Revision as of 16:44, 26 November 2023 editFyzixFighter (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users14,864 edits rv per MOS:APOSTROPHE← Previous edit | Latest revision as of 06:03, 21 November 2024 edit undoAvraham (talk | contribs)Autopatrolled, Bureaucrats, Administrators49,160 editsm Should clear annoying ref warnings | ||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{Short description|Theorem in probability theory}} | {{Short description|Theorem in probability theory}} | ||
In ], '''Slutsky's theorem''' extends some properties of algebraic operations on ] of ]s to sequences of ]s.<ref>{{cite book |first=Arthur S. |last=Goldberger |author-link=Arthur Goldberger |title=Econometric Theory |location=New York |publisher=Wiley |year=1964 |pages=–120 |url=https://archive.org/details/econometrictheor0000gold |url-access=registration }}</ref> | In ], '''Slutsky's theorem''' extends some properties of algebraic operations on ] of ]s to sequences of ]s.<ref>{{cite book |first=Arthur S. |last=Goldberger |author-link=Arthur Goldberger |title=Econometric Theory |location=New York |publisher=Wiley |year=1964 |pages=–120 |url=https://archive.org/details/econometrictheor0000gold |url-access=registration|ref=NULL }}</ref> | ||
The theorem was named after ].<ref>{{Cite journal | The theorem was named after ].<ref>{{Cite journal | ||
Line 11: | Line 11: | ||
| pages = 3–89 | | pages = 3–89 | ||
| jfm = 51.0380.03 | | jfm = 51.0380.03 | ||
| ref = NULL | |||
}}</ref> Slutsky's theorem is also attributed to ].<ref>Slutsky's theorem is also called ]'s theorem according to Remark 11.1 (page 249) of {{Cite book | }}</ref> Slutsky's theorem is also attributed to ].<ref>Slutsky's theorem is also called ]'s theorem according to Remark 11.1 (page 249) of {{Cite book | ||
| last = Gut | first = Allan | | last = Gut | first = Allan | ||
Line 17: | Line 18: | ||
| year = 2005 | | year = 2005 | ||
| isbn = 0-387-22833-0 | | isbn = 0-387-22833-0 | ||
| ref = NULL | |||
}}</ref> | }}</ref> | ||
Line 45: | Line 47: | ||
==Further reading== | ==Further reading== | ||
* {{cite book |first=George |last=Casella |first2=Roger L. |last2=Berger |title=Statistical Inference |location=Pacific Grove |publisher=Duxbury |year=2001 |pages=240–245 |isbn=0-534-24312-6 }} | * {{cite book |first=George |last=Casella |first2=Roger L. |last2=Berger |title=Statistical Inference |location=Pacific Grove |publisher=Duxbury |year=2001 |pages=240–245 |isbn=0-534-24312-6|ref=NULL }} | ||
* {{Cite book | * {{Cite book | ||
| last1 = Grimmett | first1 = G. | | last1 = Grimmett | first1 = G. | ||
Line 53: | Line 55: | ||
| publisher = Oxford | | publisher = Oxford | ||
| edition = 3rd | | edition = 3rd | ||
| ref = NULL | |||
}} | }} | ||
* {{cite book |first=Fumio |last=Hayashi |author-link=Fumio Hayashi |title=Econometrics |publisher=Princeton University Press |year=2000 |isbn=0-691-01018-8 |pages=92–93 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=QyIW8WUIyzcC&pg=PA92 }} | * {{cite book |first=Fumio |last=Hayashi |author-link=Fumio Hayashi |title=Econometrics |publisher=Princeton University Press |year=2000 |isbn=0-691-01018-8 |pages=92–93 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=QyIW8WUIyzcC&pg=PA92|ref=NULL }} | ||
{{DEFAULTSORT:Slutsky's Theorem}} | {{DEFAULTSORT:Slutsky's Theorem}} |
Latest revision as of 06:03, 21 November 2024
Theorem in probability theoryIn probability theory, Slutsky's theorem extends some properties of algebraic operations on convergent sequences of real numbers to sequences of random variables.
The theorem was named after Eugen Slutsky. Slutsky's theorem is also attributed to Harald Cramér.
Statement
Let be sequences of scalar/vector/matrix random elements. If converges in distribution to a random element and converges in probability to a constant , then
- provided that c is invertible,
where denotes convergence in distribution.
Notes:
- The requirement that Yn converges to a constant is important — if it were to converge to a non-degenerate random variable, the theorem would be no longer valid. For example, let and . The sum for all values of n. Moreover, , but does not converge in distribution to , where , , and and are independent.
- The theorem remains valid if we replace all convergences in distribution with convergences in probability.
Proof
This theorem follows from the fact that if Xn converges in distribution to X and Yn converges in probability to a constant c, then the joint vector (Xn, Yn) converges in distribution to (X, c) (see here).
Next we apply the continuous mapping theorem, recognizing the functions g(x,y) = x + y, g(x,y) = xy, and g(x,y) = x y are continuous (for the last function to be continuous, y has to be invertible).
See also
References
- Goldberger, Arthur S. (1964). Econometric Theory. New York: Wiley. pp. 117–120.
- Slutsky, E. (1925). "Über stochastische Asymptoten und Grenzwerte". Metron (in German). 5 (3): 3–89. JFM 51.0380.03.
- Slutsky's theorem is also called Cramér's theorem according to Remark 11.1 (page 249) of Gut, Allan (2005). Probability: a graduate course. Springer-Verlag. ISBN 0-387-22833-0.
- See Zeng, Donglin (Fall 2018). "Large Sample Theory of Random Variables (lecture slides)" (PDF). Advanced Probability and Statistical Inference I (BIOS 760). University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. Slide 59.
Further reading
- Casella, George; Berger, Roger L. (2001). Statistical Inference. Pacific Grove: Duxbury. pp. 240–245. ISBN 0-534-24312-6.
- Grimmett, G.; Stirzaker, D. (2001). Probability and Random Processes (3rd ed.). Oxford.
- Hayashi, Fumio (2000). Econometrics. Princeton University Press. pp. 92–93. ISBN 0-691-01018-8.