Misplaced Pages

Superstar: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively
← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 10:02, 20 August 2017 editMjlover29 (talk | contribs)19 editsm Origin of term: Various media outlets have called Michael Jackson world's biggest superstar. I have given some good references. Please do not remove it. It's a request.Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit← Previous edit Latest revision as of 18:35, 7 September 2024 edit undoDeparture– (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users3,302 editsm Undid revision 1244541260 by 2406:7400:FF03:1C2E:B506:967E:DF41:48EF (talk) rvvTag: Undo 
(202 intermediate revisions by more than 100 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{short description|Title}}
{{Other uses2|Superstar}}
{{other uses}}
{{pp-pc|small=yes}}
A '''superstar''' is someone who has great popular appeal and is widely known, prominent, or successful in their field. Celebrities referred to as "superstars" may include individuals who work as actors, musicians, athletes, and other media-based professions.


==History==
'''Superstar''' is a term used to refer to someone who has great popular appeal and is widely known, prominent, or successful in some field. Celebrities referred to as "superstars" may include individuals who work as ]s, ]es, ]s, ]s, and other media-based professions.
] popularized the term "]" to describe people like actress ].]]


The origin of the term in the context of celebrity is uncertain, but a similar expression is attested in ]'s 1832 cricket book '']''. Nyren described the 18th-century cricketer ] as "a star of the first magnitude".<ref name=JN>John Nyren, ''The Cricketers of my Time'', Robson, 1998, p.57.</ref> The earliest use of the term "superstar" has been credited to ] in reference to the ice hockey players on his ] teams of the 1910s and 1920s, specifically ].<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.thehockeynews.com/articles/40778-Vancouver-brothers-sculpted-game-of-hockey-100-years-before-Canucks-vied-for-cup.html|title=Vancouver brothers sculpted game of hockey 100 years before Canucks vied for cup - The Hockey News|agency=The Canadian Press|website=thehockeynews.com|access-date=2 April 2018}}</ref> In the June 1977 edition of '']'' magazine, pop artist ] was asked by editor ] who invented the word "superstar". Warhol, known for popularizing the term, responded, "I think it was ]." O'Brien then asked, "And who were the first superstars?" Warhol responded, "They were all Jack Smith's stars."<ref>O’Brien, Glenn (June 1977). {{cite web |url=https://www.interviewmagazine.com/art/andy-warhol |title=Andy Warhol.|date=4 June 2010}} ''Interview Magazine''.</ref> The term received widespread and commonplace use from the title of the musical '']'', in particular the 1970 concept album of the musical and the eponymous hit song. "Super Star" is also the name of a hugely successful rose which ] introduced and named in 1960.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.countrygardenroses.co.uk/shop/view/312-Super-Star-Hybrid-Tea-Rose|title=Super Star (Hybrid Tea Rose)|website=www.countrygardenroses.co.uk|access-date=2 April 2018}}</ref>
==Origin of term==


By 1909, ] companies began promoting "picture personalities" by releasing stories about actors to fan magazines and newspapers, as part of a strategy to build "brand loyalty" for their company's actors and films. By the 1920s, ] film company promoters had developed a "massive industrial enterprise" that "peddled a new intangible—fame".<ref name="Indeterminate">{{cite web|url=http://www.adidem.org/articles/MF1.html |title=? |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20020323005903/http://www.adidem.org/articles/MF1.html |archive-date=March 23, 2002 }}</ref> Hollywood "image makers" and promotional agents planted rumours, selectively released real or fictitious information to the press, and used other "gimmicks" to create public personas for actors. They then "worked reinforce that persona manage the publicity". Publicists thus "created" the "enduring images" and public perceptions of screen legends such as ], ], and ]. The development of this "]" made fame "something that could be fabricated purposely, by the masters of the new 'machinery of glory'".<ref name="Indeterminate"/>
] - the world's first designated "Superstar."]]


In 1976, ] produced a "Superstar" variation of its ].<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=NbxLVdUltiI |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/varchive/youtube/20211219/NbxLVdUltiI |archive-date=2021-12-19 |url-status=live|title=1976 Superstar Barbie Doll Commercial Full Length High Quality|last=BarbieCollectors|date=22 December 2008|access-date=2 April 2018|via=YouTube}}{{cbignore}}</ref> According to Sofia Johansson, the "canonical texts on stardom" include articles by Boorstin (1971), Alberoni (1972), and Dyer (1979) that examined the "representations of stars and on aspects of the ] star system". Johansson notes that "more recent analyses within media and cultural studies (e.g. Gamson 1994; Marshall 1997; Giles 2000; Turner, Marshall and Bonner 2000; Rojek 2001; Turner 2004) have instead dealt with the idea of a pervasive, contemporary, ']'". In an analysis of "celebrity culture", Johansson states that "fame and its constituencies are conceived of as a broader social process, connected to widespread economic, political, technological, and cultural developments".<ref>{{cite web |title=Editorial |first=Sofia |last=Johansson |work=Communication and Media Research Institute of the University of Westminster |url=http://www.wmin.ac.uk/mad/pdf/Sofia.pdf }}</ref>
], the most successful entertainer of all time<ref>https://www.riaa.com/michael-jacksons-thriller-first-ever-30x-multi-platinum-riaa-certification/</ref><ref> http://www.mtv.com/news/1614815/michael-jacksons-groundbreaking-career-by-the-numbers/</ref>, often referred to as the World's Biggest "Superstar"]] <ref>http://www.mtv.com/news/1615220/michael-jacksons-life-legacy-global-superstar-1982-86/</ref><ref>http://www.express.co.uk/news/world/110706/Michael-s-200-secret-songs-for-his-family</ref><ref>http://www.nme.com/news/music/michael-jackson-363-1304241</ref><ref>http://www.irishmirror.ie/news/irish-news/michael-jackson-hid-out-moate-2362225</ref><ref> http://www.bet.com/news/music/2015/06/25/tbt-watch-michael-jackson-get-emotional-honoring-james-brown-at-the-2003-bet-awards.html</ref><ref> http://www.nbcmiami.com/news/archive/Jacksons-Last-Dance-Starts-With-Private-Show.html</ref><ref> http://www.rollingstone.com/music/features/michael-jackson-the-making-of-the-king-of-pop-19920109</ref>


In the 1980s and 1990s, entertainment publicity tactics became "more subtle and sophisticated", such as using press releases, movie junkets, and community activities. These promotional efforts are targeted and designed using market research "to increase the predictability of success of their media ventures". In some cases, publicity agents may create "provocative advertisements" or make an outrageous public statement to "trigger public controversy and thereby generate 'free' news coverage".<ref name="Indeterminate"/>
], once the highest paid actor in India, is often referred to as "superstar".<ref name=Rapchik>{{cite news|last=Sharma|first=Neha|title=Rapchik Rajinikanth, mind it!|url=http://www.hindustantimes.com/Entertainment/Bollywood/Rapchik-Rajinikanth-mind-it/Article1-606098.aspx|accessdate=23 June 2014|newspaper=]|date=29 September 2010}}</ref>]]
] popularized the term "]" to describe people like actress ], star of '']'', who started out dancing with ]. See also ].]]
The origin of the term in the context of celebrity is uncertain, but a similar expression is attested in '']'', a famous ] book by ] about the ]. Writing in 1832, Nyren described the outstanding 18th-century batsman ] as "a star of the first magnitude".<ref name=JN>John Nyren, ''The Cricketers of my Time'', Robson, 1998, p.57.</ref>

The earliest use of the term "superstar" has been credited to ] in reference to the great hockey players on his ] teams of the 1910s-1920s, specifically ].<ref>http://www.thehockeynews.com/articles/40778-Vancouver-brothers-sculpted-game-of-hockey-100-years-before-Canucks-vied-for-cup.html</ref>

The term was later used in the 1960s by ]: "A friend of mine named Ingrid from New Jersey came up with a new last name, just right for her new, loosely defined show-business career. She called herself "Ingrid Superstar." I'm positive Ingrid invented that word. At least, I invite anyone with "superstar" clippings that predate Ingrid's to show them to me. The more parties we went to, the more they wrote her name in the papers, Ingrid Superstar, and "superstar" was starting its media run. Ingrid called me a few weeks ago. She's operating a sewing machine now. But her name is still going. It seems incredible, doesn't it?" (Andy Warhol, '']'')

The term received widespread and commonplace use from the title of the musical ], in particular the 1970 concept album of the musical and the eponymous hit song.

"Super Star" is the name of a hugely successful rose which Harry Wheatcroft introduced and named in 1960, licensed from a German developer.<ref>https://www.countrygardenroses.co.uk/shop/view/312-Super-Star-Hybrid-Tea-Rose</ref>.

==Early 1900s: development of the Hollywood "star system"==

{{Main|Star system (filmmaking)}}
By 1909, the silent film companies began promoting "picture personalities" by releasing stories about these actors to fan magazines and newspapers, as part of a strategy to build "brand loyalty" for their company's actors and films. By the 1920s, Hollywood film company promoters had developed a "massive industrial enterprise" that "... peddled a new intangible—fame."<ref name="webcache.googleusercontent.com">{{cite web|url=http://www.adidem.org/articles/MF1.html |title=? |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20020323005903/http://www.adidem.org/articles/MF1.html |archivedate=March 23, 2002 }}</ref>

Hollywood "image makers" and promotional agents planted rumours, selectively released real or fictitious biographical information to the press, and used other "gimmicks" to create personas for actors. Then they "...worked reinforce that persona manage the publicity." Publicists thus "created" the "enduring images" and public perceptions of screen legends such as Rock Hudson, Marilyn Monroe and Grace Kelly. The development of this "star system" made "fame... something that could be fabricated purposely, by the masters of the new 'machinery of glory.'"<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.adidem.org/articles/MF1.html |title=? |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20020323005903/http://www.adidem.org/articles/MF1.html |archivedate=March 23, 2002 }}</ref>

==1970s: Academic interest in stardom==
], the longest tenured and one of the most famous ] ].]]
According to Sofia Johansson the "canonical texts on stardom" include articles by Boorstin (1971), Alberoni (1972) and Dyer (1979) that examined the "representations of stars and on aspects of the ] star system." Johansson notes that "more recent analyses within media and cultural studies (e.g. Gamson 1994; Marshall 1997; Giles 2000; Turner, Marshall and Bonner 2000; Rojek 2001; Turner 2004) have instead dealt with the idea of a pervasive, contemporary, ']'." In the analysis of the 'celebrity culture,' "fame and its constituencies are conceived of as a broader social process, connected to widespread economic, political, technological and cultural developments."<ref>{{cite web |title=Editorial |first=Sofia |last=Johansson |work=Communication and Media Research Institute of the University of Westminster |url=http://www.wmin.ac.uk/mad/pdf/Sofia.pdf }}</ref>

In 1976 ] produced a Superstar concept of its Barbie™ Doll.<ref>https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=NbxLVdUltiI</ref>

==1980s–1990s: publicity tactics==

In the 1980s and 1990s, entertainment publicity tactics have become "more subtle and sophisticated", such as using press releases, movie "junkets, and community activities. These promotional efforts are targeted and designed using market research, "to increase the predictability of success of their media ventures." In some cases, publicity agents may create "provocative advertisements" or make an outrageous public statement to "trigger public controversy and thereby generate "free" news coverage."<ref name="webcache.googleusercontent.com"/>


==Socio-psychological theories== ==Socio-psychological theories==
] 'Part Of Me' movie premiere in ], ]. She is an American singer and the latest superstar. Some of her music videos have been ].]] ] has been referred to as a "globalstar", with his 2012 "]" video becoming the first ] on ].]]


According to ], superstars are created by the interplay between "mass media, free enterprise, and competition." Superstars are produced by a mixture of effort by the actors or athletes and chance (the luck of winning, due to the many arbitrary factors influencing sports, film releases, etc.). The "superstar has extraordinary natural talent augmented by an even more extraordinary perseverance and drive." According to ], superstars are created by the interplay between "mass media, free enterprise, and competition". Superstars are produced by a mixture of effort on the part of the superstar and mere chance (due to the many arbitrary factors influencing sports, film releases, etc.) and the superstar usually has "extraordinary natural talent augmented by an even more extraordinary perseverance and drive". However, small and relative differences are of decisive importance for "winning or losing by a hair's breadth". It is here that chance plays a role, with Caillois noting that "a sudden gust of wind at the end of a yachting race can mean the difference between stardom and defeat". He states that the role of chance in superstardom is paradoxical because ] is such a "predominantly ] society" which champions the importance of hard work, competition, activity, and determination.<ref name=Diogenes48>{{cite journal |title=Roger Caillois, Games of Chance and the Superstar |journal=] |author=Loek Groot |volume=48/2 |issue=190 |pages=33 |year=2000 |publisher=] /] |url=http://www2.econ.uu.nl/users/l.groot/Caillois&superstars.pdf |access-date=7 December 2010 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20111005133830/http://www2.econ.uu.nl/users/l.groot/Caillois%26superstars.pdf |archive-date=5 October 2011 }}</ref>
]) of ] was referred to as "globalstar". One of his ], the highest views recorded in YouTube's history.]]
However, "small and relative differences are of decisive importance for winning or losing by a hair's breadth." It is here that chance plays a role; a sudden gust of wind at the end of a yachting race can mean the difference between stardom and defeat. Caillois notes that the role of chance in superstardom is paradoxical, given that the west is such a "predominantly meritocratic society," which valorizes the role of work, competition, activity, and determination.<ref name=Diogenes48>{{cite journal |title=Roger Caillois, Games of Chance and the Superstar |journal=] |author=Loek Groot|volume= 48/2|issue=190 |pages=33 |year=2000 |publisher=] /] |url=http://www2.econ.uu.nl/users/l.groot/Caillois&superstars.pdf |accessdate=7 December 2010}}</ref>


" only one may be first. choose to win indirectly, through identification with someone else"- the superstar, whose triumph as the most popular actor or hit recording artist is in part due to the actions of "... those who worship the hero". The public believes that "the manicurist elected Beauty Queen, by the sales girl entrusted with the heroine's role in a super production, by the shopkeeper's daughter winning the ], by the gas station attendant who basks in the limelight as a champion toreador" represents the chance or possibility, from the public's perspective, that they may become wealthy and successful.<ref name=Diogenes48/> For example, Levine points out that "], the drummer for ], was a service station attendant before becoming a rich rock star; ] was a cabinet maker" before becoming a wealthy film star.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.dklevine.com/general/intellectual/mpaa.htm |title=Who wins and who loses? |authors=] and ]|publisher=dklevine.com }}</ref> Caillois states that " only one may be first, choose to win indirectly through identification with someone else" and that the triumph of the superstar as the most popular actor or musician is in part due to the actions of "those who worship the hero". He says the public believes that the concept of "the manicurist elected beauty queen, the sales girl entrusted with the heroine's role in a super production, the shopkeeper's daughter winning the ], and the gas station attendant who basks in the limelight as a champion toreador" represents the possibility from the public's perspective that they too may become wealthy and successful.<ref name=Diogenes48/> For example, Levine points out that ], the drummer for ], was a service station attendant before becoming a wealthy rock star and that ] was a cabinet maker before becoming a rich and famous actor.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.dklevine.com/general/intellectual/mpaa.htm |title=Who wins and who loses? |author1=] |author2=] |publisher=dklevine.com }}</ref>


Caillois calls superstars' huge incomes and rewards "disguised lotteries", a "special kind of game of chance." For example, the grand prizes for literary competitions "bring fortune and glory to a writer, for several years." Caillois notes that a "superstar" cannot merely be successful at some activity; they must also be richly rewarded. He says that the "material reward of the superstar is a necessary ingredient (for the glory of the star) for the identification of the public with the star, or whether it is the excellence or the private life of the star which is of more importance." He states that superstars' extravagant incomes play an important psychological "compensating mechanism" role for the public.<ref name=Diogenes48/> Caillois calls superstars' huge incomes and accolades "disguised lotteries" and a "special kind of game of chance". For example, the grand prizes for literary competitions "bring fortune and glory to a writer for several years". Caillois notes that a superstar cannot merely be successful at some activity{{emdash}}they must also be richly rewarded. He says that the "material reward of the superstar is a necessary ingredient (for the glory of the star) for the identification of the public with the star, or whether it is the excellence or the private life of the star which is of more importance". He states that superstars' extravagant incomes play an important psychological "compensating mechanism" role for the public.<ref name=Diogenes48/> According to Madow, "Fame is a 'relational' phenomenon, something that is conferred by others. A person can, within the limits of his natural talents, make himself strong or swift or learned. But he cannot, in this same sense, make himself famous, any more than he can make himself loved. Fame is often conferred or withheld, just as love is, for reasons and on grounds other than 'merit'. This means that regardless of how strenuously the star may try to 'monitor' and 'shape' it, the media and the public always play a substantial part in the image-making process."<ref name="Indeterminate"/>

According to Madow, "fame is a "relational" phenomenon, something that is conferred by others. A person can, within the limits of his natural talents, make himself strong or swift or learned. But he cannot, in this same sense, make himself famous, any more than he can make himself loved." Madow goes on to point out that "fame is often conferred or withheld, just as love is, for reasons and on grounds other than "merit." This means that regardless of how "... strenuously the star may ... try to "monitor" and "shape" it, the media and the public always play a substantial part in the image-making process."<ref name="webcache.googleusercontent.com"/>


==Economics of "superstars"== ==Economics of "superstars"==
In 1981, Sherwin Rosen examined the economics of superstars to determine why "relatively small numbers of people earn enormous amounts of money and seem to dominate the fields in which they engage" Rosen argues that, in superstar markets, "small differences in talent at the top of the distribution will translate into large differences in revenue".<ref name="ReferenceA">super star: Rajabaskar is the real super star. The Market for Rock Concerts in the Material World. ], ] and ] April 12, 2004</ref> Rosen points out that "sellers of higher talent charge only slightly higher prices than those of lower talent, but sell much larger quantities; their greater earnings come overwhelmingly from selling larger quantities than from charging higher prices".<ref>{{cite web |title=Competition and Market Power in Broadcasting: Where Are The Rents? |author=Paul Seabright and Helen Weeds |year=2006 |url=http://www.essex.ac.uk/~hfweeds/SeabrightWeeds_paper.pdf |publisher=essex.ac.uk }}{{Dead link|date=June 2018 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=no }}</ref>
] at the ]. He is one of the most well known Chinese people in the world.<ref>http://businessofcinema.com/bollywood-news/isivaji-the-bossi-set-to-release-on-friday/</ref>]]


Microeconomist Alfred Marshall explains that technology has greatly extended the power and reach of the planet's most gifted performers. He referenced classical opera singer ], a well-acclaimed soprano with a strong voice who could only reach a small audience and naturally did not have access to a microphone or amplifier in 1798, let alone "], ], ], and ]". This limited her ability to dominate the market in the way that artists to do today. Marshall wrote, "So long as the number of persons who can be reached by a human voice is strictly limited, it is not very likely that any singer will make an advance on the £10,000 said to have been earned in a season by Mrs. Billington at the beginning of the last century, nearly as great as that which the business leaders of the present generation have made on those of the last." Furthermore, the trends in popular music indicate that the price of the average concert ticket increased by nearly 400% from 1981 to 2012, much faster than the 150% rise in overall consumer price inflation.<ref>{{cite web |title=Land of Hope and Dreams: Rock and Roll, Economics, and Rebuilding the Middle Class |author=Alan Krueger |year=2013 |via=] |work=] |url = https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/blog/2013/06/12/rock-and-roll-economics-and-rebuilding-middle-class}}</ref>
Sherwin Rosen (1981) examined the economics of superstars to determine why "relatively small numbers of people earn enormous amounts of money and seem to dominate the fields in which they engage." Rosen argues that in superstar markets, "small differences in talent at the top of the distribution will translate into large differences in revenue."<ref name="ReferenceA">super star: Rajabaskar is the real super star. The Market for Rock Concerts in the Material World. ], ] and ] April 12, 2004</ref> Rosen points out that "...sellers of higher talent charge only slightly higher prices than those of lower talent, but sell much larger quantities; their greater earnings come overwhelmingly from selling larger quantities than from charging higher prices"<ref>{{cite web |title=Competition and Market Power in Broadcasting: Where Are The Rents? |author=Paul Seabright and Helen Weeds |year=2006 |url=http://www.essex.ac.uk/~hfweeds/SeabrightWeeds_paper.pdf |publisher=essex.ac.uk}}</ref>


Some scholars argue that superstardom plays a useful role in society. Caillois cites Rawls, who states that the "premiums earned by scarce natural talents serve to cover the costs of training and to encourage the efforts of learning, as well as to direct ability to where it best furthers the common interest".<ref name=Diogenes48/> Cowen cites Rosen to argue that "the superstar effect is welfare-improving (consumers get better performances) even if it leads to raising ]" and adds that the "superstar phenomenon should not be overstressed indeed, fame is a ], not a ] nor a ] one". Cowen states that "countervailing forces operate, such as a convergence of quality that limits the ability of the very best stars to dominate the market for long, or more radically the elastic supply of fame". This means that "when demand for fame increases, the numbers of prizes, rewards and whatever fame generating distinctions is rising too".<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.colloque2002symposium.gouv.qc.ca/PDF/Menger_paper_Symposium.pdf#search=%22superstar%20economic%20rationale%22 |title="Statistics in the Wake of Challenges Posed by Cultural Diversity in a Globalization Context" |author=Pierre-Michel Menger |work=Centre de Sociologie du Travail et des Arts Paris, France |publisher=gouv.qc.ca |access-date=7 December 2010 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110706200519/http://www.colloque2002symposium.gouv.qc.ca/PDF/Menger_paper_Symposium.pdf#search=%22superstar%20economic%20rationale%22 |archive-date=6 July 2011 |url-status=dead |df=dmy-all }}</ref>
Modern microconomist Alfred Marshall explains that technology has greatly extended the power and reach of the planet's most gifted performers. He referenced a classical of the British opera singer ]. She was a well-acclaimed soprano with a strong voice, that, naturally did not have access to a microphone or amplifier in 1798, let alone to MTV, CDs, iTunes, and Pandora. She could only reach a small audience. This limited her ability to dominate the market in the way that artists to do today. Marshall wrote, “so long as the number of persons who can be reached by a human voice is strictly limited, it is not very likely that any singer will make an advance on the £10,000 said to have been earned in a season by Mrs. Billington at the beginning of the last century, nearly as great as that which the business leaders of the present generation have made on those of the last. Furthermore, the trends in popular music indicate that "the price of the average concert ticket increased by nearly 400% from 1981 to 2012, much faster than the 150% rise in overall consumer price inflation.<ref>{{cite web |title=Land of Hope and Dreams: Rock and Roll, Economics, and Rebuilding the Middle Class |author=Alan Krueger |year=2013 |url= http://www.whitehouse.gov/blog/2013/06/12/rock-and-roll-economics-and-rebuilding-middle-class}}</ref>


On the other hand, it has been argued that "compensation systems that resemble prizes can also create ]s by discouraging cooperative behaviour and may encourage some contestants to disrupt the performance of competitors".<ref name="http">{{cite web |url=https://highered.mcgraw-hill.com/sites/0070891540/student_view0/chapter13/chapter_notes.html |title=? |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20040816080235/http://highered.mcgraw-hill.com/sites/0070891540/student_view0/chapter13/chapter_notes.html |archive-date=2004-08-16 }}</ref> As well, Frank and Cook (1995) called into question "the way the winner-take-all markets operate, with their damaging features". They argue that the "winner-take-all payoff structure generates a spiral of individual and social occupational waste, since it leads both to increasing (monetary and non-monetary) reward inequalities and to overcrowding in the markets and occupations prone to an overestimation of one's chance to succeed". As a result, they argue that "when excess numbers of contestants are induced to invest in performance enhancement in order to raise their individual odds of winning, these investments will be mutually offsetting and socially inefficient; end consumers may get more valuable products but the social costs are excessive".
===Debate over superstardom===

Some scholars argue that superstardom has a useful role in society. Caillois cites Rawls, who states that the "premiums earned by scarce natural talents . . . to cover the costs of training and to encourage the efforts of learning, as well as to direct ability to where it best furthers the common interest."<ref name=Diogenes48/> Cowen (2000) cites Rosen (1981) to argue that "the superstars effect is welfare-improving (consumers get better performances) even if it leads to raising ]," and adds that the "superstar phenomenon should not be overstressed. Indeed, fame is a positive-sum game, not a negative nor a zero-sum one." Cowen states that "countervailing forces operate, such as a convergence of quality that limits the ability of the very best stars to dominate the market for long, or more radically the elastic supply of fame." This means that "when demand for fame increases, the numbers of prizes, rewards and whatever fame generating distinctions is rising too."<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.colloque2002symposium.gouv.qc.ca/PDF/Menger_paper_Symposium.pdf#search=%22superstar%20economic%20rationale%22 |title=“Statistics in the Wake of Challenges Posed by Cultural Diversity in a Globalization Context”|author=Pierre-Michel Menger |work=Centre de Sociologie du Travail et des Arts Paris, France |publisher=gouv.qc.ca |accessdate=7 December 2010 }}</ref>

On the other hand, it has been argued "compensation systems that resemble prizes can also create ]s by discouraging cooperative behaviour and may encourage some contestants to disrupt the performance of competitors".<ref name="http">{{cite web|url=https://highered.mcgraw-hill.com/sites/0070891540/student_view0/chapter13/chapter_notes.html |title=? |deadurl=bot: unknown |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20040816080235/http://highered.mcgraw-hill.com:80/sites/0070891540/student_view0/chapter13/chapter_notes.html |archivedate=2004-08-16 |df= }}</ref> As well, Frank and Cook (1995) have called "into question the way the winner-take-all markets operate, with their damaging features." They argue that the "winner-take-all payoff structure generates a spiral of individual and social occupational waste, since it leads both to increasing (monetary and non-monetary) reward inequalities and to overcrowdings in the markets and occupations prone to an overestimation of one's chance to succeed." Thus as a result, they argue that "when excess numbers of contestants are induced to invest in performance enhancement in order to raise their individual odds of winning, these investments will be mutually offsetting and socially inefficient; end consumers may get more valuable products but the social costs are excessive."


==Other meanings== ==Other meanings==

==="Superstar" art museums=== ==="Superstar" art museums===
A small number of major art museums, including Frank Lloyd Wright's Guggenheim Museum in New York, the Centre Pompidou in Paris, Frank Gehry's Guggenheim Museum in Bilbao, among others, have become household names and major tourist destinations. Art museums such as these, with their striking, architecturally designed buildings and very well known masterpieces can be termed "superstar" art museums.<ref name="ReferenceB">{{cite web|url=https://www.iew.unizh.ch/home/smeier/downloads/Museum_Survey.pdf |title=? |deadurl=bot: unknown |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20060519094354/http://www.iew.unizh.ch:80/home/smeier/downloads/Museum_Survey.pdf |archivedate=2006-05-19 |df= }}</ref> With their huge visitor traffic, superstar museums are often able to derive a significant income from museum bookshops and restaurants and have a "major impact on the local economy".<ref name="ReferenceB"/> A small number of major art museums, including ]'s ], the ], and ]'s Guggenheim Museum, have become household names and major tourist destinations. With their striking, architecturally designed buildings and well-known masterpieces, they have been termed "superstar" art museums.<ref name="ReferenceB">{{cite web |url=https://www.iew.unizh.ch/home/smeier/downloads/Museum_Survey.pdf |title=? |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060519094354/http://www.iew.unizh.ch/home/smeier/downloads/Museum_Survey.pdf |archive-date=2006-05-19 }}</ref> With their huge visitor traffic, superstar museums are often able to derive a significant income from museum bookshops and restaurants and have a "major impact on the local economy".<ref name="ReferenceB"/> Superstar museums are able to use the popular appeal of their location and art holdings to produce their own books, videos, and television specials, which adds an additional revenue stream and further reinforces the public's awareness of the museum. Some superstar museums have also begun establishing museum networks. For example, ]'s ] launched the additional art museums ] and ].<ref name="ReferenceB"/>


Cultural institutions such as art museums play a "gatekeeping" role for consumers, helping to screen and grade cultural artefacts and artworks, thus "reducing information and search costs" for consumers. Moreover, by channelling resources to a limited group of visual artists, cultural institutions also "enhance superstar phenomena within the visual arts".{{citation needed|date=July 2019}}
Superstar museums are able to use the popular appeal of their location and art holdings to produce their own books, videos, and television specials, which adds an additional revenue stream and further reinforces the public's awareness of the museum. Some superstar museums have also begun establishing museum networks. For example, London's Tate Gallery has launched satellite art museums at Liverpool and St. Ives.<ref name="ReferenceB"/>

Cultural institutions such as art museums play a "gatekeeping role" for consumers, helping to screen and grade the cultural artifacts and artworks, thus "reduc information and search costs" for consumers. Moreover, "by channelling resources to a limited group of visual artists, cultural institutions also enhance superstar phenomena within the visual arts."<ref>{{cite web|url=https://https |title=? |deadurl=bot: unknown |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20130819141428/http://https |archivedate=2013-08-19 |df= }}</ref>


===Superstar CEOs=== ===Superstar CEOs===
McGraw-Hill's economic website argues that the multimillion-dollar salaries of superstar Chief Executive Officers (CEOs) in the corporate world can be viewed as a type of tournament prize. The huge salaries of superstar executives "often seem to resemble prizes for the winners of contests rather than compensation in return for the value of the marginal product of labour." As an example, "a company may have many vice-presidents of roughly comparable ability and the v-p (who may only be slightly more talented than the others) that is promoted to president receives a huge salary increase, which resembles a prize for winning the contest as best v-p."<ref>{{cite web|url=https://highered.mcgraw-hill.com/sites/0070891540/student_view0/chapter13/chapter_notes.html |title=? |deadurl=bot: unknown |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20040816080235/http://highered.mcgraw-hill.com:80/sites/0070891540/student_view0/chapter13/chapter_notes.html |archivedate=2004-08-16 |df= }}</ref> ]'s economic website argues that the multimillion-dollar salaries of superstar CEOs in the corporate world can be viewed as a type of tournament prize. The huge salaries of these executives "often seem to resemble prizes for the winners of contests rather than compensation in return for the value of the marginal product of labour". As an example, a company may "have many vice-presidents of roughly comparable ability and the vice-president (who may only be slightly more talented than the others) that is promoted to president receives a huge salary increase, which resembles a prize for winning the contest as best VP".<ref name="http"/> The article goes on to argue, "Such a compensation system may be efficient if the organization is only able to rank its executives according to the relative value of their contribution to the organization (the organization cannot measure the productivity of each executive, only the productivity of the group of executives). Even if executives are paid a wage equal to the average productivity of the group, there will still be an incentive to perform in order be promoted and win the prize."<ref name="http"/>

The article goes on to argue that "...such a compensation system may be efficient if the organization is only able to rank its executives according to the relative value of their contribution to the organization (the organization cannot measure the productivity of each executive, only the productivity of the group of executives)." Moreover, "even if executives are paid a wage equal to the average productivity of the group, there will still be an incentive to perform in order be promoted and win the prize." However, "compensation systems that resemble prizes can also create perverse incentives by discouraging cooperative behaviour and may encourage some contestants to disrupt the performance of competitors"<ref name="http"/>


==See also== ==See also==
*]
*] *]
*]


==References== ==References==
Line 88: Line 50:
==Further reading== ==Further reading==
* Hamlen, William A. "Superstardom in Popular Music: Empirical Evidence." ''Review of Economics and Statistics'' 73 (1991): 729–33. * Hamlen, William A. "Superstardom in Popular Music: Empirical Evidence." ''Review of Economics and Statistics'' 73 (1991): 729–33.
* Koutsobinas, Theodore. ''The Political Economy of Status: Superstars, Markets, and Culture Change'' (Edward Elgar Publishing; 2015) 264 pages; on the societal impact of luxury consumption and status markets, and the media's fascination with superstars. * ].
* MacDonald, Glenn M. "The Economics of Rising Stars." ''American Economic Review'' 78 (1988): 155–67. * MacDonald, Glenn M. "The Economics of Rising Stars." ''American Economic Review'' 78 (1988): 155–67.
* Rosen, Sherwin. The superstar effect – "The Economics of Superstars", ''American Economic Review'', 71 (1981). * Rosen, Sherwin. The superstar effect – "The Economics of Superstars", ''American Economic Review'', 71 (1981).
* Salganik, Matthew J., Peter Sheridan Dodds, and Duncan J. Watts. "Experimental Study of Inequality and Unpredictability in an Artificial Cultural Market." ''Science'' 311 (2006): 854-56. * ], Peter Sheridan Dodds, and Duncan J. Watts. "Experimental Study of Inequality and Unpredictability in an Artificial Cultural Market." ''Science'' 311 (2006): 854–56.
* Pattni, Anandi. 'Superstars: People who are good to me' ''Vanity Fair'' 157 (2007): 185–89. * Pattni, Anandi. 'Superstars: People who are good to me' ''Vanity Fair'' 157 (2007): 185–89.
* ], "People of Celebrity" as a New Social Stratum and Elite. In Hierarchy and Power in the History of Civilizations: Cultural Dimensions (pp.&nbsp;183–206). / Ed. by Leonid E. Grinin and Andrey V. ]. Moscow: KRASAND, 2009 {{cite web |url=http://old.uchitel-izd.ru/index.php?option=content&task=view&id=184&Itemid=58 |script-title=ru:Работы на иностранных языках 2009г |language=Russian |accessdate=7 December 2010}} * ], "People of Celebrity" as a New Social Stratum and Elite. In Hierarchy and Power in the History of Civilizations: Cultural Dimensions (pp.&nbsp;183–206). / Ed. by Leonid E. Grinin and ]. Moscow: KRASAND, 2009 {{cite web |url=http://old.uchitel-izd.ru/index.php?option=content&task=view&id=184&Itemid=58 |script-title=ru:Работы на иностранных языках 2009г |language=ru |access-date=7 December 2010}}


]
] ]
] ]

Latest revision as of 18:35, 7 September 2024

Title For other uses, see Superstar (disambiguation).

A superstar is someone who has great popular appeal and is widely known, prominent, or successful in their field. Celebrities referred to as "superstars" may include individuals who work as actors, musicians, athletes, and other media-based professions.

History

In the 1960s and 1970s, Andy Warhol popularized the term "superstar" to describe people like actress Mary Woronov.

The origin of the term in the context of celebrity is uncertain, but a similar expression is attested in John Nyren's 1832 cricket book The Cricketers of My Time. Nyren described the 18th-century cricketer John Small as "a star of the first magnitude". The earliest use of the term "superstar" has been credited to Frank Patrick in reference to the ice hockey players on his Vancouver Millionaires teams of the 1910s and 1920s, specifically Cyclone Taylor. In the June 1977 edition of Interview magazine, pop artist Andy Warhol was asked by editor Glenn O'Brien who invented the word "superstar". Warhol, known for popularizing the term, responded, "I think it was Jack Smith." O'Brien then asked, "And who were the first superstars?" Warhol responded, "They were all Jack Smith's stars." The term received widespread and commonplace use from the title of the musical Jesus Christ Superstar, in particular the 1970 concept album of the musical and the eponymous hit song. "Super Star" is also the name of a hugely successful rose which Harry Wheatcroft introduced and named in 1960.

By 1909, silent film companies began promoting "picture personalities" by releasing stories about actors to fan magazines and newspapers, as part of a strategy to build "brand loyalty" for their company's actors and films. By the 1920s, Hollywood film company promoters had developed a "massive industrial enterprise" that "peddled a new intangible—fame". Hollywood "image makers" and promotional agents planted rumours, selectively released real or fictitious information to the press, and used other "gimmicks" to create public personas for actors. They then "worked reinforce that persona manage the publicity". Publicists thus "created" the "enduring images" and public perceptions of screen legends such as Rock Hudson, Marilyn Monroe, and Grace Kelly. The development of this "star system" made fame "something that could be fabricated purposely, by the masters of the new 'machinery of glory'".

In 1976, Mattel produced a "Superstar" variation of its Barbie doll. According to Sofia Johansson, the "canonical texts on stardom" include articles by Boorstin (1971), Alberoni (1972), and Dyer (1979) that examined the "representations of stars and on aspects of the Hollywood star system". Johansson notes that "more recent analyses within media and cultural studies (e.g. Gamson 1994; Marshall 1997; Giles 2000; Turner, Marshall and Bonner 2000; Rojek 2001; Turner 2004) have instead dealt with the idea of a pervasive, contemporary, 'celebrity culture'". In an analysis of "celebrity culture", Johansson states that "fame and its constituencies are conceived of as a broader social process, connected to widespread economic, political, technological, and cultural developments".

In the 1980s and 1990s, entertainment publicity tactics became "more subtle and sophisticated", such as using press releases, movie junkets, and community activities. These promotional efforts are targeted and designed using market research "to increase the predictability of success of their media ventures". In some cases, publicity agents may create "provocative advertisements" or make an outrageous public statement to "trigger public controversy and thereby generate 'free' news coverage".

Socio-psychological theories

South Korean musician Psy has been referred to as a "globalstar", with his 2012 "Gangnam Style" video becoming the first to reach 1 billion views on YouTube.

According to Roger Caillois, superstars are created by the interplay between "mass media, free enterprise, and competition". Superstars are produced by a mixture of effort on the part of the superstar and mere chance (due to the many arbitrary factors influencing sports, film releases, etc.) and the superstar usually has "extraordinary natural talent augmented by an even more extraordinary perseverance and drive". However, small and relative differences are of decisive importance for "winning or losing by a hair's breadth". It is here that chance plays a role, with Caillois noting that "a sudden gust of wind at the end of a yachting race can mean the difference between stardom and defeat". He states that the role of chance in superstardom is paradoxical because the west is such a "predominantly meritocratic society" which champions the importance of hard work, competition, activity, and determination.

Caillois states that " only one may be first, choose to win indirectly through identification with someone else" and that the triumph of the superstar as the most popular actor or musician is in part due to the actions of "those who worship the hero". He says the public believes that the concept of "the manicurist elected beauty queen, the sales girl entrusted with the heroine's role in a super production, the shopkeeper's daughter winning the Tour de France, and the gas station attendant who basks in the limelight as a champion toreador" represents the possibility from the public's perspective that they too may become wealthy and successful. For example, Levine points out that Lars Ulrich, the drummer for Metallica, was a service station attendant before becoming a wealthy rock star and that Harrison Ford was a cabinet maker before becoming a rich and famous actor.

Caillois calls superstars' huge incomes and accolades "disguised lotteries" and a "special kind of game of chance". For example, the grand prizes for literary competitions "bring fortune and glory to a writer for several years". Caillois notes that a superstar cannot merely be successful at some activity—they must also be richly rewarded. He says that the "material reward of the superstar is a necessary ingredient (for the glory of the star) for the identification of the public with the star, or whether it is the excellence or the private life of the star which is of more importance". He states that superstars' extravagant incomes play an important psychological "compensating mechanism" role for the public. According to Madow, "Fame is a 'relational' phenomenon, something that is conferred by others. A person can, within the limits of his natural talents, make himself strong or swift or learned. But he cannot, in this same sense, make himself famous, any more than he can make himself loved. Fame is often conferred or withheld, just as love is, for reasons and on grounds other than 'merit'. This means that regardless of how strenuously the star may try to 'monitor' and 'shape' it, the media and the public always play a substantial part in the image-making process."

Economics of "superstars"

In 1981, Sherwin Rosen examined the economics of superstars to determine why "relatively small numbers of people earn enormous amounts of money and seem to dominate the fields in which they engage" Rosen argues that, in superstar markets, "small differences in talent at the top of the distribution will translate into large differences in revenue". Rosen points out that "sellers of higher talent charge only slightly higher prices than those of lower talent, but sell much larger quantities; their greater earnings come overwhelmingly from selling larger quantities than from charging higher prices".

Microeconomist Alfred Marshall explains that technology has greatly extended the power and reach of the planet's most gifted performers. He referenced classical opera singer Elizabeth Billington, a well-acclaimed soprano with a strong voice who could only reach a small audience and naturally did not have access to a microphone or amplifier in 1798, let alone "MTV, CDs, iTunes, and Pandora". This limited her ability to dominate the market in the way that artists to do today. Marshall wrote, "So long as the number of persons who can be reached by a human voice is strictly limited, it is not very likely that any singer will make an advance on the £10,000 said to have been earned in a season by Mrs. Billington at the beginning of the last century, nearly as great as that which the business leaders of the present generation have made on those of the last." Furthermore, the trends in popular music indicate that the price of the average concert ticket increased by nearly 400% from 1981 to 2012, much faster than the 150% rise in overall consumer price inflation.

Some scholars argue that superstardom plays a useful role in society. Caillois cites Rawls, who states that the "premiums earned by scarce natural talents serve to cover the costs of training and to encourage the efforts of learning, as well as to direct ability to where it best furthers the common interest". Cowen cites Rosen to argue that "the superstar effect is welfare-improving (consumers get better performances) even if it leads to raising income inequality" and adds that the "superstar phenomenon should not be overstressed indeed, fame is a positive-sum game, not a negative nor a zero-sum one". Cowen states that "countervailing forces operate, such as a convergence of quality that limits the ability of the very best stars to dominate the market for long, or more radically the elastic supply of fame". This means that "when demand for fame increases, the numbers of prizes, rewards and whatever fame generating distinctions is rising too".

On the other hand, it has been argued that "compensation systems that resemble prizes can also create perverse incentives by discouraging cooperative behaviour and may encourage some contestants to disrupt the performance of competitors". As well, Frank and Cook (1995) called into question "the way the winner-take-all markets operate, with their damaging features". They argue that the "winner-take-all payoff structure generates a spiral of individual and social occupational waste, since it leads both to increasing (monetary and non-monetary) reward inequalities and to overcrowding in the markets and occupations prone to an overestimation of one's chance to succeed". As a result, they argue that "when excess numbers of contestants are induced to invest in performance enhancement in order to raise their individual odds of winning, these investments will be mutually offsetting and socially inefficient; end consumers may get more valuable products but the social costs are excessive".

Other meanings

"Superstar" art museums

A small number of major art museums, including Frank Lloyd Wright's Guggenheim Museum, the Centre Pompidou, and Frank Gehry's Guggenheim Museum, have become household names and major tourist destinations. With their striking, architecturally designed buildings and well-known masterpieces, they have been termed "superstar" art museums. With their huge visitor traffic, superstar museums are often able to derive a significant income from museum bookshops and restaurants and have a "major impact on the local economy". Superstar museums are able to use the popular appeal of their location and art holdings to produce their own books, videos, and television specials, which adds an additional revenue stream and further reinforces the public's awareness of the museum. Some superstar museums have also begun establishing museum networks. For example, London's Tate Gallery launched the additional art museums Tate Liverpool and Tate St. Ives.

Cultural institutions such as art museums play a "gatekeeping" role for consumers, helping to screen and grade cultural artefacts and artworks, thus "reducing information and search costs" for consumers. Moreover, by channelling resources to a limited group of visual artists, cultural institutions also "enhance superstar phenomena within the visual arts".

Superstar CEOs

McGraw-Hill's economic website argues that the multimillion-dollar salaries of superstar CEOs in the corporate world can be viewed as a type of tournament prize. The huge salaries of these executives "often seem to resemble prizes for the winners of contests rather than compensation in return for the value of the marginal product of labour". As an example, a company may "have many vice-presidents of roughly comparable ability and the vice-president (who may only be slightly more talented than the others) that is promoted to president receives a huge salary increase, which resembles a prize for winning the contest as best VP". The article goes on to argue, "Such a compensation system may be efficient if the organization is only able to rank its executives according to the relative value of their contribution to the organization (the organization cannot measure the productivity of each executive, only the productivity of the group of executives). Even if executives are paid a wage equal to the average productivity of the group, there will still be an incentive to perform in order be promoted and win the prize."

See also

References

  1. John Nyren, The Cricketers of my Time, Robson, 1998, p.57.
  2. "Vancouver brothers sculpted game of hockey 100 years before Canucks vied for cup - The Hockey News". thehockeynews.com. The Canadian Press. Retrieved 2 April 2018.
  3. O’Brien, Glenn (June 1977). "Andy Warhol". 4 June 2010. Interview Magazine.
  4. "Super Star (Hybrid Tea Rose)". www.countrygardenroses.co.uk. Retrieved 2 April 2018.
  5. ^ "?". Archived from the original on March 23, 2002.
  6. BarbieCollectors (22 December 2008). "1976 Superstar Barbie Doll Commercial Full Length High Quality". Archived from the original on 2021-12-19. Retrieved 2 April 2018 – via YouTube.
  7. Johansson, Sofia. "Editorial" (PDF). Communication and Media Research Institute of the University of Westminster.
  8. ^ Loek Groot (2000). "Roger Caillois, Games of Chance and the Superstar" (PDF). Diogenes. 48/2 (190). ICPHS /Blackwell Publishers: 33. Archived from the original (PDF) on 5 October 2011. Retrieved 7 December 2010.
  9. Michele Boldrin; David K. Levine. "Who wins and who loses?". dklevine.com.
  10. super star: Rajabaskar is the real super star. The Market for Rock Concerts in the Material World. Alan B. Krueger, Princeton University and NBER April 12, 2004
  11. Paul Seabright and Helen Weeds (2006). "Competition and Market Power in Broadcasting: Where Are The Rents?" (PDF). essex.ac.uk.
  12. Alan Krueger (2013). "Land of Hope and Dreams: Rock and Roll, Economics, and Rebuilding the Middle Class". whitehouse.gov – via National Archives.
  13. Pierre-Michel Menger. ""Statistics in the Wake of Challenges Posed by Cultural Diversity in a Globalization Context"" (PDF). Centre de Sociologie du Travail et des Arts Paris, France. gouv.qc.ca. Archived from the original (PDF) on 6 July 2011. Retrieved 7 December 2010.
  14. ^ "?". Archived from the original on 2004-08-16.
  15. ^ "?" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2006-05-19.

Further reading

Categories: