Misplaced Pages

Health Impact Fund: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editNext edit →Content deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 08:14, 16 June 2010 editErianna (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users12,471 editsm Support← Previous edit Revision as of 07:58, 8 July 2010 edit undoPascal666 (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users17,486 editsm Removed Category:Intellectual Property; Adding category Category:Intellectual property law (Redirect Category:Intellectual property resolved) (using HotCat)Next edit →
Line 58: Line 58:
<!--- Categories ---> <!--- Categories --->


]
] ]
]


] ]

Revision as of 07:58, 8 July 2010

The Health Impact Fund (HIF) is a proposed international agency that would provide a market-based solution to problems concerning the development and distribution of medicines. It would incentivize the research and development of new pharmaceutical products that make substantial reductions in the global burden of disease. The HIF is the creation of a team of researchers lead by the Yale philosopher Thomas Pogge and the University of Calgary economist Aidan Hollis, and is promoted by the non-profit organization Incentives for Global Health.

Motivation

In the current system of development and distribution of medicines, millions of people in poor countries die from diseases because the patented medicines they need are unaffordable or because no medicine exists to cure their ailments. Little pharmaceutical research is concentrated on diseases specific to the poor. This is largely because it has been difficult for pharmaceutical companies to profit from research and development directed at products needed by the poor. The cost of pharmaceutical research and development is high and unlikely to be recovered from those in poor countries who cannot afford the medicines.

The distribution of pharmaceutical research and development is partly a result of the global patent regime established by the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS). Prior to TRIPS, countries were free to not enact intellectual property laws covering medicines, leading to flourishing generic drug industries in countries such as India. Following TRIPS, all World Trade Organization members were required to institute strict, American-style intellectual property rights. As a result, the supply of generic medicines to poor countries has been sharply diminished. According to Nobel Laureate Joseph Stiglitz, the pharmaceutical patent system needs an "alternative" that would "give large rewards for cures or vaccines for diseases like malaria that affect millions."

Design of the Fund

The HIF is intended to address the problems with an uncomplemented pharmaceutical patent system. The HIF uses market forces to create incentives to develop medicines for typically neglected diseases and to distribute these medicines at low prices all over the world. Pharmaceutical patent-holders would receive financial rewards by opting to register their new medicines, or new uses of existing medicines, with the fund. By registering, a patent-holder agrees to distribute its medicine globally at cost and to cooperate in measuring the health impact of that medicine. In return, the firm receives an annual reward based on its measurable contribution to reducing the global burden of disease.

Registrants of new drugs are eligible for reward payments for ten years starting at the date of marketing approval of their product. New uses receive rewards for five years. Following the reward period, registrants agree to allow generic manufacturing of their medicines, in order to prevent price spikes. Registrants retain their rights to control follow-on innovation.

Assessing the Health Impact of a Registered Product

When assessing the health impact of a registered product, “the HIF would essentially estimate the difference between (1) the actual health status of people who consumed the registered product and (2) the estimated health status of those people, had they not had access to the registered product.”

The standard measure of health impact is the Quality-Adjusted Life Year (QALY). For example, if all registered products were in conjunction estimated to have saved 10 million QALYs, then a registered product that saved 1 million of those QALYS would receive ten percent of the available reward funds for that year. The health impact assessment of a registered product would be conducted for each year of its registration with the HIF, and payments would be disbursed annually.

Funding

The HIF is to be financed by governments, and will require an initial commitment of at least six billion dollars per year. Ideally, countries will commit a fixed amount of their gross national income (GNI) to the HIF (0.03 percent of a country’s GNI is the suggested minimum). Governments would be required to make a twelve-year commitment to the fund, so that researchers would be confident that future funding will be available.

Relationship to Other Proposals

The HIF can be seen as a kind of comprehensive Advanced Market Commitment, since it essentially is a way of incentivizing new research while ensuring access at low prices. However, compared to the Advanced Market Commitment, it is comprehensive because it could apply to any drug or vaccine, and it would operate in all countries. Alternatively, one can put it in the context of prizes, since it has prize-like characteristics in terms of incentivizing research while not enabling high prices. A third way of viewing it is as a supplementary global drug insurance system, in which the copayment made by consumers is equal to the cost of production.

Reception

Criticisms

When the HIF was proposed in 2008, it attracted considerable criticism for not requiring open licensing of registered drugs. Instead, it required registrants to sell the drug globally at the cost of production and distribution. The proponents have more recently suggested greater flexibility about this aspect of the HIF.

Brita Pekarsky (2010) has argued that the cost of the HIF may be too high, if it is taking money away from other valuable development aid or health related activities.

Paul Grootendorst (2009) states that the primary drawback of the HIF is the difficulty of measuring health impact accurately. He notes particularly the problems of trying to attribute health impact to drugs that have long latency periods in their effectiveness (such as vaccines and anti-hypertensives); the problems of consistency across different therapeutic areas; and the technical difficulty of disentangling the effect of the drug from confounding factors.

Jorn Sonderholm (2009) argues that there is a lack of evidence that patents create a barrier to access, so that the HIF may fail to address a real problem.

Support

The World Health Organization Expert Working Group on Research and Development Financing (related to Public health, innovation and intellectual property) described the HIF as one of a few "promising" proposals deserving further examination.

Carl Nathan (2009) suggests that the HIF could help to overcome obstacles to the control of tuberculosis such as development and distribution of vaccines and medicines to the poor.

John J. DeGioia, President of Georgetown University, has complimented the HIF for bringing moral imperatives and pragmatic market principles together. He states, "that this is the beauty of the Health Impact Fund . . . it translates idealism into innovation."

Christian Barry and Matt Peterson favour the HIF as a mechanism for providing innovators with incentives to develop new medicines that have significant health impacts rather than significant sales impacts.

James Orbinski states that the HIF is an innovative policy proposal that "should be implemented."

References

Constructs such as ibid., loc. cit. and idem are discouraged by Misplaced Pages's style guide for footnotes, as they are easily broken. Please improve this article by replacing them with named references (quick guide), or an abbreviated title. (April 2010) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
  1. Joseph Stiglitz, "Scrooge and Intellectual Property Rights," British Medical Journal 333, no. 7582 (2006), pp. 1279.
  2. Ibid.
  3. Aidan Hollis and Thomas Pogge, The Health Impact Fund: Making Medicines Available for All (New Haven, CT: Incentives for Global Health, 2008), p. 3.
  4. Ibid., ch. 2.
  5. Ibid., pp. 13-14.
  6. Ibid., p. 17.
  7. Ibid., p. 9.
  8. Ibid., pp. 3-4.
  9. Ibid., pp. 10-11.
  10. Ibid., p. 43.
  11. Brita Pekarsky, “Should Financial Incentives be Used to Differentially Reward ‘Me-Too’ and Innovative Drugs,” Pharmacoeconomics 28.1(2010): 1-17.
  12. Paul Grootendorst, “How Should We Support Pharmaceutical Innovation?,” Expert. Rev. Pharmacoeconomics Outcomes Res. 2009: 9(4) – 313-320.
  13. Jorn Sonderholm, “A Reform Proposal in Need of Reform: A Critique of Thomas Pogge’s Proposal for How to Incentivize Research and Development of Essential Drugs,” Public Health Ethics 0.0 (2009): 1-11.
  14. "WHO Working Group Endorses HIF", Incentives for Global Health. 17 Jan. 2010.
  15. Carl Nathan, “Taming Tuberculosis: A Challenge for Science and Society,” Cell Host and Microbe 5(2009): 222.
  16. John J. DeGioia, “Making New Medicines Available to All: The Health Impact Fund,” Georgetown University, Gonda Theater. 1 Dec. 2008.
  17. Christian Barry and Matt Peterson, “Shallow Cuts: GSK’s Voluntary Price Reductions and Patent Pooling Are Not Enough,” Public Ethics Media, 4 Mar. 2009.
  18. James Orbinski, “Are Patents Impeding Medical Care and Innovation?”, PLoS Medicine 7.1(2009): 3.

Further reading

More information about the Health Impact Fund is available online at: http://www.healthimpactfund.org

Peter Singer, "Tuberculosis or Hair Loss?”, The Guardian. 16 Sept. 2008.

Amitava Banerjee, Aidan Hollis, Thomas Pogge,“The Health Impact Fund: Incentives for Improving Access to Medicines” Lancet 375.9709 (2010): 166–69.

Categories: