Misplaced Pages

Welfare trap: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editNext edit →Content deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 12:30, 2 June 2022 editL'être et le néant (talk | contribs)84 edits Deletion of heavily biased, dubiously sourced, poorly cited image that showed what was supposed to be a flow chart but was instead just a collection of shapes, arrows, and hyperpartisan political opinion that lacked the binary function of any actual flow chart, Deletion for the following reasons: (1) The source was improperly cited and improperly formatted, and it linked to othing but the exact same image of itself w/o any verifiable source info; (2) The image violated Misplaced Pages neutrality rulesTag: Visual edit← Previous edit Revision as of 15:19, 4 July 2022 edit undoThe Quirky Kitty (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users20,214 editsm Put the image in a standard frame.Tag: Visual editNext edit →
Line 2: Line 2:
{{for|the general concept of self-reinforcing mechanisms which maintain poverty|Poverty trap}} {{for|the general concept of self-reinforcing mechanisms which maintain poverty|Poverty trap}}
{{More citations needed|date=May 2007}} {{More citations needed|date=May 2007}}
]
]

The '''welfare trap''' (or '''unemployment trap''' or '''poverty trap''' in British English) theory asserts that ] and ] systems can jointly contribute to keep people on ] because the withdrawal of ]ed benefits that comes with entering low-paid work causes there to be no significant increase in total income. According to this theory, an individual sees that the ] of getting a better paying job is too great for too little a financial return, and this can create a ] to not pursue a better paying job.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.learnliberty.org/blog/the-welfare-cliff-and-why-many-low-income-workers-will-never-overcome-poverty/|title=The Welfare Cliff and Why Many Low-Income Workers Will Never Overcome Poverty|website=Learn Liberty|date=August 24, 2016|first=Howard|last=Baetjer}}</ref> The '''welfare trap''' (or '''unemployment trap''' or '''poverty trap''' in British English) theory asserts that ] and ] systems can jointly contribute to keep people on ] because the withdrawal of ]ed benefits that comes with entering low-paid work causes there to be no significant increase in total income. According to this theory, an individual sees that the ] of getting a better paying job is too great for too little a financial return, and this can create a ] to not pursue a better paying job.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.learnliberty.org/blog/the-welfare-cliff-and-why-many-low-income-workers-will-never-overcome-poverty/|title=The Welfare Cliff and Why Many Low-Income Workers Will Never Overcome Poverty|website=Learn Liberty|date=August 24, 2016|first=Howard|last=Baetjer}}</ref>



Revision as of 15:19, 4 July 2022

Economics theory For the general concept of self-reinforcing mechanisms which maintain poverty, see Poverty trap.
This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.
Find sources: "Welfare trap" – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (May 2007) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
Graph of the welfare trap, showing drops in post-benefits income when earnings exceed the thresholds for different programs

The welfare trap (or unemployment trap or poverty trap in British English) theory asserts that taxation and welfare systems can jointly contribute to keep people on social insurance because the withdrawal of means-tested benefits that comes with entering low-paid work causes there to be no significant increase in total income. According to this theory, an individual sees that the opportunity cost of getting a better paying job is too great for too little a financial return, and this can create a perverse incentive to not pursue a better paying job.

Different definitions

The term used for this concept varies depending on country. In the United States, where government benefit payments are colloquially referred to as "welfare", the welfare trap often indicates that a person is completely dependent on benefits, with little or no hope of self-sufficiency. The welfare trap is also known as the unemployment trap or the poverty trap, with both terms frequently being used interchangeably as they often go hand-in-hand, but there are subtle differences.

In other contexts, the terms "welfare trap" and "poverty trap" are clearly distinguished. For example, a Southern African Regional Poverty Network report on social protection clarifies that "poverty trap a structural condition from which people cannot rescue themselves despite their best efforts. A welfare trap in this context, by contrast, refers to the barrier created by means-tested social grants that have in-built perverse incentives." The South African definition is typically used with regard to developing countries.

This concept may include other adverse effects of welfare such as on the family structure: it may encourage the increase in the numbers of single-mother families and divorce rates, as individuals see a distinct benefit in such a lifestyle.

In the UK, there is a distinction between two concepts within the welfare trap:

  • The unemployment trap occurs when the net income difference between low-paid work and unemployment benefits is less than work-related costs (bus pass, work clothes, daycare), discouraging movement into work;
  • The poverty trap is the position when means-tested benefit payments are reduced as income rises, combined with income tax and other deductions, with the effect of discouraging work with a higher income, longer hours or acquiring skills. In some cases, if a recipient's wage income rises too much, they may lose some or all of their social assistance.

Causes of welfare traps

The are two predominant views which look to examine how recipients can become stuck in such traps. The first view examines the behavioural traits of recipients and their inability to climb the socio-economic ladder. This view holds that recipients' lack of necessary traits is a result of their decision-making or individual psychology.

The other view examines analyses of labour supply wherein individuals will act to maximise their utility. This utility acts as a function of the amount of goods and services they can enjoy (their real disposable income) and the amount of non-working time available to them. For example, if a worker is free to choose the amount of hours they work, they will continue to offer more labour until an additional hour of leisure forgone is worth more than the goods and services attained through the additional work. Thus, people strive for a utility maximisation in which individuals may deliberately choose to continue receiving employment benefits, as the opportunity cost of employment is too high for the reduction in means-tested support they would otherwise receive.

Example: If a person on welfare finds a part-time job that will pay the minimum wage of $5 per hour for eight hours per week (totaling $40), and, of the amount earned per week, $20 is deducted from welfare, there is a net gain of only $20. If the government imposes taxes on the $40, at say 15% ($6), and there may be extra child-care and commuting costs as well since that the person can no longer remain at home all day, the person is now worse off than before getting the job. This result occurs despite performing eight hours of work per week that is productive to society.

Welfare traps in practice

Range of Marginal Tax Rates Between the 10th and 90th Percentiles for Low- and Moderate-Income Taxpayers, by Earnings Group, 2016

Many western countries have developed complex social safety nets that act to protect vulnerable families and individuals experiencing poverty and destitution. As these individuals aim to move off of welfare, the complex labyrinth of programs and policies - such as the 80 federal anti-poverty programs currently available in the United States - create confusion in the process to understand effects of increased income to means-tested payments.

In the United States, the Congressional Budget Office estimates that median marginal tax rates will rise sharply for taxpayers in the lowest quartile who earn less than 150 percent of the federal poverty level (FPL). For a taxpayer earning less than 50 percent of the FPL, the median marginal tax rate would increase from 14 percent to 34 percent when they find work that places their earnings at just above the poverty line (100-149 percent of the FPL). Following the second view on welfare traps posited earlier, recipients are rational actors and would likely experience material losses in access to goods and services when taxes, loss of leisure time, and support for dependents is factored in.

Avoiding welfare traps

An incentive to get out of the welfare trap is that the return to the labour market gives a person chances of moving up the career ladder, improving old and acquiring new job skills, etc., thus eventually improving standard of living. Policies that allow for the continued receipt of benefit payments for a period of time after entering work or up to a specific earnings ceiling may also eliminate the welfare trap. For example, for UK claimants of Incapacity Benefit or Employment Support Allowance, "permitted work" arrangements allow for paid work up to either 16 hours or £95 per week without the withdrawal of the disability benefit payments, leading to a net overall increase in income. However, any earnings over £20 may be taxed, and additional earnings may affect receipt of Housing Benefit and Council Tax Benefit, which is an example of the welfare trap remaining potentially in effect. To eliminate the welfare trap entirely would require a policy that permanently continues benefit payments regardless of any conditions, with no income from paid work being withdrawn. One example of this would be unconditional basic income.

See also

References

  1. Baetjer, Howard (August 24, 2016). "The Welfare Cliff and Why Many Low-Income Workers Will Never Overcome Poverty". Learn Liberty.
  2. An example of the use of "welfare" as shorthand for public assistance in an academic publication.
  3. "The Unemployment Trap", CentrePiece Spring 2008. Barbara Petrongolo, London School of Economics.
  4. Kay, Lawrence (August 18, 2009). "Escaping the Poverty Trap: How to help people on benefits into work". Policy Exchange.
  5. pdf, webpage, a SARPN (Southern African Regional Poverty Network) report
  6. "The state of working America, 1996-97". Lawrence Mishel, Jared Bernstein, John Schmitt, section "Government Benefits and Family structure: Is there a Welfare Trap?"
  7. Fraser, Gordon, Nancy, Linda (1994). "A Genealogy of Dependency: Tracing A Keyword of the U.S. Welfare State". Signs. 19, 2: 309–336.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  8. "Welfare Regimes and Perceived Causes of Poverty", The Institutional Logic of Welfare Attitudes, Routledge, pp. 79–112, 2016-02-24, retrieved 2022-05-01
  9. M., Dockery, Alfred (2008). Welfare traps in Australia : do they bite?. the Centre for Labour Market Research. OCLC 836911417.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  10. Kraay, Aart; McKenzie, David (2014-08-01). "Do Poverty Traps Exist? Assessing the Evidence". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 28 (3): 127–148. doi:10.1257/jep.28.3.127. ISSN 0895-3309.
  11. "Social safety net", Misplaced Pages, 2021-11-19, retrieved 2022-05-01
  12. "Human Resources Subcommittee Discusses Need to Better Coordinate Dozens of Anti-Poverty Programs". Ways and Means Republicans. 2015-11-03. Retrieved 2022-05-01.
  13. "Effective Marginal Tax Rates for Low- and Moderate-Income Workers in 2016 | Congressional Budget Office". www.cbo.gov. 2015-11-19. Retrieved 2022-05-01.
  14. "Human Resources Subcommittee Discusses Need to Better Coordinate Dozens of Anti-Poverty Programs". Ways and Means Republicans. 2015-11-03. Retrieved 2022-05-01.
  15. Brian Lee Crowley (June 8, 2005). "Equalization:Welfare Trap or Helping Hand, a Brian Lee Crowley speech". Archived from the original on September 29, 2011.
  16. DirectGov
  17. "Basic Income and Labor Supply: The German Case" by B. Michael Gilroy & Mark Schopf & Anastasia Semenova, 2012.
Categories: