Revision as of 22:26, 3 December 2017 editSlovinstein (talk | contribs)31 edits Incomplete sentence. Finished it with a place holder, should be further revised.← Previous edit | Revision as of 00:05, 27 January 2018 edit undo84.229.127.239 (talk) →CriticismNext edit → | ||
Line 41: | Line 41: | ||
* the theory wrongly implied that the state could somehow ''overrule'' inter-capitalist ], the laws of motion of capitalism and market forces generally, supposedly cancelling out the operation of the ].{{citation needed|date=April 2015}} | * the theory wrongly implied that the state could somehow ''overrule'' inter-capitalist ], the laws of motion of capitalism and market forces generally, supposedly cancelling out the operation of the ].{{citation needed|date=April 2015}} | ||
* the theory lacked any sophisticated account of the ''class basis'' of the ], and the real linkages between governments and elites. It postulated a monolithic structure of ] which in reality did not exist in that way.{{citation needed|date=April 2015}} | * the theory lacked any sophisticated account of the ''class basis'' of the ], and the real linkages between governments and elites. It postulated a monolithic structure of ] which in reality did not exist in that way.{{citation needed|date=April 2015}} | ||
* the theory failed to explain the rise of ] ideology in the business class, which claims precisely that an important social goal should be a ''reduction'' of the state's influence in the economy. {{citation needed|date=April 2015}} However, neoliberalism does not oppose making states subservient to the aims of large corporations, in what is known as ]. | * the theory failed to explain the rise of ] ideology in the business class, which claims precisely that an important social goal should be a ''reduction'' of the state's influence in the economy. {{citation needed|date=April 2015}} However, neoliberalism does not oppose making states subservient to the aims of large corporations, in what is known as ].{{citation needed}} | ||
* the theory failed to show clearly what the difference was between a ''socialist'' state and a ''bourgeois'' state, except that in a socialist state, the Communist Party (or, rather, its central committee) played the leading political role. In that case, the ''class-content'' of the state itself was defined purely in terms of the policy of the ruling political party (or its central committee).{{citation needed|date=April 2015}} | * the theory failed to show clearly what the difference was between a ''socialist'' state and a ''bourgeois'' state, except that in a socialist state, the Communist Party (or, rather, its central committee) played the leading political role. In that case, the ''class-content'' of the state itself was defined purely in terms of the policy of the ruling political party (or its central committee).{{citation needed|date=April 2015}} | ||
Revision as of 00:05, 27 January 2018
The theory of state monopoly capitalism was initially a Marxist doctrine popularised after World War II. Lenin had claimed in 1916 that World War I had transformed laissez-faire capitalism into monopoly capitalism, but he did not publish any extensive theory about the topic. The term refers to an environment where the state intervenes in the economy to protect larger monopolistic or oligopolistic businesses from threats. As conceived by Lenin in his pamphlet of the same name the theory aims to describe the final historical stage of capitalism, of which he believed the Imperialism of that time to be the highest expression.
Occasionally the concept also appears in neo-Trotskyist theories of state capitalism as well as in libertarian anti-state theories. The analysis made is usually identical in its main features, but very different political conclusions are drawn from it.
The main thesis
The main Marxist–Leninist thesis is that big business, having achieved a monopoly or cartel position in most markets of importance, fuses with the government apparatus. A kind of financial oligarchy or conglomerate therefore results, whereby government officials aim to provide the social and legal framework within which giant corporations can operate most effectively.
This is a close partnership between big business and government, and it is argued that the aim is to integrate labor-unions completely in that partnership.
Versions of the theory
Different versions of this idea were elaborated by economists of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union (e.g., Eugen Varga), East Germany's Socialist Unity Party, the French Communist Party (e.g., Paul Boccara), the Communist Party of Great Britain (e.g., Ben Fine and Laurence Harris), and the American Communist Party of the USA (e.g., Victor Perlo).
Political implication
Ever since monopoly capital took over the world, it has kept the greater part of humanity in poverty, dividing all the profits among the group of the most powerful countries. The standard of living in those countries is based on the extreme poverty of our countries.
— Che Guevara, 1965
The strategic political implication of the theory for Marxist-Leninists, towards the end of the Joseph Stalin era and afterwards, was that the labour movement should form a people's democratic alliance under the leadership of the Communist Party with the progressive middle classes and small business, against the state and big business (called "monopoly" for short). Sometimes this alliance was also called the "anti-monopoly alliance".
Neo-Trotskyist theory
In neo-Trotskyist theory, however, such an alliance was rejected as being based either on a false strategy of popular fronts, or on political opportunism, said to be incompatible either with a permanent revolution or with the principle of independent working class political action.
The state in Soviet-type societies was redefined by the neo-Trotskyists as being also state-monopoly capitalist. There was no difference, in their view, between the West and the East in this regard. Consequently, some kind of anti-bureaucratic revolution was said to be required, but different Trotskyist groups quarreled about what form such a revolution would need to take, or could take.
Some Trotskyists believed the anti-bureaucratic revolution would happen spontaneously, inevitably and naturally, others believed it needed to be organised - the aim being to establish a society owned and operated by the working class. According to the neo-Trotskyists, the Communist Party could not play its leading role, because it did not represent the interests of the working class.
Market anarchism
Market anarchists typically criticize neoliberal forces for inconsistent or hypocritical application of neoliberal theory regarding stamocap (State monopoly capitalism); that in those inconsistencies exist the basis of continued selective state-guaranteed privileges for the plutocratic neoliberal elite.
Eurocommunism
The concept was to a large extent either modified or abandoned in the era of eurocommunism, because it came to be believed that the state apparatus could be reformed to reflect the interests of the working majority. In other words, the fusion between the state and big business postulated earlier was not so tight that it could not be undone by a mass movement from below, under the leadership of the Communist Party (or its central committee).
Criticism
When Varga introduced the theory, orthodox Stalinist economists attacked it as incompatible with the doctrine that state planning was a feature only of socialism, and that "under capitalism anarchy of production reigns."
Critics of the theory (e.g., Ernest Mandel and Leo Kofler) claimed that:
- the theory wrongly implied that the state could somehow overrule inter-capitalist competition, the laws of motion of capitalism and market forces generally, supposedly cancelling out the operation of the law of value.
- the theory lacked any sophisticated account of the class basis of the state, and the real linkages between governments and elites. It postulated a monolithic structure of domination which in reality did not exist in that way.
- the theory failed to explain the rise of neo-liberal ideology in the business class, which claims precisely that an important social goal should be a reduction of the state's influence in the economy. However, neoliberalism does not oppose making states subservient to the aims of large corporations, in what is known as government-granted monopoly.
- the theory failed to show clearly what the difference was between a socialist state and a bourgeois state, except that in a socialist state, the Communist Party (or, rather, its central committee) played the leading political role. In that case, the class-content of the state itself was defined purely in terms of the policy of the ruling political party (or its central committee).
See also
- Capitalism
- Capitalist mode of production
- Crony capitalism
- Late capitalism
- Monopoly Capital
- State capitalism
- Government-granted monopoly
- Supercapitalism
- White Monopoly Capital
References
- Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism V.I.Lenin 1916
- At the Afro-Asian Conference in Algeria by Che Guevara, Delivered at the Second Economic Seminar of Afro-Asian Solidarity in Algiers, Algeria - on February 24, 1965
- "The Iron Fist Behind the Invisible Hand: Corporate Capitalism As a State-Guaranteed System of Privilege" by Kevin A. Carson
- The Case of Eugene Varga Raya Dunayevskaya 1949
Further reading
- Guy Ankerl, Beyond Monopoly Capitalism and Monopoly Socialism. Cambridge MA, Schenkman, 1978, ISBN 0-87073-938-7
- Nikolai Bukharin, Imperialism and World Economy.
- Gerd Hardach, Dieter Karras and Ben Fine, A short history of socialist economic thought., pp. 63–68.
- Bob Jessop, The capitalist state.
- Charlene Gannage, "E. S. Varga and the Theory of State Monopoly Capitalism", in Review of Radical Political Economics 12(3), Fall 1980, pages 36–49.
- Johnn Fairley, French Developments in the Theory of State Monopoly Capitalism, in: Science and Society; 44(3), Fall 1980, pages 305-25.
- Ernest Mandel, Late Capitalism, pp. 515–522.
- Ernest Mandel, Historical Materialism and the Capitalist State.
- Paul Boccara et al., Le Capitalisme Monopoliste d'Etat. Paris: Editions Sociales, 1971 (2 vols).
- G. N. Sorvina et al., "The Role of the State in the System of State Monopoly Capitalism", in: The Teaching of Political Economy: A Critique of Non Marxian Theories. Moscow: Progress, 1984, pages 171-179.
- Ben Fine & Laurence Harris, Re-reading Capital.
- Jacques Valier, Le Parti Communiste Francais Et Le Capitalisme Monopoliste D'Etat, 1976
External links
- The Age of Monopoly-Finance Capital by John Bellamy Foster, Monthly Review, February 2010