Revision as of 12:44, 19 October 2001 editZundark (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users, File movers, Pending changes reviewers29,653 editsm superceded -> superseded← Previous edit | Revision as of 18:29, 19 October 2001 edit undoLee Daniel Crocker (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users4,417 editsmNo edit summaryNext edit → | ||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
The '''labor theory of value''' is a | |||
⚫ | |||
⚫ | theory in ] that the price of a commodity | ||
traded on a market tends toward the labor time required | traded on a market tends toward the labor time required | ||
to produce that commodity. The labor theory of value is | to produce that commodity. The labor theory of value is | ||
popularly associated with ] and | popularly associated with ] and | ||
]. It is |
]. It is a theory of objective value, | ||
superseded in much of Western economics by the turn | superseded in much of Western economics by the turn | ||
toward ] | toward ] | ||
associated with the development of ] | associated with the development of ] | ||
in the 1870s. | in the 1870s. | ||
The labor needed to produce a commodity includes both | The labor needed to produce a commodity includes both | ||
labor directly expended on production of the commodity | labor directly expended on production of the commodity | ||
and labor expended on the production of capital goods | and labor expended on the production of capital goods | ||
used up in the production of the commodity. For example, | used up in the production of the commodity. For example, | ||
if twenty workers are used for a year to produce capital | if twenty workers are used for a year to produce capital | ||
goods used by twenty workers in the next year to | goods used by twenty workers in the next year to | ||
produce a consumer good, the consumer good embodies | produce a consumer good, the consumer good embodies | ||
the labor of forty workers. | the labor of forty workers. | ||
This theory supports a highly political conclusion, that the role of owners and managers in production is exploitative, since it is only the workers that add value to the product. | This theory supports a highly political conclusion, that the role of owners and managers in production is exploitative, since it is only the workers that add value to the product. | ||
The price of the product is said to tend towards the sum | The price of the product is said to tend towards the sum | ||
of the value of the capital goods used up in production | of the value of the capital goods used up in production | ||
and the value added by direct labor. But profit, interest, | and the value added by direct labor. But profit, interest, | ||
rent, etc. is only possible, according to the theory, | rent, etc. is only possible, according to the theory, | ||
if the wages of these direct workers do not fully compensate | if the wages of these direct workers do not fully compensate | ||
them for the value they add to the capital goods to | them for the value they add to the capital goods to | ||
produce the product. | produce the product. | ||
The classical economists and Marx quickly realized that | The classical economists and Marx quickly realized that | ||
the labor theory of value could not be exactly true. | the labor theory of value could not be exactly true. | ||
Suppose the proportion of unpaid to paid labor time is | Suppose the proportion of unpaid to paid labor time is | ||
the same for all workers. Further suppose that workers | the same for all workers. Further suppose that workers | ||
are paid when the product is sold. | are paid when the product is sold. | ||
Technology will result in | Technology will result in | ||
the ratio of direct labor to the value of capital goods | the ratio of direct labor to the value of capital goods | ||
differing among industries. If products were traded | differing among industries. If products were traded | ||
based on labor values, prices would result in different | based on labor values, prices would result in different | ||
industries earning different rates of profits on the | industries earning different rates of profits on the | ||
capital invested. But competition among industries | capital invested. But competition among industries | ||
should be modeled as tending to remove differences | should be modeled as tending to remove differences | ||
in profitability. Thus, the labor theory of value | in profitability. Thus, the labor theory of value | ||
cannot be true. ] presented a numerical | cannot be true. ] presented a numerical | ||
example of this ]: | example of this ]: | ||
<i>Suppose I employ twenty men at an expense of 1000 pounds | <i>Suppose I employ twenty men at an expense of 1000 pounds | ||
for a year in the production of a commodity, and at the end | for a year in the production of a commodity, and at the end | ||
of the year I employ twenty men again for another year, at | of the year I employ twenty men again for another year, at | ||
a further expense of 1000 pounds in finishing or perfecting | a further expense of 1000 pounds in finishing or perfecting | ||
the same commodity, and that I bring it to market at the end | the same commodity, and that I bring it to market at the end | ||
of two years, if profits be 10 per cent., my commodity must | of two years, if profits be 10 per cent., my commodity must | ||
sell for 2,310 pounds.; for I have employed 1000 pounds | sell for 2,310 pounds.; for I have employed 1000 pounds | ||
capital for one year, and 2,100 pounds capital for one year | capital for one year, and 2,100 pounds capital for one year | ||
more. Another man employs precisely the same quantity of | more. Another man employs precisely the same quantity of | ||
labour, but he employs it all in the first year; he employs | labour, but he employs it all in the first year; he employs | ||
forty men at an expense of 2000 pounds, and at the end of | forty men at an expense of 2000 pounds, and at the end of | ||
the first year he sells it with 10 per cent. profit, or | the first year he sells it with 10 per cent. profit, or | ||
for 2,200 pounds. Here then are two commodities | for 2,200 pounds. Here then are two commodities | ||
having precisely the same quantity of labour bestowed on | having precisely the same quantity of labour bestowed on | ||
them, one of which sells for 2,310 pounds |
them, one of which sells for 2,310 pounds--the other | ||
for 2,200 pounds.</i> | for 2,200 pounds.</i> | ||
There are other difficulties with the labor theory of | There are other difficulties with the labor theory of | ||
value associated with varying skills among heterogeneous | value associated with varying skills among heterogeneous | ||
workers, land rent, and machinery. The above logical | workers, land rent, and machinery. The above logical | ||
consequence of varying capital intensity has been the | consequence of varying capital intensity has been the | ||
main focus of economic analysis of Marxist economics. | main focus of economic analysis of Marxist economics. | ||
Discussion | Discussion | ||
of this aspect of the theory goes on under the rubric | of this aspect of the theory goes on under the rubric | ||
of the transformation problem, since it is about the | of the transformation problem, since it is about the | ||
"transformation" of labor values to prices. | "transformation" of labor values to prices. | ||
---- | ---- | ||
/Talk | /Talk | ||
Revision as of 18:29, 19 October 2001
The labor theory of value is a
theory in economics that the price of a commodity
traded on a market tends toward the labor time required
to produce that commodity. The labor theory of value is
popularly associated with classical economics and
Marxism. It is a theory of objective value,
superseded in much of Western economics by the turn
toward economic subjectivism
associated with the development of neoclassical economics
in the 1870s.
The labor needed to produce a commodity includes both
labor directly expended on production of the commodity
and labor expended on the production of capital goods
used up in the production of the commodity. For example,
if twenty workers are used for a year to produce capital
goods used by twenty workers in the next year to
produce a consumer good, the consumer good embodies
the labor of forty workers.
This theory supports a highly political conclusion, that the role of owners and managers in production is exploitative, since it is only the workers that add value to the product.
The price of the product is said to tend towards the sum
of the value of the capital goods used up in production
and the value added by direct labor. But profit, interest,
rent, etc. is only possible, according to the theory,
if the wages of these direct workers do not fully compensate
them for the value they add to the capital goods to
produce the product.
The classical economists and Marx quickly realized that
the labor theory of value could not be exactly true.
Suppose the proportion of unpaid to paid labor time is
the same for all workers. Further suppose that workers
are paid when the product is sold.
Technology will result in
the ratio of direct labor to the value of capital goods
differing among industries. If products were traded
based on labor values, prices would result in different
industries earning different rates of profits on the
capital invested. But competition among industries
should be modeled as tending to remove differences
in profitability. Thus, the labor theory of value
cannot be true. David Ricardo presented a numerical
example of this reductio ad absurdum:
Suppose I employ twenty men at an expense of 1000 pounds
for a year in the production of a commodity, and at the end
of the year I employ twenty men again for another year, at
a further expense of 1000 pounds in finishing or perfecting
the same commodity, and that I bring it to market at the end
of two years, if profits be 10 per cent., my commodity must
sell for 2,310 pounds.; for I have employed 1000 pounds
capital for one year, and 2,100 pounds capital for one year
more. Another man employs precisely the same quantity of
labour, but he employs it all in the first year; he employs
forty men at an expense of 2000 pounds, and at the end of
the first year he sells it with 10 per cent. profit, or
for 2,200 pounds. Here then are two commodities
having precisely the same quantity of labour bestowed on
them, one of which sells for 2,310 pounds--the other
for 2,200 pounds.
There are other difficulties with the labor theory of
value associated with varying skills among heterogeneous
workers, land rent, and machinery. The above logical
consequence of varying capital intensity has been the
main focus of economic analysis of Marxist economics.
Discussion
of this aspect of the theory goes on under the rubric
of the transformation problem, since it is about the
"transformation" of labor values to prices.
/Talk