Misplaced Pages

Simple majority voting: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editNext edit →Content deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 06:13, 21 December 2007 editAbd (talk | contribs)14,259 edits trim back article, cut the math. it's a start.← Previous edit Revision as of 10:28, 5 February 2008 edit undoTualha (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users1,849 edits +{{Electoral systems}}Next edit →
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Mergeto|Plurality voting system|date=December 2007}} {{Mergeto|Plurality voting system|date=December 2007}}



{{Unreferenced|date=July 2006}} {{Unreferenced|date=July 2006}}


{{Electoral systems}}
'''Simple majority voting''' is a common form of voting where, given two options, the option receiving a simple majority of votes wins, a well-known example of democratic procedure. It is informally used in small groups to make all kinds of practical decisions, by counting hands in a group or judging the loudness of the cheers in a crowd. However, ] states that any ] rule that satisfies certain conditions, will turn out to be the simple majority rule. '''Simple majority voting''' is a common form of voting where, given two options, the option receiving a simple majority of votes wins, a well-known example of democratic procedure. It is informally used in small groups to make all kinds of practical decisions, by counting hands in a group or judging the loudness of the cheers in a crowd. However, ] states that any ] rule that satisfies certain conditions, will turn out to be the simple majority rule.



Revision as of 10:28, 5 February 2008

It has been suggested that this article be merged into Plurality voting system. (Discuss) Proposed since December 2007.
This article does not cite any sources. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.
Find sources: "Simple majority voting" – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (July 2006) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
A joint Politics and Economics series
Social choice and electoral systems
Single-winner methodsSingle vote - plurality methods

Condorcet methods


Positional voting


Cardinal voting

Proportional representationParty-list

Quota-remainder methods


Approval-based committees


Fractional social choice


Semi-proportional representation

Mixed systemsBy results of combination
By mechanism of combination

By ballot type

Paradoxes and pathologiesSpoiler effects

Pathological response


Strategic voting


Paradoxes of majority rule

Social and collective choiceImpossibility theorems

Positive results

icon Mathematics portal

Simple majority voting is a common form of voting where, given two options, the option receiving a simple majority of votes wins, a well-known example of democratic procedure. It is informally used in small groups to make all kinds of practical decisions, by counting hands in a group or judging the loudness of the cheers in a crowd. However, May’s theorem states that any social choice rule that satisfies certain conditions, will turn out to be the simple majority rule.

May's Theorem

Manipulability by voters is as such unobservable, but doesn’t constitute a problem with simple majority voting, since in a two option case, it is impossible to manipulate the result by voting strategically. May states that, since group choice must depend only upon individual preferences concerning the alternatives in a set, a pattern of group choice may be built up if we know the group preference for each pair of alternatives. However, manipulability in a more options case is not as simple as it sounds.

Definition Simple majority voting is an example of a social choice rule: the winning choice is the one whose number of votes is greater than half of the voters who are not indifferent between the two choices. This is in contrast with absolute majority voting, where the winner is the option which gets more than half of all votes, including abstentions.

Properties

Simple majority voting satisfies the property of universal domain: it assigns an unambiguous value to every logically possible list of individual preferences. In other words, whatever every individual chooses, the procedure always yields a result. This trait is sometimes referred to as decisiveness.

Secondly, simple majority voting satisfies anonymity: it assigns the same value to two lists that are permutations of one another. This means that when two people change their votes in such a way that the number of voters for each option remains the same, than the result remains the same. The procedure does not care about which voter votes for an option, only about how many voters vote for that option. If the result changed, that would mean that one of those two votes overrides all the other votes, which comes down to a dictatorship.

Simple majority voting also satisfies neutrality: if everyone reverses their vote, the result is reversed, a tie remains a tie.

As fourth and last property, simple majority voting satisfies positive responsiveness. If one of the two options has more or equally many votes as the other option and one voter changes his mind in favor of that first option, then the result will also change in favor of that option: a tie becomes a win and a win stays a win.

See also:

Categories: