Misplaced Pages

Helly metric

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Metric to measure distances between strategies in game theory
This article includes a list of references, related reading, or external links, but its sources remain unclear because it lacks inline citations. Please help improve this article by introducing more precise citations. (June 2021) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

In game theory, the Helly metric is used to assess the distance between two strategies. It is named for Eduard Helly.

Definition

Consider a game Γ = X , Y , H {\displaystyle \Gamma =\left\langle {\mathfrak {X}},{\mathfrak {Y}},H\right\rangle } , between player I and II. Here, X {\displaystyle {\mathfrak {X}}} and Y {\displaystyle {\mathfrak {Y}}} are the sets of pure strategies for players I and II respectively. The payoff function is denoted by H = H ( , ) {\displaystyle H=H(\cdot ,\cdot )} . In other words, if player I plays x X {\displaystyle x\in {\mathfrak {X}}} and player II plays y Y {\displaystyle y\in {\mathfrak {Y}}} , then player I pays H ( x , y ) {\displaystyle H(x,y)} to player II.

The Helly metric ρ ( x 1 , x 2 ) {\displaystyle \rho (x_{1},x_{2})} is defined as

ρ ( x 1 , x 2 ) = sup y Y | H ( x 1 , y ) H ( x 2 , y ) | . {\displaystyle \rho (x_{1},x_{2})=\sup _{y\in {\mathfrak {Y}}}\left|H(x_{1},y)-H(x_{2},y)\right|.}

The metric so defined is symmetric, reflexive, and satisfies the triangle inequality.

Properties

The Helly metric measures distances between strategies, not in terms of the differences between the strategies themselves, but in terms of the consequences of the strategies. Two strategies are distant if their payoffs are different. Note that ρ ( x 1 , x 2 ) = 0 {\displaystyle \rho (x_{1},x_{2})=0} does not imply x 1 = x 2 {\displaystyle x_{1}=x_{2}} but it does imply that the consequences of x 1 {\displaystyle x_{1}} and x 2 {\displaystyle x_{2}} are identical; and indeed this induces an equivalence relation.

If one stipulates that ρ ( x 1 , x 2 ) = 0 {\displaystyle \rho (x_{1},x_{2})=0} implies x 1 = x 2 {\displaystyle x_{1}=x_{2}} , then the topology so induced is called the natural topology.

The metric on the space of player II's strategies is analogous:

ρ ( y 1 , y 2 ) = sup x X | H ( x , y 1 ) H ( x , y 2 ) | . {\displaystyle \rho (y_{1},y_{2})=\sup _{x\in {\mathfrak {X}}}\left|H(x,y_{1})-H(x,y_{2})\right|.}

Note that Γ {\displaystyle \Gamma } thus defines two Helly metrics: one for each player's strategy space.

Conditional compactness

Recall the definition of ϵ {\displaystyle \epsilon } -net: A set X ϵ {\displaystyle X_{\epsilon }} is an ϵ {\displaystyle \epsilon } -net in the space X {\displaystyle X} with metric ρ {\displaystyle \rho } if for any x X {\displaystyle x\in X} there exists x ϵ X ϵ {\displaystyle x_{\epsilon }\in X_{\epsilon }} with ρ ( x , x ϵ ) < ϵ {\displaystyle \rho (x,x_{\epsilon })<\epsilon } .

A metric space P {\displaystyle P} is conditionally compact (or precompact), if for any ϵ > 0 {\displaystyle \epsilon >0} there exists a finite ϵ {\displaystyle \epsilon } -net in P {\displaystyle P} . Any game that is conditionally compact in the Helly metric has an ϵ {\displaystyle \epsilon } -optimal strategy for any ϵ > 0 {\displaystyle \epsilon >0} . fMoreover, if the space of strategies for one player is conditionally compact, then the space of strategies for the other player is conditionally compact (in their Helly metric).

References

Stub icon

This game theory article is a stub. You can help Misplaced Pages by expanding it.

Categories: