Revision as of 11:08, 30 July 2020 editMrOllie (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users, Pending changes reviewers, Rollbackers236,461 editsm Reverted 1 edit by Sumairalikayani (talk) to last revision by MrOllie (TW)Tag: Undo← Previous edit | Latest revision as of 22:41, 14 December 2024 edit undoCitation bot (talk | contribs)Bots5,410,330 edits Altered template type. Add: pmid, issue, pages, volume, journal, date, title, doi, authors 1-2. Changed bare reference to CS1/2. | Use this bot. Report bugs. | Suggested by Jay8g | #UCB_toolbar | ||
(100 intermediate revisions by 69 users not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{Short description|Wealth gained by a person or company within a given time period}} | |||
{{About|theoretical attempts to define income|its definition in United States law|Income (United States legal definitions)}} | |||
{{for|the concept in U.S. law|Income (United States legal definitions)}} | |||
{{refimprove|date=October 2010}} | {{refimprove|date=October 2010}} | ||
'''Income''' is the consumption and saving opportunity gained by an entity within a specified timeframe, which is generally expressed in monetary terms.<ref name="Smith">Smith's financial dictionary. Smith, Howard Irving. 1908. Income is defined as, "Revenue; the amount of money coming to a person or a corporation (usually interpreted as meaning annually) whether as payment for services or as interest or other profit from investment."</ref><ref>Webster's new modern English dictionary, illustrated. Webster, Noah. 1922. Income is defined as "the gain which proceeds from labor, business, property or capital; annual receipts of a person or corporation."</ref><ref name="Barr"/> | |||
'''Income''' is the ] and ] opportunity gained by an entity within a specified timeframe, which is generally expressed in ] terms.<ref name="Barr"/> Income is difficult to define conceptually and the definition may be different across fields.<ref name="Mc">{{Cite book|last=McCaffery|first=Edward|title=The Oxford Introductions to U.S. Law: Income Tax Law 1st Edition|publisher= Oxford University Press|date=2012}}</ref>{{page needed|date=January 2022}} For example, a person's income in an economic sense may be different from their income as defined by law.<ref name="Mc"/> | |||
For households and individuals, "income is the sum of all the wages, salaries, profits, interest payments, rents, and other forms of earnings received in a given period of time."<ref name="Case & Fair">Case, K. & Fair, R. (2007). ''Principles of Economics''. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education. p. 54.</ref> (also known as ]). Net income is defined as the gross income minus taxes and other deductions (e.g., mandatory ] contributions), and is usually the basis to calculate how much ] is owed. | |||
An extremely important definition of income is ], which defines income as ''Consumption + Change in net worth'' and is widely used in ].<ref name="Mc"/> | |||
For ]s and individuals in the ], income is defined by tax law as a sum that includes any ], ], ], ] payment, ], or other form of earnings received in a calendar year.<ref name="Case & Fair">Case, K. & Fair, R. (2007). ''Principles of Economics''. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education. p. 54.</ref> ] is often defined as gross income minus ]es and other deductions (e.g., mandatory ] contributions), and is widely used as a basis to compare the welfare of taxpayers. | |||
In the field of ], the concept may comprise the accumulation of both monetary and non-monetary consumption ability, with the former (monetary) being used as a proxy for total income. | In the field of ], the concept may comprise the accumulation of both monetary and non-monetary consumption ability, with the former (monetary) being used as a proxy for total income. | ||
For a firm, gross income can be defined as sum of all ] minus the ]. ] nets out expenses: net income equals revenue minus |
For a firm, gross income can be defined as sum of all ] minus the ]. ] nets out expenses: net income equals revenue minus cost of goods sold, ], ], interest, and taxes.<ref name="Barr"> | ||
Barr, N. (2004). Problems and definition of measurement. In ''Economics of the welfare state''. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 121–124 | Barr, N. (2004). Problems and definition of measurement. In ''Economics of the welfare state''. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 121–124 | ||
</ref> | </ref> | ||
==Economic definitions== | ==Economic definitions== | ||
===Full and Haig–Simons income=== | |||
In ], "]" is the return accruing for a person, or a nation, derived from the "factors of production": rental income, wages generated by labor, the interest created by capital, and profits from entrepreneurial ventures.<ref>{{cite web|title=factor income|url=http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/factor-income.html|work=BusinessDictionary.com|publisher=WebFinance, Inc|accessdate=20 June 2012|author=Staff|year=2012}}</ref> | |||
{{Main article|Haig–Simons income}} | |||
"Full income" refers to the accumulation of both the monetary and the non-monetary consumption-ability of any given entity, such as a person or a household. According to what the economist ] describes as the "classical definition of income" (the 1938 Haig–Simons definition): "income may be defined as the... sum of (1) the market value of rights exercised in consumption and (2) the change in the value of the store of property rights..." Since the consumption potential of non-monetary goods, such as leisure, cannot be measured, monetary income may be thought of as a proxy for full income.<ref name="Barr"/> As such, however, it is criticized{{by whom|date=July 2015}} for being unreliable, ''i.e.'' failing to accurately reflect affluence (and thus the consumption opportunities) of any given agent. | |||
It omits the utility a person may derive from non-monetary income and, on a macroeconomic level, fails to accurately chart ]. According to Barr, "in practice money income as a proportion of total income varies widely and unsystematically. Non-observability of full income prevents a complete characterization of the individual opportunity set, forcing us to use the unreliable yardstick of money income. | |||
===Factor income=== | |||
In ], "]" is the return accruing for a person, or a nation, derived from the "factors of production": rental income, wages generated by labor, the interest created by capital, and profits from entrepreneurial ventures.<ref>{{cite web|title=factor income|url=http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/factor-income.html|work=BusinessDictionary.com|publisher=WebFinance, Inc|access-date=20 June 2012|author=Staff|year=2012|archive-date=18 June 2012|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120618040855/http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/factor-income.html|url-status=dead}} m</ref> | |||
In ] 'income' is another name for the "budget constraint |
In ] 'income' is another name for the "budget constraint", an amount <math>Y</math> to be spent on different goods x and y in quantities <math>x</math> and <math>y</math> at prices <math>P_x</math> and <math>P_y</math>. The basic equation for this is | ||
:<math>Y=P_x \cdot x + P_y \cdot y</math> | :<math>Y=P_x \cdot x + P_y \cdot y</math> | ||
This equation implies two things. First buying one more unit of good x implies buying <math>\frac{P_x}{P_y}</math> less units of good y. So, <math>\frac{P_x}{P_y}</math> is the ''relative'' price of a unit of x as to the number of units given up in y. |
This equation implies two things. First buying one more unit of good x implies buying <math>\frac{P_x}{P_y}</math> less units of good y. So, <math>\frac{P_x}{P_y}</math> is the ''relative'' price of a unit of x as to the number of units given up in y. Second, if the price of x falls for a fixed <math>Y</math> and fixed <math>P_y,</math> then its relative price falls. The usual hypothesis, the ], is that the quantity demanded of x would increase at the lower price. The analysis can be generalized to more than two goods. | ||
The theoretical generalization to more than one period is a multi-period ] and income constraint. For example, the same person can gain more productive skills or acquire more productive income-earning assets to earn a higher income. In the multi-period case, something might also happen to the economy beyond the control of the individual to reduce (or increase) the flow of income. Changing measured income and its relation to consumption over time might be modeled accordingly, such as in the ]. | The theoretical generalization to more than one period is a multi-period ] and income constraint. For example, the same person can gain more productive skills or acquire more productive income-earning assets to earn a higher income. In the multi-period case, something might also happen to the economy beyond the control of the individual to reduce (or increase) the flow of income. Changing measured income and its relation to consumption over time might be modeled accordingly, such as in the ]. | ||
==Legal definitions== | |||
===Full and Haig–Simons income=== | |||
{{Main article|Haig–Simons income}} | |||
===Definitions under the Internal Revenue Code=== | |||
"Full income" refers to the accumulation of both the monetary and the non-monetary consumption-ability of any given entity, such as a person or a household. According to what the economist ] describes as the "classical definition of income" (the 1938 Haig–Simons definition): "income may be defined as the... sum of (1) the market value of rights exercised in consumption and (2) the change in the value of the store of property rights..." Since the consumption potential of non-monetary goods, such as leisure, cannot be measured, monetary income may be thought of as a proxy for full income.<ref name="Barr"/> As such, however, it is criticized{{by whom|date=July 2015}} for being unreliable, ''i.e.'' failing to accurately reflect affluence (and thus the consumption opportunities) of any given agent. It omits the utility a person may derive from non-monetary income and, on a macroeconomic level, fails to accurately chart ]. According to Barr, "in practice money income as a proportion of total income varies widely and unsystematically. Non-observability of full-income prevent a complete characterization of the individual opportunity set, forcing us to use the unreliable yardstick of money income. | |||
{{Main|Internal Revenue Code section 61}} | |||
{{Blockquote|Except as otherwise provided in this subtitle, gross income means all income from whatever source derived, including (but not limited to) the following items: (1) Compensation for services, including fees, commissions, fringe benefits, and similar items; (2) Gross income derived from business; (3) Gains derived from dealings in property; (4) Interest; (5) Rents; (6) Royalties; (7) Dividends; (8) Annuities; (9) Income from life insurance and endowment contracts; (10) Pensions; (11) Income from discharge of indebtedness; (12) Distributive share of partnership gross income; (13) Income in respect of a decedent; and (14) Income from an interest in an estate or trust.}} | |||
26 U.S. Code § 61 - Gross income defined. There are also some statutory exclusions from income.<ref name="Mc"/> | |||
===Definition under US Case law=== | |||
{{Main|Commissioner v. Glenshaw Glass Co.}} | |||
Income is an "undeniable accessions to wealth, clearly realized, and over which the taxpayer has complete dominion." Commentators say that this is a pretty good definition of income.<ref name="Mc"/> | |||
Taxable income is usually lower than Haig-Simons income.<ref name="Mc"/> This is because unrealized appreciation (e.g., the increase in the value of stock over the course of a year) is economic income but not taxable income, and because there are many statutory exclusions from taxable income, including ], ], gifts, child support, and in-kind government transfers.<ref>Brooks, John R., "The Definitions of Income" (2018). Georgetown Law Faculty Publications and Other Works. 1952. https://scholarship.law.georgetown.edu/facpub/1952/</ref> | |||
==Accounting definitions== | |||
{{Main article|Income (United States legal definitions)}} | |||
The ] (IASB) uses the following definition: "Income is increases in economic benefits during the accounting period in the form of inflows or enhancements of assets or decreases of liabilities that result in increases in equity, other than those relating to contributions from equity participants." (IFRS Framework). | |||
Previously the IFRS conceptual framework (4.29) stated: "The definition of income encompasses both revenue and gains. Revenue arises in the course of the ordinary activities of an entity and is referred to by a variety of different names including sales, fees, interest, dividends, royalties and rent. 4.30: Gains represent other items that meet the definition of income and may, or may not, arise in the course of the ordinary activities of an entity. Gains represent increases in economic benefits and as such are no different in nature from revenue. Hence, they are not regarded as constituting a separate element in this Conceptual Framework."<ref>{{Cite web |last=admin |title=Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting 2018 |url=https://www.iasplus.com/en/standards/other/framework |access-date=2022-06-28 |website=www.iasplus.com |language=en}}</ref> | |||
The current IFRS conceptual framework <ref>{{cite web|title=IASB|url=https://www.ifrs.org/issued-standards/list-of-standards/}}</ref> (4.68) no longer draws a distinction between revenue and gains. Nevertheless, the distinction continues to be drawn at the standard and reporting levels. For example, IFRS 9.5.7.1 states: "A gain or loss on a financial asset or financial liability that is measured at fair value shall be recognised in profit or loss ..." while the IASB defined IFRS XBRL taxonomy <ref>{{cite web|title=IASB|url=https://www.ifrs.org/issued-standards/ifrs-taxonomy/ifrs-taxonomy-2021/}}</ref> includes OtherGainsLosses, GainsLossesOnNetMonetaryPosition and similar items. | |||
US GAAP does not define income but does define comprehensive income (CON 8.4.E75): Comprehensive income is the change in equity of a business entity during a period from transactions and other events and circumstances from nonowner sources. It includes all changes in equity during a period except those resulting from investments by owners and distributions to owners. | |||
According to ], income "is the maximum amount which can be spent during a period if there is to be an expectation of maintaining intact, the capital value of prospective receipts (in money terms)".<ref>{{cite web|title=Oxbridge Notes|url=https://www.oxbridgenotes.co.uk/revision_notes/accounting-lse-financial-accounting-analysis-and-valuation/samples/5-hicks-income|access-date=18 August 2016}}</ref> | |||
=="Nonincome"== | |||
=== Debt === | |||
Borrowing or repaying money is not income under any definition, for either the borrower or the lender.<ref name="Mc"/> Interest and ] are income. | |||
=== Psychic income === | |||
"Non-monetary joy," such as watching a sunset or having sex, simply is not income.<ref name="Mc"/> Similarly, nonmonetary suffering, such as heartbreak or ], are not negative income. This may seem trivial, but the non-inclusion of psychic income has important effects on economics and tax policy.<ref name="Mc"/> It encourages people to find happiness in nonmonetary, nontaxable ways and means that reported income may overstate or understate the well-being of a given individual.<ref name="Mc"/> | |||
== Income growth == | == Income growth == | ||
] has been increasing steadily in most countries.<ref>. ].</ref> Many factors contribute to people having a higher income, including ],<ref>. ].</ref> ] and favorable political circumstances such as ] and ]. Increases in income also tend to lead to people choosing to work fewer ]. | ] has been increasing steadily in most countries.<ref>. ].</ref> Many factors contribute to people having a higher income, including ],<ref>. ].</ref> ] and favorable political circumstances such as ] and ]. Increases in income also tend to lead to people choosing to work fewer ]. | ||
] (defined as countries with a "developed economy") have higher incomes as opposed to ] tending to have lower incomes. | ] (defined as countries with a "developed economy") have higher incomes as opposed to ] tending to have lower incomes. | ||
=== Factors contributing to higher income === | |||
Education has a positive effect on the level of income.<ref>Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.</ref><ref>Card, D. (1999). "The Causal Effect of Education on Earnings." In: Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D. (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3.</ref><ref>Moretti, E. (2004). "Estimating the Social Return to Higher Education: Evidence from Longitudinal and Repeated Cross-Sectional Data." Journal of Econometrics</ref> Education increases the skills of the workforce, which in turn increases its productivity (and thus higher wages). Gary Becker developed a Human Capital Theory, which emphasizes that investment in education and training lead to efficiency gains, and by extension to economic growth.<ref>Becker, G. S. (1964). Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education. Columbia University Press.</ref> | |||
Globalization can increase incomes by integrating markets, and allowing individuals greater possibilities of income increases through efficient allocation of resources and expanding existing wealth. | |||
Generally, countries more open to trade have higher incomes.<ref>Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2004). Trade, Growth, and Poverty. The Economic Journal, 114(493), F22–F49. <nowiki>http://www.jstor.org/stable/3590109</nowiki></ref> And while globalization tends to increase average income in a country, it does so unequally.<ref>Goldberg, P. K., & Pavcnik, N. (2007). "Distributional effects of globalization in developing countries." Journal of Economic Literature, 45(1), 39-82.</ref> Sachs and Warner claim, that “countries with open economies will converge to the same level of income, although admittedly it will take a long time.”<ref>Sachs, J. D., & Warner, A. M. (1995). "Economic reform and the process of global integration." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1995(1), 103.</ref> | |||
==Income inequality== | ==Income inequality== | ||
] is the extent to which income is distributed in an uneven manner. It can be measured by various methods, including the ] and the ]. Many economists argue that certain amounts of inequality are necessary and desirable but that excessive inequality leads to efficiency problems and social injustice.<ref name="Barr"/> | ] is the extent to which income is distributed in an uneven manner. It can be measured by various methods, including the ] and the ]. Many economists argue that certain amounts of inequality are necessary and desirable but that excessive inequality leads to efficiency problems and social injustice.<ref name="Barr"/> Thereby necessitating initiatives like the United Nations ] aimed at reducing inequality.<ref>{{Cite web|title=Goal 10 targets|url=https://www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/sustainable-development-goals/goal-10-reduced-inequalities/targets.html|access-date=2020-09-23|website=UNDP|language=en|archive-date=2020-11-27|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20201127140337/https://www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/sustainable-development-goals/goal-10-reduced-inequalities/targets.html|url-status=dead}}</ref> | ||
=== National Income === | |||
National income, measured by statistics such as ] (NNI), measures the total income of individuals, corporations, and government in the economy. For more information see ]. | National income, measured by statistics such as ] (NNI), measures the total income of individuals, corporations, and government in the economy. For more information see ]. | ||
The total output of an economy equals its total income. From this viewpoint, GDP can be an indicator and measurement of national income since it measures a nation’s total production of goods and services produced within the borders of one country and its total income simultaneously. GDP is measured through factors of production (inputs) and the production function (the ability to turn inputs into outputs). One important note in this is ] working through the factor market and how national income is divided among these factors. For this examination, the Neoclassical theory of distribution and factor prices is the modern theory to look into.<ref>{{Cite book |last=MANKIW |first=N. GREGORY |title=MACROECONOMICS |date=22 May 2015 |isbn=978-1-4641-8289-1 |edition=9th |pages=47–80|publisher=Macmillan Learning }}</ref> | |||
== Basic income == | |||
{{Main article|List of basic income models}} | |||
Basic income models advocate for a regular, and usually unconditional, receipt of money from the public institution. There are mana basic income models, with the most famous being Universal Basic Income. | |||
=== Universal Basic Income === | |||
{{Main article|Universal basic income}} | |||
Universal Basic Income is a periodic receival of cash given to individuals on universal and unconditional basis. Unlike other programs like the ]''',''' UBI provides eligible recipients with cash instead of coupons. Instead of households, it is paid to all individuals without requiring means test and regardless of employment status.<ref>{{cite web | url=https://basicincome.org/about-basic-income/ | title=About basic income }}</ref> | |||
The proponents of UBI argue, that basic income is needed for social protection, mitigating automation and labour market disruptions.<ref>{{cite journal | url=https://academic.oup.com/hsw/article-abstract/48/1/7/6917094?redirectedFrom=fulltext&login=false | doi=10.1093/hsw/hlac040 | title=Universal Basic Income: A Synopsis for Social Work | date=2023 | last1=Evans | first1=Ethan J. | journal=Health & Social Work | volume=48 | pages=7–10 }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal | url=https://academic.oup.com/sw/article-abstract/64/4/321/5576193?login=false | doi=10.1093/sw/swz028 | title=Universal Basic Income, Poverty, and Social Justice: A Moral and Economic Imperative for Social Workers | date=2019 | last1=Hamilton | first1=Leah | last2=Martin-West | first2=Stacia | journal=Social Work | volume=64 | issue=4 | pages=321–328 | pmid=31566240 }}</ref> Opponents argue that UBI, in addition to being costly, will distort incentives for individuals to work. They might argue that there are other and more cost-effective policies that can tackle problems raised by the proponents of UBI. These policies include for example negative income tax.<ref>{{cite web | url=https://journalistsresource.org/economics/universal-basic-income-guaranteed-income-ubi/ | title=Universal basic income: Money for nothing or efficient equalizer? | date=15 February 2017 }}</ref> | |||
==Income in philosophy and ethics== | ==Income in philosophy and ethics== | ||
Throughout history, many have written about the impact of income on ] and ]. ] wrote 'For the love of money is a root of all kinds of evil:' (] (])). | Throughout history, many have written about the impact of income on ] and ]. ] wrote 'For the love of money is a root of all kinds of evil:' (] (])). | ||
Some scholars have come to the conclusion that material progress and prosperity, as manifested in continuous income growth at both the individual and the national level, provide the indispensable foundation for sustaining any kind of morality. This argument was explicitly given by ] in his ''Theory of Moral Sentiments''{{ |
Some scholars have come to the conclusion that material progress and prosperity, as manifested in continuous income growth at both the individual and the national level, provide the indispensable foundation for sustaining any kind of morality. This argument was explicitly given by ] in his ''Theory of Moral Sentiments'',<ref>{{Cite book|last=Smith|first=Adam|url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/1017407319|title=The theory of moral sentiments|publisher=Clarendon|year=2009|isbn=|location=Oxford|pages=|language=English|oclc=1017407319}}</ref> and has more recently been developed by Harvard economist ] in his book ''The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth''.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Friedman|first=Benjamin M|url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/71353264|title=The moral consequences of economic growth|date=2006|publisher=Vintage Books|isbn=978-1-4000-9571-1|location=New York, NY|language=English|oclc=71353264}}</ref> | ||
==Income and health== | |||
==Accountancy== | |||
{{multiple image | total_width=450 | |||
The ] (IASB) uses the following definition: "Income is increases in economic benefits during the accounting period in the form of inflows or enhancements of assets or decreases of liabilities that result in increases in equity, other than those relating to contributions from equity participants." (IFRS Framework). | |||
| image1= 20241113 Homicide rates vs gross national income per person, by country.svg |caption1= National homicide rates are generally lower in countries with higher gross national income (GNI) per person.<ref name=HomicideVsIncome>● Homicide data from {{cite web |author1=United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (UNODC) |title=Homicide rate, 2023 / Annual number of deaths from homicide per 100,000 people |url=https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/homicide-rate-unodc?tab=table |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20241113181658/https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/homicide-rate-unodc?tab=table |archive-date=13 November 2024 |date=2024 |quote=Data source: United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (2024) |url-status=live}}<br>● Income data from {{cite web |author1=United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) |title=Gross national income (GNI) per capita |url=https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/gross-national-income-per-capita-undp?tab=table |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20241113182218/https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/gross-national-income-per-capita-undp?tab=table |archive-date=13 November 2024 |date=2024 |url-status=live |quote=Data source: UNDP, Human Development Report (2024)}}</ref> | |||
| image2= 202411245 Homicide rate vs median disposable household income, by country.svg |caption2= Homicide rates show a stronger correlation with ''median'' personal income than for gross national income per person, as GNI is skewed toward extremely wealthy individual persons.<ref>● Homicide data from {{cite web |author1= United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (UNODC) |title=Homicide rate, 2023 / Annual number of deaths from homicide per 100,000 people |url=https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/homicide-rate-unodc?tab=table |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20241113181658/https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/homicide-rate-unodc?tab=table |archive-date=13 November 2024 |date=2024 |quote=Data source: United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (2024) |url-status=live}}<br>● Income data from {{cite web |author1=Luxembourg Income Study |title=Median income (after tax), 1963 to 2022 |url=https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/median-income-after-tax-lis |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20240923112231/https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/median-income-after-tax-lis |archive-date=23 September 2024 |date=2024 |quote= This data is adjusted for inflation and for differences in the cost of living between countries. Income here is measured after taxes and benefits. – Data source: Luxembourg Income Study (2024) – This data is measured in international-$ at 2017 prices. Income has been equivalized. |url-status=live}}</ref> | |||
}} | |||
A landmark ] from ] researchers in the ] found that income given in the form of ] leads to reductions in disease, improvements in food security and dietary diversity, increases in children's school attendance, decreases in extreme poverty, and higher health care spending.<ref name="doi10.1002/14651858.CD011135.pub2">{{cite journal |title=Unconditional cash transfers for reducing poverty and vulnerabilities: effect on use of health services and health outcomes in low- and middle-income countries |journal=Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews |volume=11 |pages=CD011135 |year=2017 |doi= 10.1002/14651858.CD011135.pub2 |last1=Pega |first1=Frank |last2=Liu |first2=Sze |last3=Walter |first3=Stefan |last4=Pabayo |first4=Roman |last5=Saith |first5=Ruhi |last6=Lhachimi |first6=Stefan |issue=4 |pmc=6486161 |pmid=29139110 }}</ref><ref name="doi10.1002/14651858.CD011135.pub3">{{cite journal |title=Unconditional cash transfers for reducing poverty and vulnerabilities: effect on use of health services and health outcomes in low- and middle-income countries |journal=Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews |volume=2022 |pages=CD011135 |year=2022 |doi= 10.1002/14651858.CD011135.pub3 |last1=Pega |first1=Frank |last2=Pabayo |first2=Roman |last3=Benny |first3=Claire |last4=Lee |first4=Eun-Young |last5=Lhachimi |first5=Stefan |last6=Liu |first6=Sze |issue=3 |pmid=35348196 |pmc=8962215 }}</ref> | |||
The Health Foundation published an analysis where people on the lower income spectrum were more likely to describe their health negatively. Higher income was associated with self-reported better health.<ref>The Health Foundation. (n.d.). Relationship between income and health - The Health Foundation. In ''The Health Foundation''. <nowiki>https://www.health.org.uk/evidence-hub/money-and-resources/income/relationship-between-income-and-health</nowiki></ref> Another study found that “an increase in household income of £1,000 is associated with a 3.6 month increase in life expectancy for both men and women.”<ref>The Health Foundation. (n.d.). Relationship between income and life expectancy by neighbourhood - The Health Foundation. In ''The Health Foundation''. <nowiki>https://www.health.org.uk/evidence-hub/money-and-resources/income/relationship-between-income-and-healthy-life-expectancy-by-neighbourhood</nowiki></ref> | |||
A study by a Professor of Epidemiology Michael G Marmot found argues that there are two ways which could explain a positive correlation between income and health: the ability to afford goods and services necessary for biological survival, and the ability to influence life circumstances.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Marmot |first=Michael |date=2002 |title=The influence of income on health: views of an epidemiologist |url=http://www.healthaffairs.org/doi/10.1377/hlthaff.21.2.31 |journal=Health Affairs |language=en |volume=21 |issue=2 |pages=31–46 |doi=10.1377/hlthaff.21.2.31|pmid=11900185 }}</ref> | |||
Russell Ecob and George Davey Smith found that there is a relationship between income and a number of health measures. Greater household equivalised income is associated with better health indicators such as height, waist–hip ratio, respiratory function, malaise, limiting long-term illness.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Ecob |first1=Russell |last2=Davey Smith |first2=George |date=1999 |title=Income and health: what is the nature of the relationship? |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0277953698003852 |journal=Social Science & Medicine |volume=48 |issue=5 |pages=693–705 |doi=10.1016/S0277-9536(98)00385-2|pmid=10080369 }}</ref> | |||
According to ], income "is the maximum amount which can be spent during a period if there is to be an expectation of maintaining intact, the capital value of prospective receipts (in money terms)”.<ref>{{cite web|title=Oxbridge Notes|url=https://www.oxbridgenotes.co.uk/revision_notes/accounting-lse-financial-accounting-analysis-and-valuation/samples/5-hicks-income|accessdate=18 August 2016}}</ref> | |||
==History== | ==History== | ||
John Hicks used "I" for income, but ] wrote to him in 1937, "''after trying both, I believe it is easier to use Y for income and I for investment.''" Some consider Y as an alternative letter for the |
Income is conventionally denoted by "Y" in economics. John Hicks used "I" for income, but ] wrote to him in 1937, "''after trying both, I believe it is easier to use Y for income and I for investment.''" Some consider Y as an alternative letter for the phoneme I in languages like Spanish,<ref>{{cite web|url=http://gregmankiw.blogspot.com/2016/12/why-y.html|title=Why Y?|date=December 21, 2016|website=Greg Mankiw's Blog}}</ref> although Y as the "]" was actually pronounced like the modern German ü or the phonetic /y/. | ||
==See also== | ==See also== | ||
{{Wiktionary|income}} | {{Wiktionary|income}} | ||
* ] | * ] | ||
* ] | * ] | ||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | * ] | ||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | * ] | ||
==References== | ==References== | ||
{{reflist}} | {{reflist}} | ||
* D. Usher (1987). "real income," ''The ]'', v. 4, pp. 104–5 | |||
==Further reading== | |||
* D. Usher (1987). "real income", ''The ]'', v. 4, pp. 104–5. | |||
{{Authority control}} | {{Authority control}} |
Latest revision as of 22:41, 14 December 2024
Wealth gained by a person or company within a given time period For the concept in U.S. law, see Income (United States legal definitions).This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. Find sources: "Income" – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (October 2010) (Learn how and when to remove this message) |
Income is the consumption and saving opportunity gained by an entity within a specified timeframe, which is generally expressed in monetary terms. Income is difficult to define conceptually and the definition may be different across fields. For example, a person's income in an economic sense may be different from their income as defined by law.
An extremely important definition of income is Haig–Simons income, which defines income as Consumption + Change in net worth and is widely used in economics.
For households and individuals in the United States, income is defined by tax law as a sum that includes any wage, salary, profit, interest payment, rent, or other form of earnings received in a calendar year. Discretionary income is often defined as gross income minus taxes and other deductions (e.g., mandatory pension contributions), and is widely used as a basis to compare the welfare of taxpayers.
In the field of public economics, the concept may comprise the accumulation of both monetary and non-monetary consumption ability, with the former (monetary) being used as a proxy for total income.
For a firm, gross income can be defined as sum of all revenue minus the cost of goods sold. Net income nets out expenses: net income equals revenue minus cost of goods sold, expenses, depreciation, interest, and taxes.
Economic definitions
Full and Haig–Simons income
Main article: Haig–Simons income"Full income" refers to the accumulation of both the monetary and the non-monetary consumption-ability of any given entity, such as a person or a household. According to what the economist Nicholas Barr describes as the "classical definition of income" (the 1938 Haig–Simons definition): "income may be defined as the... sum of (1) the market value of rights exercised in consumption and (2) the change in the value of the store of property rights..." Since the consumption potential of non-monetary goods, such as leisure, cannot be measured, monetary income may be thought of as a proxy for full income. As such, however, it is criticized for being unreliable, i.e. failing to accurately reflect affluence (and thus the consumption opportunities) of any given agent.
It omits the utility a person may derive from non-monetary income and, on a macroeconomic level, fails to accurately chart social welfare. According to Barr, "in practice money income as a proportion of total income varies widely and unsystematically. Non-observability of full income prevents a complete characterization of the individual opportunity set, forcing us to use the unreliable yardstick of money income.
Factor income
In economics, "factor income" is the return accruing for a person, or a nation, derived from the "factors of production": rental income, wages generated by labor, the interest created by capital, and profits from entrepreneurial ventures.
In consumer theory 'income' is another name for the "budget constraint", an amount to be spent on different goods x and y in quantities and at prices and . The basic equation for this is
This equation implies two things. First buying one more unit of good x implies buying less units of good y. So, is the relative price of a unit of x as to the number of units given up in y. Second, if the price of x falls for a fixed and fixed then its relative price falls. The usual hypothesis, the law of demand, is that the quantity demanded of x would increase at the lower price. The analysis can be generalized to more than two goods.
The theoretical generalization to more than one period is a multi-period wealth and income constraint. For example, the same person can gain more productive skills or acquire more productive income-earning assets to earn a higher income. In the multi-period case, something might also happen to the economy beyond the control of the individual to reduce (or increase) the flow of income. Changing measured income and its relation to consumption over time might be modeled accordingly, such as in the permanent income hypothesis.
Legal definitions
Definitions under the Internal Revenue Code
Main article: Internal Revenue Code section 61Except as otherwise provided in this subtitle, gross income means all income from whatever source derived, including (but not limited to) the following items: (1) Compensation for services, including fees, commissions, fringe benefits, and similar items; (2) Gross income derived from business; (3) Gains derived from dealings in property; (4) Interest; (5) Rents; (6) Royalties; (7) Dividends; (8) Annuities; (9) Income from life insurance and endowment contracts; (10) Pensions; (11) Income from discharge of indebtedness; (12) Distributive share of partnership gross income; (13) Income in respect of a decedent; and (14) Income from an interest in an estate or trust.
26 U.S. Code § 61 - Gross income defined. There are also some statutory exclusions from income.
Definition under US Case law
Main article: Commissioner v. Glenshaw Glass Co.Income is an "undeniable accessions to wealth, clearly realized, and over which the taxpayer has complete dominion." Commentators say that this is a pretty good definition of income.
Taxable income is usually lower than Haig-Simons income. This is because unrealized appreciation (e.g., the increase in the value of stock over the course of a year) is economic income but not taxable income, and because there are many statutory exclusions from taxable income, including workman's compensation, SSI, gifts, child support, and in-kind government transfers.
Accounting definitions
Main article: Income (United States legal definitions)The International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) uses the following definition: "Income is increases in economic benefits during the accounting period in the form of inflows or enhancements of assets or decreases of liabilities that result in increases in equity, other than those relating to contributions from equity participants." (IFRS Framework).
Previously the IFRS conceptual framework (4.29) stated: "The definition of income encompasses both revenue and gains. Revenue arises in the course of the ordinary activities of an entity and is referred to by a variety of different names including sales, fees, interest, dividends, royalties and rent. 4.30: Gains represent other items that meet the definition of income and may, or may not, arise in the course of the ordinary activities of an entity. Gains represent increases in economic benefits and as such are no different in nature from revenue. Hence, they are not regarded as constituting a separate element in this Conceptual Framework."
The current IFRS conceptual framework (4.68) no longer draws a distinction between revenue and gains. Nevertheless, the distinction continues to be drawn at the standard and reporting levels. For example, IFRS 9.5.7.1 states: "A gain or loss on a financial asset or financial liability that is measured at fair value shall be recognised in profit or loss ..." while the IASB defined IFRS XBRL taxonomy includes OtherGainsLosses, GainsLossesOnNetMonetaryPosition and similar items.
US GAAP does not define income but does define comprehensive income (CON 8.4.E75): Comprehensive income is the change in equity of a business entity during a period from transactions and other events and circumstances from nonowner sources. It includes all changes in equity during a period except those resulting from investments by owners and distributions to owners.
According to John Hicks' definitions, income "is the maximum amount which can be spent during a period if there is to be an expectation of maintaining intact, the capital value of prospective receipts (in money terms)".
"Nonincome"
Debt
Borrowing or repaying money is not income under any definition, for either the borrower or the lender. Interest and forgiveness of debt are income.
Psychic income
"Non-monetary joy," such as watching a sunset or having sex, simply is not income. Similarly, nonmonetary suffering, such as heartbreak or labor, are not negative income. This may seem trivial, but the non-inclusion of psychic income has important effects on economics and tax policy. It encourages people to find happiness in nonmonetary, nontaxable ways and means that reported income may overstate or understate the well-being of a given individual.
Income growth
Income per capita has been increasing steadily in most countries. Many factors contribute to people having a higher income, including education, globalisation and favorable political circumstances such as economic freedom and peace. Increases in income also tend to lead to people choosing to work fewer hours. Developed countries (defined as countries with a "developed economy") have higher incomes as opposed to developing countries tending to have lower incomes.
Factors contributing to higher income
Education has a positive effect on the level of income. Education increases the skills of the workforce, which in turn increases its productivity (and thus higher wages). Gary Becker developed a Human Capital Theory, which emphasizes that investment in education and training lead to efficiency gains, and by extension to economic growth.
Globalization can increase incomes by integrating markets, and allowing individuals greater possibilities of income increases through efficient allocation of resources and expanding existing wealth.
Generally, countries more open to trade have higher incomes. And while globalization tends to increase average income in a country, it does so unequally. Sachs and Warner claim, that “countries with open economies will converge to the same level of income, although admittedly it will take a long time.”
Income inequality
Income inequality is the extent to which income is distributed in an uneven manner. It can be measured by various methods, including the Lorenz curve and the Gini coefficient. Many economists argue that certain amounts of inequality are necessary and desirable but that excessive inequality leads to efficiency problems and social injustice. Thereby necessitating initiatives like the United Nations Sustainable Development Goal 10 aimed at reducing inequality.
National Income
National income, measured by statistics such as net national income (NNI), measures the total income of individuals, corporations, and government in the economy. For more information see Measures of national income and output.
The total output of an economy equals its total income. From this viewpoint, GDP can be an indicator and measurement of national income since it measures a nation’s total production of goods and services produced within the borders of one country and its total income simultaneously. GDP is measured through factors of production (inputs) and the production function (the ability to turn inputs into outputs). One important note in this is income distribution working through the factor market and how national income is divided among these factors. For this examination, the Neoclassical theory of distribution and factor prices is the modern theory to look into.
Basic income
Main article: List of basic income modelsBasic income models advocate for a regular, and usually unconditional, receipt of money from the public institution. There are mana basic income models, with the most famous being Universal Basic Income.
Universal Basic Income
Main article: Universal basic incomeUniversal Basic Income is a periodic receival of cash given to individuals on universal and unconditional basis. Unlike other programs like the Food Stamp Program, UBI provides eligible recipients with cash instead of coupons. Instead of households, it is paid to all individuals without requiring means test and regardless of employment status.
The proponents of UBI argue, that basic income is needed for social protection, mitigating automation and labour market disruptions. Opponents argue that UBI, in addition to being costly, will distort incentives for individuals to work. They might argue that there are other and more cost-effective policies that can tackle problems raised by the proponents of UBI. These policies include for example negative income tax.
Income in philosophy and ethics
Throughout history, many have written about the impact of income on morality and society. Saint Paul wrote 'For the love of money is a root of all kinds of evil:' (1 Timothy 6:10 (ASV)).
Some scholars have come to the conclusion that material progress and prosperity, as manifested in continuous income growth at both the individual and the national level, provide the indispensable foundation for sustaining any kind of morality. This argument was explicitly given by Adam Smith in his Theory of Moral Sentiments, and has more recently been developed by Harvard economist Benjamin Friedman in his book The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth.
Income and health
National homicide rates are generally lower in countries with higher gross national income (GNI) per person.Homicide rates show a stronger correlation with median personal income than for gross national income per person, as GNI is skewed toward extremely wealthy individual persons.A landmark systematic review from Harvard University researchers in the Cochrane Collaboration found that income given in the form of unconditional cash transfers leads to reductions in disease, improvements in food security and dietary diversity, increases in children's school attendance, decreases in extreme poverty, and higher health care spending.
The Health Foundation published an analysis where people on the lower income spectrum were more likely to describe their health negatively. Higher income was associated with self-reported better health. Another study found that “an increase in household income of £1,000 is associated with a 3.6 month increase in life expectancy for both men and women.”
A study by a Professor of Epidemiology Michael G Marmot found argues that there are two ways which could explain a positive correlation between income and health: the ability to afford goods and services necessary for biological survival, and the ability to influence life circumstances.
Russell Ecob and George Davey Smith found that there is a relationship between income and a number of health measures. Greater household equivalised income is associated with better health indicators such as height, waist–hip ratio, respiratory function, malaise, limiting long-term illness.
History
Income is conventionally denoted by "Y" in economics. John Hicks used "I" for income, but Keynes wrote to him in 1937, "after trying both, I believe it is easier to use Y for income and I for investment." Some consider Y as an alternative letter for the phoneme I in languages like Spanish, although Y as the "Greek I" was actually pronounced like the modern German ü or the phonetic /y/.
See also
- Citizen's dividend
- Comprehensive income
- Disposable household and per capita income
- Guaranteed minimum income
- List of countries by GNI (nominal) per capita
- List of countries by GNI (PPP) per capita
- List of countries by GNI per capita growth
- Median income
- Income tax
- Real income
- Revenue
- Social dividend
- Universal basic income
- Unpaid work
References
- ^ Barr, N. (2004). Problems and definition of measurement. In Economics of the welfare state. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 121–124
- ^ McCaffery, Edward (2012). The Oxford Introductions to U.S. Law: Income Tax Law 1st Edition. Oxford University Press.
- Case, K. & Fair, R. (2007). Principles of Economics. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education. p. 54.
- Staff (2012). "factor income". BusinessDictionary.com. WebFinance, Inc. Archived from the original on 18 June 2012. Retrieved 20 June 2012. m
- Brooks, John R., "The Definitions of Income" (2018). Georgetown Law Faculty Publications and Other Works. 1952. https://scholarship.law.georgetown.edu/facpub/1952/
- admin. "Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting 2018". www.iasplus.com. Retrieved 2022-06-28.
- "IASB".
- "IASB".
- "Oxbridge Notes". Retrieved 18 August 2016.
- "Gapminder World". Gapminder Foundation.
- "Gapminder World". Gapminder Foundation.
- Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.
- Card, D. (1999). "The Causal Effect of Education on Earnings." In: Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D. (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3.
- Moretti, E. (2004). "Estimating the Social Return to Higher Education: Evidence from Longitudinal and Repeated Cross-Sectional Data." Journal of Econometrics
- Becker, G. S. (1964). Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education. Columbia University Press.
- Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2004). Trade, Growth, and Poverty. The Economic Journal, 114(493), F22–F49. http://www.jstor.org/stable/3590109
- Goldberg, P. K., & Pavcnik, N. (2007). "Distributional effects of globalization in developing countries." Journal of Economic Literature, 45(1), 39-82.
- Sachs, J. D., & Warner, A. M. (1995). "Economic reform and the process of global integration." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1995(1), 103.
- "Goal 10 targets". UNDP. Archived from the original on 2020-11-27. Retrieved 2020-09-23.
- MANKIW, N. GREGORY (22 May 2015). MACROECONOMICS (9th ed.). Macmillan Learning. pp. 47–80. ISBN 978-1-4641-8289-1.
- "About basic income".
- Evans, Ethan J. (2023). "Universal Basic Income: A Synopsis for Social Work". Health & Social Work. 48: 7–10. doi:10.1093/hsw/hlac040.
- Hamilton, Leah; Martin-West, Stacia (2019). "Universal Basic Income, Poverty, and Social Justice: A Moral and Economic Imperative for Social Workers". Social Work. 64 (4): 321–328. doi:10.1093/sw/swz028. PMID 31566240.
- "Universal basic income: Money for nothing or efficient equalizer?". 15 February 2017.
- Smith, Adam (2009). The theory of moral sentiments. Oxford: Clarendon. OCLC 1017407319.
- Friedman, Benjamin M (2006). The moral consequences of economic growth. New York, NY: Vintage Books. ISBN 978-1-4000-9571-1. OCLC 71353264.
- ● Homicide data from United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (UNODC) (2024). "Homicide rate, 2023 / Annual number of deaths from homicide per 100,000 people". Archived from the original on 13 November 2024.
Data source: United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (2024)
● Income data from United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) (2024). "Gross national income (GNI) per capita". Archived from the original on 13 November 2024.Data source: UNDP, Human Development Report (2024)
- ● Homicide data from United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (UNODC) (2024). "Homicide rate, 2023 / Annual number of deaths from homicide per 100,000 people". Archived from the original on 13 November 2024.
Data source: United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (2024)
● Income data from Luxembourg Income Study (2024). "Median income (after tax), 1963 to 2022". Archived from the original on 23 September 2024.This data is adjusted for inflation and for differences in the cost of living between countries. Income here is measured after taxes and benefits. – Data source: Luxembourg Income Study (2024) – This data is measured in international-$ at 2017 prices. Income has been equivalized.
- Pega, Frank; Liu, Sze; Walter, Stefan; Pabayo, Roman; Saith, Ruhi; Lhachimi, Stefan (2017). "Unconditional cash transfers for reducing poverty and vulnerabilities: effect on use of health services and health outcomes in low- and middle-income countries". Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews. 11 (4): CD011135. doi:10.1002/14651858.CD011135.pub2. PMC 6486161. PMID 29139110.
- Pega, Frank; Pabayo, Roman; Benny, Claire; Lee, Eun-Young; Lhachimi, Stefan; Liu, Sze (2022). "Unconditional cash transfers for reducing poverty and vulnerabilities: effect on use of health services and health outcomes in low- and middle-income countries". Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews. 2022 (3): CD011135. doi:10.1002/14651858.CD011135.pub3. PMC 8962215. PMID 35348196.
- The Health Foundation. (n.d.). Relationship between income and health - The Health Foundation. In The Health Foundation. https://www.health.org.uk/evidence-hub/money-and-resources/income/relationship-between-income-and-health
- The Health Foundation. (n.d.). Relationship between income and life expectancy by neighbourhood - The Health Foundation. In The Health Foundation. https://www.health.org.uk/evidence-hub/money-and-resources/income/relationship-between-income-and-healthy-life-expectancy-by-neighbourhood
- Marmot, Michael (2002). "The influence of income on health: views of an epidemiologist". Health Affairs. 21 (2): 31–46. doi:10.1377/hlthaff.21.2.31. PMID 11900185.
- Ecob, Russell; Davey Smith, George (1999). "Income and health: what is the nature of the relationship?". Social Science & Medicine. 48 (5): 693–705. doi:10.1016/S0277-9536(98)00385-2. PMID 10080369.
- "Why Y?". Greg Mankiw's Blog. December 21, 2016.
Further reading
- D. Usher (1987). "real income", The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 4, pp. 104–5.