Misplaced Pages

Sectoral balances: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editNext edit →Content deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 22:56, 3 August 2015 editIodineSushi (talk | contribs)4 editsmNo edit summary← Previous edit Revision as of 18:17, 27 November 2015 edit undoLevelledout (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users1,042 editsNo edit summaryTags: Mobile edit Mobile web editNext edit →
Line 1: Line 1:
The '''sectoral balances''' (also called '''sectoral financial balances''') are a ] framework for macroeconomic analysis of national economies developed by British economist ].<ref></ref> ] The balances represent an ''ex-post'' accounting identity resulting from rearranging the components of ], showing how the ] affects the financial balances of the private sector, government sector and foreign sector.<ref name="fiebeger">{{cite journal|last1=Fiebeger|first1=Brett|title=A constructive critique of the Levy Sectoral Financial Balance approach|journal=Real World Economics Review|date=2013|pages=59-80|accessdate=27 December 2014}}</ref> This corresponds approximately to ] developed by ] in the 1950s. The '''sectoral balances''' (also called '''sectoral financial balances''') are a ] framework for macroeconomic analysis of national economies developed by British economist ].<ref></ref> ] The balances represent an ''ex-post''{{jargon-inline}} accounting ] resulting from rearranging the components of ], showing how the ] affects the financial balances of the private sector, government sector and foreign sector.<ref name="fiebeger">{{cite journal|last1=Fiebeger|first1=Brett|title=A constructive critique of the Levy Sectoral Financial Balance approach|journal=Real World Economics Review|date=2013|pages=59-80|accessdate=27 December 2014}}</ref> This corresponds approximately to ] developed by ] in the 1950s.


The approach is used by scholars at the ] to support macroeconomic modelling and by ] to justify theoretical claims about the relationship between government budget deficits and private saving.<ref name="fiebeger" /> The approach is used by scholars at the ] to support macroeconomic modelling and by ] to justify theoretical claims about the relationship between government budget deficits and private saving.<ref name="fiebeger" />

Revision as of 18:17, 27 November 2015

The sectoral balances (also called sectoral financial balances) are a sectoral analysis framework for macroeconomic analysis of national economies developed by British economist Wynne Godley.

Sectoral financial balances in U.S. economy 1990-2012. By definition, the three balances must net to zero. Since 2009, the U.S. capital surplus and private sector surplus have driven a government budget deficit.

The balances represent an ex-post accounting identity resulting from rearranging the components of aggregate demand, showing how the flow of funds affects the financial balances of the private sector, government sector and foreign sector. This corresponds approximately to Balances Mechanics developed by Wolfgang Stützel in the 1950s.

The approach is used by scholars at the Levy Economics Institute to support macroeconomic modelling and by Modern Monetary Theorists to justify theoretical claims about the relationship between government budget deficits and private saving.

Overview

Economist Martin Wolf explained in July 2012 that government fiscal balance is one of three major financial sectoral balances in the national economy, the others being the foreign financial sector and the private financial sector. The sum of the surpluses or deficits across these three sectors must be zero by definition. Hence, a foreign financial surplus (or capital surplus) exists because capital is imported (net) to fund the trade deficit. Further, there is a private sector financial surplus due to household savings exceeding business investment. By definition, there must therefore exist a government budget deficit so all three net to zero. The government sector includes federal, state and local. For example, the U.S. government budget deficit in 2011 was approximately 10% GDP (8.6% GDP of which was federal), offsetting a capital surplus of 4% GDP and a private sector surplus of 6% GDP.

Wolf argued that sudden shifts in the private sector from deficit to surplus forced the government balance into deficit, and cited as example the U.S.: "The financial balance of the private sector shifted towards surplus by the almost unbelievable cumulative total of 11.2 per cent of gross domestic product between the third quarter of 2007 and the second quarter of 2009, which was when the financial deficit of US government (federal and state) reached its peak...No fiscal policy changes explain the collapse into massive fiscal deficit between 2007 and 2009, because there was none of any importance. The collapse is explained by the massive shift of the private sector from financial deficit into surplus or, in other words, from boom to bust."

Economist Paul Krugman also explained in December 2011 the causes of the sizable shift from private deficit to surplus: "This huge move into surplus reflects the end of the housing bubble, a sharp rise in household saving, and a slump in business investment due to lack of customers."

Sectoral balances description

GDP (Gross Domestic Product) is the value of all goods and services sold within a country during one year. GDP measures flows rather than stocks (example: the public deficit is a flow, the government debt is a stock). Flows are derived from the National Accounting relationship between aggregate spending and income. Ergo:

(1) Y = C + I + G + (X – M)

where Y is GDP (income), C is consumption spending, I is private investment spending, G is government spending, X is exports and M is imports (so X – M = net exports).

Another perspective on the national income accounting is to note that households can use total income (Y) for the following uses:

(2) Y = C + S + T

where S is total saving and T is total taxation (the other variables are as previously defined).

You than then bring the two perspectives together (because they are both just “views” of Y) to write:

(3) C + S + T = Y = C + I + G + (X – M)

You can then drop the C (common on both sides) and you get:

(4) S + T = I + G + (X – M)

Then you can convert this into the following sectoral balances accounting relations, which allow us to understand the influence of fiscal policy over private sector indebtedness. Hence, equation (4) can be rearranged to get the accounting identity for the three sectoral balances – private domestic, government budget and external:

(S – I) = (G – T) + (X – M)

The sectoral balances equation says that total private savings (S) minus private investment (I) has to equal the public deficit (spending, G minus taxes, T) plus net exports (exports (X) minus imports (M)), where net exports represent the net savings of non-residents.

Another way of saying this is that total private savings (S) is equal to private investment (I) plus the public deficit (spending, G minus taxes, T) plus net exports (exports (X) minus imports (M)), where net exports represent the net savings of non-residents.

All these relationships (equations) hold as a matter of accounting and not matters of opinion.

Thus, when an external deficit (X – M < 0) and public surplus (G - T < 0) coincide, there must be a private deficit. While private spending can persist for a time under these conditions using the net savings of the external sector, the private sector becomes increasingly indebted in the process.

Usage

In macroeconomics, the Modern Money Theory uses sectoral balances to define any transactions between the government sector and the non-government sector as a vertical transaction.

The government sector is considered to include the treasury and the central bank, whereas the non-government sector includes private individuals and firms (including the private banking system) and the external sector – that is, foreign buyers and sellers.

In any given time period, the government’s budget can be either in deficit or in surplus. A deficit occurs when the government spends more than it taxes; and a surplus occurs when a government taxes more than it spends. Sectoral balances analysis states that as a matter of accounting, it follows that government budget deficits add net financial assets to the private sector. This is because a budget deficit means that a government has deposited more money into private bank accounts than it has removed in taxes. A budget surplus means the opposite: in total, the government has removed more money from private bank accounts via taxes than it has put back in via spending.

Therefore, budget deficits, by definition, are equivalent to adding net financial assets to the private sector; whereas budget surpluses remove financial assets from the private sector.

This is represented by the identity:

(G – T) = (S – I) – NX

which is

(state sector saldo) = (intern private sector saldo) – extern sector saldo

where G is government spending, T is taxes, S is savings, I is investment and NX is net exports.

The conclusion drawn from this is that private net saving is only possible if the government runs budget deficits; alternately, the private sector is forced to dis-save when the government runs a budget surplus.

According to the sectoral balances framework, budget surpluses remove net savings; in a time of high effective demand, this may lead to a private sector reliance on credit to finance consumption patterns. Hence, continual budget deficits are necessary for a growing economy that wants to avoid deflation. Therefore budget surpluses are required only when the economy has excessive aggregate demand, and is in danger of inflation.

Austerity in the view of the sectoral balances approach

According to the sectoral balances approach, austerity can be counterproductive in a downturn due to a significant private-sector financial surplus, in which consumer savings is not fully invested by businesses. In a healthy economy, private-sector savings placed into the banking system by consumers are borrowed and invested by companies. However, if consumers have increased their savings but companies are not investing the money, a surplus develops. Business investment is one of the major components of GDP.

Economist Richard Koo described similar effects for several of the developed world economies in December 2011: "Today private sectors in the U.S., the U.K., Spain, and Ireland (but not Greece) are undergoing massive deleveraging in spite of record low interest rates. This means these countries are all in serious balance sheet recessions. The private sectors in Japan and Germany are not borrowing, either. With borrowers disappearing and banks reluctant to lend, it is no wonder that, after nearly three years of record low interest rates and massive liquidity injections, industrial economies are still doing so poorly. Flow of funds data for the U.S. show a massive shift away from borrowing to savings by the private sector since the housing bubble burst in 2007. The shift for the private sector as a whole represents over 9 percent of U.S. GDP at a time of zero interest rates. Moreover, this increase in private sector savings exceeds the increase in government borrowings (5.8 percent of GDP), which suggests that the government is not doing enough to offset private sector deleveraging."

See also

References

  1. Goldman's Top Economist Explains The World's Most Important Chart, And His Big Call For The US Economy
  2. ^ Fiebeger, Brett (2013). "A constructive critique of the Levy Sectoral Financial Balance approach". Real World Economics Review: 59–80. {{cite journal}}: |access-date= requires |url= (help)
  3. ^ Financial Times-Martin Wolf-The Balance Sheet Recession in the U.S.- July 2012
  4. NYT-Paul Krugman-The Problem-December 2011
  5. "Deficit Spending 101 - Part 1 : Vertical Transactions" Bill Mitchell, 21 February 2009
  6. Richard Koo-The world in balance sheet recession-Real World Economics Review-December 2011

Further reading

Category: