Misplaced Pages

Pareto index

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.

In economics the Pareto index, named after the Italian economist and sociologist Vilfredo Pareto, is a measure of the breadth of income or wealth distribution. It is one of the parameters specifying a Pareto distribution and embodies the Pareto principle. As applied to income, the Pareto principle is sometimes stated in popular expositions by saying q=20% of the population has p=80% of the income. In fact, Pareto's data on British income taxes in his Cours d'économie politique indicates that about 20% of the population had about 80% of the income.. For example, if the population is 100 and the total wealth is $100xm, then together q=20 people have pxm=$80xm. Hence, each of these people has x=pxm/q=$4xm.

One of the simplest characterizations of the Pareto distribution, when used to model the distribution of incomes, says that the proportion of the population whose income exceeds any positive number x > xm is

q = ( x m x ) α = ( q p ) α {\displaystyle q=\left({\frac {x_{\mathrm {m} }}{x}}\right)^{\alpha }=\left({\frac {q}{p}}\right)^{\alpha }}

where xm is a positive number, the minimum of the support of this probability distribution (the subscript m stands for minimum). The Pareto index is the parameter α. Since a proportion must be between 0 and 1, inclusive, the index α must be positive, but in order for the total income of the whole population to be finite, α must also be greater than 1. The larger the Pareto index, the smaller the proportion of very high-income people.

Given a p + q = 1 {\displaystyle p+q=1} rule (why?), with p > q {\displaystyle p>q} , the Pareto index is given by:

α = log p / q 1 / q = log ( 1 / q ) / log ( p / q ) = log ( q ) / log ( q / p ) . {\displaystyle \alpha =\log _{p/q}1/q=\log(1/q)/\log(p/q)=\log(q)/\log(q/p).}

If q = 1 / n {\displaystyle q=1/n} , this simplifies to

α = log n 1 ( n ) . {\displaystyle \alpha =\log _{n-1}(n).}

Alternatively, in terms of odds, X:Y

α = log X / Y ( X + Y ) / Y , {\displaystyle \alpha =\log _{X/Y}(X+Y)/Y,}

so X:1 yields

α = log X ( X + 1 ) . {\displaystyle \alpha =\log _{X}(X+1).}

For example, the 80–20 (4:1) rule corresponds to α = log(5)/log(4) ≈ 1.16, 90–10 (9:1) corresponds to α = log(10)/log(9) ≈ 1.05, and 99–1 corresponds to α = log(100)/log(99) ≈ 1.002, whereas the 70–30 rule corresponds to α = log(0.3)/log(0.3/0.7) ≈ 1.42 and 2:1 (67–33) corresponds to α = log(3)/log(2) ≈ 1.585.

Mathematically, the formula above entails that all incomes are at least the lower bound xm, which is positive. Up to this income the probability density keeps decreasing, and then suddenly jumps down to zero, which is clearly unrealistic. Economists therefore sometimes state that the Pareto law as stated here applies only to the upper tail of the distribution.

See also

This article includes a list of references, related reading, or external links, but its sources remain unclear because it lacks inline citations. Please help improve this article by introducing more precise citations. (January 2012) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

References and external links

Categories: