Revision as of 20:39, 28 March 2001 editJimbo Wales (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users, Founder14,538 editsmNo edit summary | Revision as of 12:44, 19 October 2001 edit undoZundark (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users, File movers, Pending changes reviewers29,653 editsm superceded -> supersededNext edit → | ||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
A theory in ] that the price of a commodity | |||
A form of intrinsic value theory that is a cornerstone of ]. The labor theory of value, like all intrinsic value theories, holds that there is a 'true' value for any item, and that this true value is determined by the amount of labor that went into its production. | |||
traded on a market tends toward the labor time required | |||
to produce that commodity. The labor theory of value is | |||
popularly associated with ] and | |||
]. It is an theory of objective value, | |||
superseded in much of Western economics by the turn | |||
toward ] | |||
associated with the development of ] | |||
in the 1870s. | |||
The labor needed to produce a commodity includes both | |||
labor directly expended on production of the commodity | |||
and labor expended on the production of capital goods | |||
used up in the production of the commodity. For example, | |||
if twenty workers are used for a year to produce capital | |||
goods used by twenty workers in the next year to | |||
produce a consumer good, the consumer good embodies | |||
the labor of forty workers. | |||
This theory supports a highly political conclusion, that the role of owners and managers in production is exploitative, since it is only the workers that add value to the product. | This theory supports a highly political conclusion, that the role of owners and managers in production is exploitative, since it is only the workers that add value to the product. | ||
The price of the product is said to tend towards the sum | |||
of the value of the capital goods used up in production | |||
and the value added by direct labor. But profit, interest, | |||
rent, etc. is only possible, according to the theory, | |||
if the wages of these direct workers do not fully compensate | |||
them for the value they add to the capital goods to | |||
produce the product. | |||
The classical economists and Marx quickly realized that | |||
Today the labor theory of value is not taken seriously by economists, and is accepted only by those who support the political conclusions that it implies. | |||
the labor theory of value could not be exactly true. | |||
Suppose the proportion of unpaid to paid labor time is | |||
A ] of this theory would go as follows: Say two men each set out to build a shed. One is skillful and experienced and completes the shed in five hours. The other lacks skill and experience, and must work twice as long to build an identical shed. According to the labor theory of value, the second shed should have twice the value of the first, because twice as much labor went into it, despite the fact that they are in all other respects identical. | |||
the same for all workers. Further suppose that workers | |||
are paid when the product is sold. | |||
Marxists will respond that this is a misrepresentation of the meaning of the labor theory of value. Even Marx deals with the problem of unequal abilities in chapter one of volume one of ]. Perhaps the clearest exposition of Marx's view on this question can be found in ]: | |||
Technology will result in | |||
the ratio of direct labor to the value of capital goods | |||
<i>Does labour time, as the measure of value, suppose at least that the days are equivalent, and that one man's day is worth as much as another's? No.</i> | |||
differing among industries. If products were traded | |||
based on labor values, prices would result in different | |||
industries earning different rates of profits on the | |||
capital invested. But competition among industries | |||
should be modeled as tending to remove differences | |||
in profitability. Thus, the labor theory of value | |||
cannot be true. ] presented a numerical | |||
example of this ]: | |||
<i>Suppose I employ twenty men at an expense of 1000 pounds | |||
<i>Let us suppose for a moment that a jeweller's day is equivalent to three days of a weaver; the fact remains that any change in the value of jewels relative to that of woven materials, unless it be the transitory result of the fluctuation of demand and supply, must have as its cause a reduction or an increase in the labour time expended in the production of one or the other. If three working days of different workers be related to one another in the ratio 1:2:3, then a change in the relative value of their products will be a change in the same proportion of 1:2:3. Thus values can be measured by labour time, in spite of the inequality of value of different working days; but to apply such a measure we must have a comparative scale of the different working days: it is competition that sets up this scale.</i> | |||
for a year in the production of a commodity, and at the end | |||
of the year I employ twenty men again for another year, at | |||
The overall point here is that <i>for a given set of skill levels throughout the economy</i>, the overall rate of profit must be zero unless some workers are 'exploited' in the Marxist sense. This, it is said, can be demonstrated without a claim that all laborers are equal. | |||
a further expense of 1000 pounds in finishing or perfecting | |||
the same commodity, and that I bring it to market at the end | |||
of two years, if profits be 10 per cent., my commodity must | |||
sell for 2,310 pounds.; for I have employed 1000 pounds | |||
capital for one year, and 2,100 pounds capital for one year | |||
more. Another man employs precisely the same quantity of | |||
labour, but he employs it all in the first year; he employs | |||
forty men at an expense of 2000 pounds, and at the end of | |||
the first year he sells it with 10 per cent. profit, or | |||
for 2,200 pounds. Here then are two commodities | |||
having precisely the same quantity of labour bestowed on | |||
them, one of which sells for 2,310 pounds - the other | |||
for 2,200 pounds.</i> | |||
There are other difficulties with the labor theory of | |||
Modern economists respond by pointing out that if the labor theory of value means this, then it isn't really a labor theory at all. | |||
value associated with varying skills among heterogeneous | |||
workers, land rent, and machinery. The above logical | |||
consequence of varying capital intensity has been the | |||
main focus of economic analysis of Marxist economics. | |||
Discussion | |||
of this aspect of the theory goes on under the rubric | |||
of the transformation problem, since it is about the | |||
"transformation" of labor values to prices. | |||
---- | |||
/Talk | /Talk |
Revision as of 12:44, 19 October 2001
A theory in economics that the price of a commodity traded on a market tends toward the labor time required to produce that commodity. The labor theory of value is popularly associated with classical economics and Marxism. It is an theory of objective value, superseded in much of Western economics by the turn toward economic subjectivism associated with the development of neoclassical economics in the 1870s.
The labor needed to produce a commodity includes both labor directly expended on production of the commodity and labor expended on the production of capital goods used up in the production of the commodity. For example, if twenty workers are used for a year to produce capital goods used by twenty workers in the next year to produce a consumer good, the consumer good embodies the labor of forty workers.
This theory supports a highly political conclusion, that the role of owners and managers in production is exploitative, since it is only the workers that add value to the product. The price of the product is said to tend towards the sum of the value of the capital goods used up in production and the value added by direct labor. But profit, interest, rent, etc. is only possible, according to the theory, if the wages of these direct workers do not fully compensate them for the value they add to the capital goods to produce the product.
The classical economists and Marx quickly realized that the labor theory of value could not be exactly true. Suppose the proportion of unpaid to paid labor time is the same for all workers. Further suppose that workers are paid when the product is sold. Technology will result in the ratio of direct labor to the value of capital goods differing among industries. If products were traded based on labor values, prices would result in different industries earning different rates of profits on the capital invested. But competition among industries should be modeled as tending to remove differences in profitability. Thus, the labor theory of value cannot be true. David Ricardo presented a numerical example of this Reductio ad absurdum:
Suppose I employ twenty men at an expense of 1000 pounds for a year in the production of a commodity, and at the end of the year I employ twenty men again for another year, at a further expense of 1000 pounds in finishing or perfecting the same commodity, and that I bring it to market at the end of two years, if profits be 10 per cent., my commodity must sell for 2,310 pounds.; for I have employed 1000 pounds capital for one year, and 2,100 pounds capital for one year more. Another man employs precisely the same quantity of labour, but he employs it all in the first year; he employs forty men at an expense of 2000 pounds, and at the end of the first year he sells it with 10 per cent. profit, or for 2,200 pounds. Here then are two commodities having precisely the same quantity of labour bestowed on them, one of which sells for 2,310 pounds - the other for 2,200 pounds.
There are other difficulties with the labor theory of value associated with varying skills among heterogeneous workers, land rent, and machinery. The above logical consequence of varying capital intensity has been the main focus of economic analysis of Marxist economics. Discussion of this aspect of the theory goes on under the rubric of the transformation problem, since it is about the "transformation" of labor values to prices.
/Talk