBN 9789264111639. Retrieved December 16, 2011.
  18. ^ Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising. OECD. 2011. doi:10.1787/9789264119536-en. ISBN 978-9264119536.
  19. "Stock quotes, financial tools, news and analysis". MSN Money. Archived from the original on September 5, 2011. Retrieved July 24, 2010.
  20. "Growth of millionaires in India fastest in world" Archived June 23, 2013, at the Wayback Machine. Thaindian News. June 25, 2008.
  21. Clifford, Catherine (January 26, 2021). "The '1%' are the main drivers of climate change, but it hits the poor the hardest: Oxfam report". CNBC. Retrieved February 14, 2021.
  22. Joseph, Stiglitz (March 1, 2022). "COVID Has Made Global Inequality Much Worse". Scientific American. Retrieved August 3, 2022.
  23. Neate, Rupert (January 14, 2024). "World's five richest men double their money as poorest get poorer". The Guardian. Retrieved January 15, 2024.
  24. ^ "Evolution of wealth indicators, USA, 1913–2019". WID.world. World Inequality Database. 2022. Archived from the original on July 5, 2023. Retrieved September 6, 2023.
  25. Kertscher, Tom; Borowski, Greg (March 10, 2011). "The Truth-O-Meter Says: True – Michael Moore says 400 Americans have more wealth than half of all Americans combined". PolitiFact. Retrieved August 11, 2013.
  26. Moore, Michael (March 6, 2011). "America Is Not Broke". Huffington Post. Retrieved August 11, 2013.
  27. Moore, Michael (March 7, 2011). "The Forbes 400 vs. Everybody Else". michaelmoore.com. Archived from the original on March 9, 2011. Retrieved August 11, 2013.
  28. Pepitone, Julianne (September 22, 2010). "Forbes 400: The super-rich get richer". CNN. Retrieved August 11, 2013.
  29. Kristof, Nicholas (July 22, 2014). "An Idiot's Guide to Inequality". The New York Times. Retrieved July 22, 2014.
  30. Bruenig, Matt (March 24, 2014). "You call this a meritocracy? How rich inheritance is poisoning the American economy". Salon. Retrieved August 24, 2014.
  31. "Inequality – Inherited wealth". The Economist. March 18, 2014. Retrieved August 24, 2014.
  32. Neate, Rupert (November 8, 2017). "Bill Gates, Jeff Bezos and Warren Buffett are wealthier than poorest half of US". The Guardian. Retrieved November 9, 2017.
  33. Taylor, Matt (November 9, 2017). "The Paradise Papers Are Just a Glimpse at the Unreal Wealth Gap". Vice. Retrieved November 10, 2017.
  34. Neate, Rupert (October 26, 2017). "World's witnessing a new Gilded Age as billionaires' wealth swells to $6tn". The Guardian. Retrieved October 27, 2017.
  35. Neate, Rupert (October 26, 2018). "World's billionaires became 20% richer in 2017, report reveals". The Guardian. Retrieved November 5, 2018.
  36. Telford, Taylor (September 26, 2019). "Income inequality in America is the highest it's been since census started tracking it, data shows". The Washington Post. Retrieved September 30, 2019.
  37. Novotný, Josef (2007). "On the measurement of regional inequality: Does spatial dimension of income inequality matter?". The Annals of Regional Science. 41 (3): 563–580. Bibcode:2007ARegS..41..563N. doi:10.1007/s00168-007-0113-y. S2CID 51753883.
  38. Mark Anderson (July 24, 2014). Jobs and social security needed as income inequality widens, UNDP warn. The Guardian. Retrieved July 24, 2014.
  39. Norton, Michael I.; Ariely, Dan (2011). "Building a Better America – One Wealth Quintile at a Time". Perspectives on Psychological Science. 6 (1): 9–12. doi:10.1177/1745691610393524. PMID 26162108. S2CID 2013655.
  40. Hammar, Olle; Waldenström, Daniel (2020). "Global Earnings Inequality, 1970–2018". The Economic Journal. 130 (632): 2526–2545. doi:10.1093/ej/ueaa109. S2CID 157907204.
  41. Hellebrandt, Tomáš; Mauro, Paolo (2015). The Future of Worldwide Income Distribution. Peterson Institute for International Economics.
  42. "Rising inequality affecting more than two-thirds of the globe, but it's not inevitable: new UN report". UN News. January 21, 2020. Retrieved September 6, 2020.
  43. Improving job quality and reducing gender gaps are essential to tackling growing inequality. OECD, May 21, 2015.
  44. Era Dabla-Norris; Kalpana Kochhar; Nujin Suphaphiphat; Frantisek Ricka; Evridiki Tsounta (June 15, 2015). Causes and Consequences of Income Inequality : A Global Perspective. International Monetary Fund. Retrieved June 16, 2015.
  45. Dunsmuir, Lindsay (October 11, 2017). "IMF calls for fiscal policies that tackle rising inequality". Reuters. Retrieved October 30, 2017.
  46. Lawson, Max; Martin, Matthew (October 9, 2018). "The Commitment to Reducing Inequality Index 2018". Oxfam. Retrieved November 13, 2018.
  47. Kaplan, Juliana; Kiersz, Andy (December 7, 2021). "A huge study of 20 years of global wealth demolishes the myth of 'trickle-down' and shows the rich are taking most of the gains for themselves". Business Insider. Retrieved December 8, 2021.
  48. Elliott, Larry (December 7, 2021). "Global inequality 'as marked as it was at peak of western imperialism'". The Guardian. Retrieved December 8, 2021.
  49. "World Inequality Report 2022". Retrieved December 8, 2021.
  50. "Country Comparison: Distribution of family income – Gini index". The World Factbook. CIA. Archived from the original on June 4, 2011. Retrieved May 8, 2017.
  51. OECD Framework for Statistics on the Distribution of Household Income, Consumption and Wealth. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. 2013 – via OECD iLibrary.
  52. Attanasio, Orazio P.; Pistaferri, Luigi (April 2016). "Consumption Inequality" (PDF). Journal of Economic Perspectives. 30 (2): 3–28. doi:10.1257/jep.30.2.3.
  53. "Consumption Inequality: What's in Your Shopping Basket? | JPMorgan Chase Institute". www.jpmorganchase.com.
  54. Neckerman, Kathryn M.; Torche, Florencia (July 18, 2007). "Inequality: Causes and Consequences". Annual Review of Sociology. 33 (1): 335–357. doi:10.1146/annurev.soc.33.040406.131755. ISSN 0360-0572.
  55. Piketty, Thomas (2014). Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Belknap Press. ISBN 067443000X p. 571
  56. Stone, Jon (May 27, 2016). "Neoliberalism is increasing inequality and stunting economic growth, the IMF says". The Independent. Retrieved August 20, 2023.
  57. Ostry, Jonathan D.; Loungani, Prakash; Furceri, Davide (June 2016). "Neoliberalism: Oversold?". Finance & Development. International Monetary Fund. Retrieved August 20, 2023.
  58. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future (Kindle ed.). Norton. p. 34. ISBN 9780393088694.
  59. ^ Kausik, B. N. (May 3, 2022). "Income Inequality, Cause and Cure". Challenge. 65 (3–4): 93–105. arXiv:2201.10726. doi:10.1080/05775132.2022.2046883. ISSN 0577-5132. S2CID 246285783.
  60. Parker, Kim; Fry, Richard (March 25, 2020). "More than half of U.S. households have some investment in the stock market". Pew Research Center. Retrieved April 21, 2022.
  61. Picchi, Aimee (October 17, 2019). "America's richest 400 families now pay a lower tax rate than the middle class". CBS News. Archived from the original on May 11, 2024. (Chart labeled "Effective tax rates by income".) Analysis by economists Emmanuel Saez and Gabriel Zucman.
  62. Britannica Concise Encyclopedia: Tax levied at a rate that increases as the quantity subject to taxation increases.
  63. Princeton University WordNet: (n) progressive tax (any tax in which the rate increases as the amount subject to taxation increases)
  64. Alesina, Alberto; Dani Rodrick (May 1994). "Distributive Politics and Economic Growth". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 109 (2): 465–490. doi:10.2307/2118470. JSTOR 2118470.
  65. Hatch, Megan E.; Rigby, Elizabeth (2015). "Laboratories of (In)equality? Redistributive Policy and Income Inequality in the American States". Policy Studies Journal. 43 (2): 163–187. doi:10.1111/psj.12094.
  66. Shlomo Yitzhaki (1998). "More than a Dozen Alternative Ways of Spelling Gini" (PDF). Economic Inequality. 8: 13–30.
  67. Chetty, Raj; Deming, David J.; Friedman, John N. (July 2023). "Diversifying Society's Leaders? The Determinants and Consequences of Admission to Highly Selective Colleges" (PDF). Opportunity Insights. p. 2. Archived (PDF) from the original on July 31, 2023. Figure 3. "Ivy-Plus" refers to Ivy League schools plus others with similar prestige, rankings or selectivity.
  68. Becker, Gary S.; Murphy, Kevin M. (May 2007). "The Upside of Income Inequality". The America. Archived from the original on January 2, 2014. Retrieved January 8, 2014.
  69. Bosworth, Barry; Burtless, Gary; Steuerle, C. Eugene (December 1999). Lifetime Earnings Patterns, the Distribution of Future Social Security Benefits, and the Impact of Pension Reform (PDF) (report no. CRR WP 1999-06). Chestnut Hill, MA: Center for Retirement Research at Boston College. p. 43. Archived from the original (PDF) on July 19, 2010. Retrieved October 1, 2012.
  70. Shealy, Craig N. (November 1, 2009). "An Interview With Education for Sustainable Development "Young Voices": Beliefs and Values From the Next Generation of ESD Leaders". Beliefs and Values. 1 (2): 135–141. doi:10.1891/1942-0617.1.2.135 (inactive December 2, 2024). ISSN 1942-0617.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of December 2024 (link)
  71. ^ Baten, Jörg; Hippe, Ralph (2017). "Geography, land inequality and regional numeracy in Europe in historical perspective". Journal of Economic Growth.
  72. Schmitt, John and Ben Zipperer. 2006. "Is the U.S. a Good Model for Reducing Social Exclusion in Europe?" CEPR
  73. Michael Hiltzik (March 25, 2015). IMF agrees: Decline of union power has increased income inequality. Los Angeles Times. Retrieved March 26, 2015.
  74. IMF: The last generation of economic policies may have been a complete failure. Business Insider. May 2016.
  75. Srikanth, Anagha (December 17, 2020). "Huge new study shows trickle-down economics makes inequality worse, researchers say". The Hill. Retrieved August 20, 2023.
  76. Basu, Kaushik (January 6, 2016). "Is technology making inequality worse?". World Economic Forum. Retrieved November 17, 2017.
  77. Rotman, David (October 21, 2014). "Technology and Inequality". MIT Technology Review. Retrieved November 17, 2017.
  78. Rothwell, Jonathan (November 17, 2017). "Myths of the 1 Percent: What's Putting People at the Top". The New York Times. The New York Times. Retrieved November 17, 2017.
  79. Schor, Juliet B. (February 10, 2017). "Does the sharing economy increase inequality within the eighty percent?: findings from a qualitative study of platform providers". Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society. 10 (2): 263–279. doi:10.1093/cjres/rsw047. ISSN 1752-1378.
  80. Newton, Casey (May 23, 2013). "Temping fate: can TaskRabbit go from side gigs to real jobs?". The Verge. Retrieved April 30, 2021.
  81. Autor, David; Dorn, David; Katz, Lawrence F; Patterson, Christina; Van Reenen, John (May 1, 2020). "The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms*". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 135 (2): 645–709. doi:10.1093/qje/qjaa004. ISSN 0033-5533.
  82. Moll, Benjamin; Rachel, Lukasz; Restrepo, Pascual (2022). "Uneven Growth: Automation's Impact on Income and Wealth Inequality". Econometrica. 90 (6): 2645–2683. doi:10.3982/ECTA19417. ISSN 0012-9682.
  83. "SOF/Heyman | The Society of Fellows and Heyman Center for the Humanities". SOF/Heyman.
  84. "Economic Focus". The Economist. London. April 19, 2008. p. 81.
  85. Slaughter, Matthew J.; Swagel, Phillip (September 1997). "Does Globalization Lower Wages and Export Jobs?". Economic Issues. 11. International Monetary Fund. Retrieved June 18, 2022.
  86. Hickel, Jason (2018). The Divide: A Brief Guide to Global Inequality and its Solutions. Windmill Books. pp. 175–176. ISBN 978-1786090034.
  87. OECD. OECD Employment Outlook 2008 – Statistical Annex Archived December 6, 2008, at the Wayback Machine. OECD, Paris, 2008, p. 358.
  88. "Are Women Earning More Than Men?". Forbes. May 12, 2006. Archived from the original on December 10, 2008.
  89. Lukas, Carrie (April 3, 2007). "A Bargain At 77 Cents To a Dollar". The Washington Post. Retrieved May 3, 2010.
  90. Weinberg, Daniel H (May 2004). "Evidence From Census 2000 About Earnings by Detailed Occupation for Men and Women" (PDF). Retrieved February 21, 2017.
  91. Habibov, Nazim (2012). "Income inequality and its driving forces in transitional countries: evidence from Armenia, Azerbaijan and Georgia". Journal of Comparative Social Welfare. 28 (3): 209–211. doi:10.1080/17486831.2012.749504. S2CID 153681101.
  92. ^ Brady, David; Burton, Linda M., eds. (April 5, 2017). "The Oxford Handbook of the Social Science of Poverty". Oxford Handbooks Online. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199914050.001.0001. ISBN 978-0199914050.
  93. Becker, Gary S.; Tomes, Nigel (December 1979). "An Equilibrium Theory of the Distribution of Income and Intergenerational Mobility". Journal of Political Economy. 87 (6): 1153–1189. doi:10.1086/260831. ISSN 0022-3808. S2CID 153939481.
  94. ^ Borjas, George (July 1991). Ethnic Capital and Intergenerational Mobility (Report). Cambridge, MA. doi:10.3386/w3788.
  95. Economic Mobility Project: An Initiative of the Pew Charitable Trusts. 2010.
  96. "Mapping Inequality." Digital Scholarship Lab, dsl.richmond.edu/panorama/redlining/.
  97. Richardson, Jason; Mitchell, Bruce C.; Meier, Helen C.S.; Lynch, Emily; Edlebi, Jad (September 10, 2020). "Redlining and Neighborhood Health". NCRC.
  98. Myers, JoAnne (2020). The good citizen: the markers of privilege in America. doi:10.4324/9781351006705. ISBN 978-1-351-00669-9. OCLC 1111653987. S2CID 211349002.
  99. Badger, Emily (May 10, 2019). "Can the Racial Wealth Gap Be Closed Without Speaking of Race?". The New York Times.
  100. Danaei, Goodarz; Rimm, Eric B.; Oza, Shefali; Kulkarni, Sandeep C.; Murray, Christopher J. L.; Ezzati, Majid (2010). "The Promise of Prevention: The Effects of Four Preventable Risk Factors on National Life Expectancy and Life Expectancy Disparities by Race and County in the United States". PLOS Medicine. 7 (3): e1000248. doi:10.1371/journal.pmed.1000248. PMC 2843596. PMID 20351772.
  101. Howell, Brittani (June 24, 2020). "How Redlining, Racism Harm Black Americans' Health". WYSO.
  102. CDC (April 30, 2020). "Communities, Schools, Workplaces, & Events". Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. Archived from the original on August 5, 2020. Retrieved December 9, 2020.
  103. Bloome, D.; Western, B. (December 1, 2011). "Cohort Change and Racial Differences in Educational and Income Mobility". Social Forces. 90 (2): 375–395. doi:10.1093/sf/sor002. ISSN 0037-7732. S2CID 16514651.
  104. Herring, Cedric; Conley, Dalton (March 2000). "Being Black, Living in the Red: Race, Wealth, and Social Policy in America". Contemporary Sociology. 29 (2): 349. doi:10.2307/2654395. ISSN 0094-3061. JSTOR 2654395.
  105. "Why the racial wealth gap persists, more than 150 years after emancipation". The Washington Post. Retrieved July 5, 2024.
  106. Vallejo, Jody Agius (December 2010). "Generations of exclusion: Mexican Americans, assimilation and race". Latino Studies. 8 (4): 572–574. doi:10.1057/lst.2010.45. ISSN 1476-3435. S2CID 143814091.
  107. ^ Bowles, Samuel; Gintis, Herbert (August 1, 2002). "The Inheritance of Inequality". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 16 (3): 3–30. doi:10.1257/089533002760278686. ISSN 0895-3309.
  108. Bhattacharya, Debopam; Mazumder, Bhashkar (2010). "A Nonparametric Analysis of Black-White Differences in Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States". Quantitative Economics. 2 (3): 335–379. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1066819. hdl:10419/150324. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 55109224.
  109. Hertz, Tom (December 31, 2009), Bowles, Samuel; Gintis, Herbert; Osborne Groves, Melissa (eds.), "Chapter Five. Rags, Riches, and Race The Intergenerational Economic Mobility of Black and White Families in the United States", Unequal Chances, Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 165–191, doi:10.1515/9781400835492.165, ISBN 978-1400835492
  110. de Ferranti, David; Perry, Guillermo E.; Ferreira, Francisco; Walton, Michael (2004). Inequality in Latin America. doi:10.1596/0-8213-5665-8. ISBN 978-0821356654.
  111. Bossuroy, Thomas; Cogneau, Denis (April 18, 2013). "Social Mobility in Five African Countries". Review of Income and Wealth. 59: S84 – S110. doi:10.1111/roiw.12037. hdl:10.1111/roiw.12037. ISSN 0034-6586. S2CID 154317227.
  112. Peil, Margaret (January 1990). "Intergenerational mobility through education: Nigeria, Sierra Leone and Zimbabwe". International Journal of Educational Development. 10 (4): 311–325. doi:10.1016/s0738-0593(09)90008-6. ISSN 0738-0593.
  113. Hnatkovska, Viktoria; Lahiri, Amartya; Paul, Sourabh B. (2013). "Breaking the Caste Barrier: Intergenerational Mobility in India". Journal of Human Resources. 48 (2): 435–473. doi:10.1353/jhr.2013.0012. ISSN 1548-8004. S2CID 13341683.
  114. Korpi, Walter; Palme, Joakim (1998). "The Paradox of Redistribution and Strategies of Equality: Welfare State Institutions, Inequality, and Poverty in the Western Countries". American Sociological Review. 63 (5): 661–687. ISSN 0003-1224. JSTOR 2657333.
  115. Milanović, Branko (2018). Global inequality: a new approach for the age of globalization (1st Harvard University Press paperback ed.). Cambridge, MA; London: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-98403-5.
  116. pp. 384 Table 12.2, U.S. university endowment size vs. real annual rate of return
  117. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (June 4, 2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future (pp. 30–31, 35–36). Norton. Kindle Edition.
  118. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future (p. 32). Norton. Kindle Edition.
  119. James K. Galbraith, Inequality and Instability: A Study of the World Economy Just before the Great Crisis (New York: Oxford University Press, 2012).
  120. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers Our Future, p. 334. Norton. Kindle Edition.
  121. Stevens, Harry (March 1, 2023). "The United States has caused the most global warming. When will China pass it?". The Washington Post. Archived from the original on March 1, 2023.
  122. ^ Cozzi, Laura; Chen, Olivia; Kim, Hyeji (February 22, 2023). "The world's top 1% of emitters produce over 1000 times more CO2 than the bottom 1%". iea.org. International Energy Agency (IEA). Archived from the original on March 3, 2023. "Methodological note: ... The analysis accounts for energy-related CO2, and not other greenhouse gases, nor those related to land use and agriculture."
  123. Uchoa, Pablo (May 6, 2019). "How global warming has made the rich richer". BBC. Retrieved June 5, 2019.
  124. Harvey, Fiona (September 20, 2020). "World's richest 1% cause double CO2 emissions of poorest 50%, says Oxfam". The Guardian. Retrieved September 22, 2020.
  125. McGrath, Matt (December 10, 2020). "Climate change: Global 'elite' will need to slash high-carbon lifestyles". BBC. Retrieved December 11, 2020.
  126. Ward-Glenton, Hannah (November 8, 2022). "Billionaires emit a million times more greenhouse gases than the average person: Oxfam". CNBC. Retrieved November 8, 2022.
  127. Elliott, Larry. "Top economists call for action on runaway global inequality". The Guardian. Retrieved July 19, 2023.
  128. "WORLD INVESTMENT REPORT 2023". UN Trade & development.
  129. "UNSDG | Developing countries face staggering $4 trillion investment gap in SDGs". unsdg.un.org. Retrieved June 27, 2024.
  130. Ruggeri, Kai; Ashcroft-Jones, S.; Abate Romero Landini, G. (June 26, 2023). "The persistence of cognitive biases in financial decisions across economic groups". Scientific Reports. 13 (1): 10329. Bibcode:2023NatSR..1310329R. doi:10.1038/s41598-023-36339-2. PMC 10293260. PMID 37365245.
  131. ^ Data from Chetty, Raj; Jackson, Matthew O.; Kuchler, Theresa; Stroebel, Johannes; et al. (August 1, 2022). "Social capital I: measurement and associations with economic mobility". Nature. 608 (7921): 108–121. Bibcode:2022Natur.608..108C. doi:10.1038/s41586-022-04996-4. PMC 9352590. PMID 35915342. Charted in Leonhardt, David (August 1, 2022). "'Friending Bias' / A large new study offers clues about how lower-income children can rise up the economic ladder". The New York Times. Archived from the original on August 1, 2022.
  132. Bradley, David; Huber, Evelyne; Moller, Stephanie; Nielsen, François; Stephens, John D. (2011). "Distribution and Redistribution in Postindustrial Democracies" (PDF). World Politics. 55 (2): 193–228. doi:10.1353/wp.2003.0009. hdl:10419/160937. S2CID 873271.
  133. Huber, Evelyne; Nielsen, François; Pribble, Jenny; Stephens, John D. (2006). "Politics and Inequality in Latin America and the Caribbean". American Sociological Review. 71 (6): 943–963. doi:10.1177/000312240607100604. JSTOR 25472438. S2CID 144270746.
  134. García-Peñalosa, Cecilia; Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2007). "Growth, Income Inequality, and Fiscal Policy: What Are the Relevant Trade-offs?". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 39 (2–3): 369–394. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.186.2754. doi:10.1111/j.0022-2879.2007.00029.x.
  135. Carroll, Christopher; Slacalek, Jiri; Kiichi, Tokuoka; White, Matthew (2017). "The distribution of wealth and the marginal propensity to consume". Quantitative Economics. 8 (3): 977–1020. doi:10.3982/QE694.
  136. Maialeh, Robin (2019). "Why Market Imperatives Invigorate Economic Inequality? Cobb-Douglas Utility Remodelled". Panoeconomicus. 66 (2): 145–163. doi:10.2298/PAN160220031M.
  137. Keller, Katarina R.I. (2010). "How Can Education Policy Improve Income Distribution?: An Empirical Analysis of Education Stages and Measures on Income Inequality". The Journal of Developing Areas. 43 (2): 51–77. doi:10.1353/jda.0.0052. JSTOR 40376250.
  138. Clark, J. R.; Lawson, Robert A. (2008). "The Impact of Economic Growth, Tax Policy and Economic Freedom on Income Inequality". The Journal of Private Enterprise. SSRN 2566842.
  139. Alfani, Guido (January 15, 2017). "The top rich in Europe in the long run of history (1300 to present day)". VoxEU.org. Retrieved January 16, 2017.
  140. Scheidel, Walter (February 23, 2017). "Inequality Has Historically Been Leveled Only By Terrible Violence And Upheaval". The Huffington Post. Retrieved March 30, 2017.
  141. ^ Taylor, Matt (February 22, 2017). "One Recipe for a More Equal World: Mass Death". Vice. Retrieved April 7, 2017.
  142. Porter, Eduardo (December 6, 2016). "A Dilemma for Humanity: Stark Inequality or Total War". The New York Times. Retrieved March 30, 2017.
  143. Scheidel, Walter (2017). The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press. pp. 438, 444. ISBN 978-0691165028.
  144. Moyes, P (1988). "A note on minimally progressive taxation and absolute income inequality". Social Choice and Welfare. 5 (2–3): 227–234. doi:10.1007/BF00735763. S2CID 189918945.
  145. Pickett and Wilkinson, The Spirit Level: Why More Equal Societies Almost Always Do Better, 2011
  146. Duncan, Denvil, Klara Sabirianova Peter (October 2012). "Unequal Inequalities: Do Progressive Taxes Reduce Income Inequality?" (PDF). Institute for the Study of Labor.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  147. Wealth Gap Widens In Rich Countries As Austerity Threatens To Worsen Inequality: OECD. The Huffington Post. Retrieved May 14, 2013
  148. Annie Lowrey (April 16, 2012). For Two Economists, the Buffett Rule Is Just a Start. The New York Times. Retrieved August 17, 2013.
  149. Nader, Ralph (April 18, 2013). Time for a Sales Tax on Wall Street Financial Transactions. The Huffington Post. Retrieved June 5, 2013.
  150. Erika Eichelberger (October 30, 2013). Economists to Congress: It's Time for a "Robin Hood Tax" on the Rich. Mother Jones. Retrieved November 15, 2013.
  151. "The logical floor". The Economist. December 14, 2013.
  152. Konczal, Mike (March 30, 2013). "How an anti-rentier agenda might bring liberals, conservatives together". The Washington Post. Retrieved April 6, 2013.
  153. Grusky, David B. (March–April 2013). "What to Do about Inequality". Boston Review. Archived from the original on April 20, 2013. Retrieved April 6, 2013.
  154. ^ Acemoglu, Daron; Robinson, James A.; Verdier, Thierry (2017). "Asymmetric Growth and Institutions in an Interdependent World". Journal of Political Economy. 125 (5): 1245–1305. doi:10.1086/693038. hdl:1721.1/118645. S2CID 154662416.
  155. Lane, Kenworthy (2015). Social Democratic America. US: Oxford University Press. pp. 88–93. ISBN 978-0190230951.
  156. "Goal 10 targets". UNDP. Archived from the original on November 27, 2020. Retrieved September 23, 2020.
  157. ^ "The Spirit Level". equalitytrust.org.uk.
  158. ^ Pickett, KE; Wilkinson, RG (March 2015). "Income inequality and health: a causal review". Social Science & Medicine. 128: 316–326. doi:10.1016/j.socscimed.2014.12.031. PMID 25577953.
  159. Woodward, Aylin (November 30, 2019). "Life expectancy in the US keeps going down, and a new study says America's worsening inequality could be to blame". Business Insider. Archived from the original on December 18, 2019. Retrieved December 18, 2019.
  160. Coughlan, Sean; Brown, David (May 14, 2019). "Inequality driving 'deaths of despair'". BBC. Retrieved December 18, 2019.
  161. Antony, Jürgen, and Torben Klarl. "Estimating the income inequality-health relationship for the United States between 1941 and 2015: Will the relevant frequencies please stand up?." The Journal of the Economics of Ageing. 17 (2020): 100275.
  162. Conley, Julia (March 20, 2019). "Social Democratic Nations Rank Happiest on Global Index (Again). US Ranking Falls (Again)". Common Dreams. Retrieved August 21, 2023.
  163. "World Happiness Report 2019" (PDF).
  164. Neapolitan, Jerome L (1999). "A comparative analysis of nations with low and high levels of violent crime". Journal of Criminal Justice. 27 (3): 259–274. doi:10.1016/S0047-2352(98)00064-6.
  165. Ezcurra, Roberto; Palacios, David (2016). "Terrorism and spatial disparities: Does interregional inequality matter?". European Journal of Political Economy. 42: 60–74. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2016.01.004.
  166. Kang, Songman (2015). "Inequality and crime revisited: Effects of local inequality and economic segregation on crime". Journal of Population Economics. 29 (2): 593–626. doi:10.1007/s00148-015-0579-3. S2CID 155852321.
  167. Corvalana, Alejandro, and Matteo Pazzonab. "Does Inequality Really Increase Crime? Theory and Evidence." In Technical Report. 2019.
  168. Richard Layard (March 3–5, 2003). "Happiness: Has Social Science A Clue?" (PDF). Lionel Robbins Memorial Lectures. Archived from the original (PDF) on June 3, 2013.
  169. Blanchard 2000; Oswald 2003, .
  170. Blanchard, Olivier (2000). Macroeconomics (2nd ed.). Upper Saddle River N.J: Prentice-Hall. OCLC 42454429.
  171. Oswald, Andrew J. (2003). "How Much do External Factors Affect Wellbeing? A Way to Use 'Happiness Economics' to Decide" (PDF). The Psychologist. 16: 140–141.
  172. Bernstein, Jared (January 13, 2014). "Poverty and Inequality, in Charts". Economix Blog. Retrieved April 30, 2021.
  173. "No Matter How We Measure Poverty, the Poverty Rate Would Be Much Lower If Economic Growth Were More Broadly Shared". Economic Policy Institute. Retrieved April 30, 2021.
  174. "Conservative Inequality Denialism," by Timothy Noah The New Republic (October 25, 2012)
  175. The Way Forward Archived July 11, 2012, at archive.today By Daniel Alpert, Westwood Capital; Robert Hockett, Professor of Law, Cornell University; and Nouriel Roubini, Professor of Economics, New York University, New America Foundation, October 10, 2011
  176. Plumer, Brad (March 27, 2013). "'Trickle-down consumption': How rising inequality can leave everyone worse off". Washington Post. Retrieved March 27, 2013.
  177. Bram Lancee and Hermanvande Werfhorst (2011) "Income Inequality and Participation: A Comparison of 24 European Countries" GINI Discussion Paper No. 6 (Amsterdam Centre for Inequality Studies)
  178. Alesina, Alberto; Perotti, Roberto (1996). "Income distribution, political instability, and investment". European Economic Review. 40 (6): 1203–1228. doi:10.1016/0014-2921(95)00030-5. S2CID 51838517.
  179. Robert C. Lieberman; Suzanne Mettler; Thomas B. Pepinsky; Kenneth M. Roberts; Richard Valelly (June 2019). "The Trump Presidency and American Democracy: A Historical and Comparative Analysis". Perspectives on Politics. 17 (2): 470–479. doi:10.1017/S1537592718003286.
  180. Walder, D.; Lust, E. (2018). "Unwelcome Change: Coming to Terms with Democratic Backsliding". Annual Review of Political Science. 21 (1): 93–113. doi:10.1146/annurev-polisci-050517-114628.
  181. Huq, Aziz; Ginsburg, Tom (2018). "How to Lose a Constitutional Democracy". UCLA Law Review. 65: 78–169.
  182. Baten, Joerg; Mumme, Christina (December 1, 2013). "Does inequality lead to civil wars? A global long-term study using anthropometric indicators (1816–1999)". European Journal of Political Economy. 32: 56–79. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2013.06.007. ISSN 0176-2680.
  183. Christina Mumme and Jörg Baten (2014). "Civil War Determinants From a Long-Term Perspective: Was There Impact Of Anthropometric Deprivation From 1816–1999?". European Review of Political Economy. 32: 56–79.
  184. Connell, Brendan J.; Dorr, Dalton C.; Shin, Adrian J. (March 6, 2021). "Inequality and the Partisan Political Economy". Representation. 57 (4): 575–601. doi:10.1080/00344893.2021.1883100. ISSN 0034-4893. S2CID 233845379.
  185. Barbara Goodwin. Using Political Ideas. West Sussex, England: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., 2007. p. 107.
  186. Wood, John Cunningham (1996). Karl Marx's Economics: Critical Assessments I and II. Routledge. ISBN 978-0415087148.
  187. Oldrich Kyn. "The Normative View of Marxian Theory on Income Distribution under Socialism". Archived from the original on March 14, 2015. Retrieved November 30, 2013.
  188. Landes, David. S. (1969). The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge & New York: Press Syndicate of the University of Cambridge. ISBN 978-0521094184.
  189. O'Donnell, Michael, and Serena Chen. "Political Ideology, the Moralizing of Income Inequality, and Its Social Consequences." Available at SSRN 3253666 (2018).
  190. Nozick, Robert (1974). Anarchy, state, and utopia. Blackwell Publishing. ISBN 978-0631197805. OCLC 1120103788.
  191. Rawls, John (2005). A Theory of Justice. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0674017726.
  192. Barry, Brian (1975). The liberal theory of justice : a critical examination of the principal doctrines in A theory of justice by John Rawls. Clarendon Press. ISBN 0198245092. OCLC 476228713.
  193. Cowen, Tyler (July 19, 2014). "Income Inequality Is Not Rising Globally. It's Falling". The New York Times. Retrieved July 26, 2014.
  194. Li, Robert (July 1, 2011). 'KILLING THE NOOB' A thesis on Meritocracy and what it has to do with Massive Multiplayer Online Role Playing Games (Bachelor of Arts with Honours thesis). Swinburne University of Technology.
  195. Anthony Giddens (June 27, 2005). "NS Essay – 'Accumulation of wealth is unjust where it arises not from hard work and risk-taking enterprise, but from brute luck factors such as returns from property. Inheritance is a form of brute-luck inequality'". New Statesman. Archived from the original on December 9, 2007.
  196. John Nichols (December 2, 2013). Pope: "King Money" Culture is Hurting Young and Old. Moyers & Company. Retrieved December 8, 2013.
  197. Andrew Brown (April 28, 2014). Pope Francis condemns inequality, thus refusing to play the game. The Guardian. Retrieved May 27, 2014.
  198. The Economics of Welfare| Arthur Cecil Pigou
  199. "inequity - Traduction anglais-arabe | PONS". fr.pons.com. Retrieved June 18, 2022.
  200. "Inequality and Happiness: Are Europeans and Americans Different?". Archived from the original on February 1, 2014.
  201. The relation between economic inequality and political inequality is explained by Robert Alan Dahl in the chapters The Presence of a Market Economy (p. 63), The Distribution of Political Resources (p. 84) und Market Capitalism and Human Dispositions (p. 87) in On Political Equality, 2006, 120 pages, Yale University Press, ISBN 978-0300126877
  202. "The toll of job loss". www.apa.org. Retrieved November 26, 2023.
  203. ^ Amartya Sen (1999). "Poverty as Capability Deprivation". Development as Freedom. New York: Anchor Books.
  204. Fukuda-Parr, Sakiko (2003). "The Human Development Paradigm: Operationalizing Sen's Ideas on Capabilities". Feminist Economics. 9 (2–3): 301–317. doi:10.1080/1354570022000077980. S2CID 18178004.
  205. UNDP (United Nations Development Programme) (January 1, 1990). Human Deuelopment Report 1990 (PDF) (Report). Oxford & New York: Oxford University Press. Via Human Deuelopment Reports
  206. Deneulin, Séverine; Alkire, Sabina (2009), "The human development and capability approach", in Deneulin, Séverine; Shahani, Lila (eds.), An introduction to the human development and capability approach freedom and agency, Sterling, VA & Ottawa, Ontario: Earthscan International Development Research Centre, pp. 22–48, ISBN 978-1844078066
  207. Communications, NYU Web. "Neoliberal Policies, Institutions Have Prompted Preference for Greater Inequality, New Study Finds". www.nyu.edu. Retrieved August 20, 2023.
  208. Stilwell, Frank (2019). The Political Economy of Inequality. Polity. pp. 240–241. ISBN 978-1509528653.

Further reading

Books
Articles

Historical

External links

Extreme wealth
Concepts
People
Wealth
Lists
People
Organizations
Other
Related
Philanthropy
Sayings
Media
Categories: