Misplaced Pages

Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
(Redirected from Ramsey model) Neoclassical economic model
Part of a series on
Macroeconomics
Federal Reserve
Basic concepts
Policies
Models
Related fields
SchoolsMainstream

Heterodox

People
See also

The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model, or Ramsey growth model, is a neoclassical model of economic growth based primarily on the work of Frank P. Ramsey, with significant extensions by David Cass and Tjalling Koopmans. The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model differs from the Solow–Swan model in that the choice of consumption is explicitly microfounded at a point in time and so endogenizes the savings rate. As a result, unlike in the Solow–Swan model, the saving rate may not be constant along the transition to the long run steady state. Another implication of the model is that the outcome is Pareto optimal or Pareto efficient.

Originally Ramsey set out the model as a social planner's problem of maximizing consumption levels over successive generations. Only later was a model adopted by Cass and Koopmans as a description of a decentralized dynamic economy with a representative agent. The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model aims only at explaining long-run economic growth rather than business cycle fluctuations and does not include sources of disturbances like market imperfections, heterogeneity among households, or exogenous shocks. Subsequent researchers extended the model, allowing for government purchases, employment variations, and other shocks, notably in real business cycle theory.

Mathematical description

Model setup

In the usual setup, time is continuous starting, for simplicity, at t = 0 {\displaystyle t=0} and continuing forever. By assumption, the only productive factors are capital K {\displaystyle K} and labour L {\displaystyle L} , both required to be nonnegative. The labour force, which makes up the entire population, is assumed to grow at a constant rate n {\displaystyle n} , i.e. L ˙ = d L d t = n L {\displaystyle {\dot {L}}={\tfrac {\mathrm {d} L}{\mathrm {d} t}}=nL} , implying that L = L 0 e n t {\displaystyle L=L_{0}e^{nt}} with initial level L 0 > 0 {\displaystyle L_{0}>0} at t = 0 {\displaystyle t=0} . Finally, let Y {\displaystyle Y} denote aggregate production, and C {\displaystyle C} denote aggregate consumption.

The variables that the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model ultimately aims to describe are c = C L {\displaystyle c={\frac {C}{L}}} , the per capita (or more accurately, per labour) consumption, as well as k = K L {\displaystyle k={\frac {K}{L}}} , known as capital intensity. It does so by first connecting capital accumulation, written K ˙ = d K d t {\displaystyle {\dot {K}}={\tfrac {\mathrm {d} K}{\mathrm {d} t}}} in Newton's notation, with consumption C {\displaystyle C} , describing a consumption-investment trade-off. More specifically, since the existing capital stock decays by depreciation rate δ {\displaystyle \delta } (assumed to be constant), it requires investment of current-period production output Y {\displaystyle Y} . Thus, K ˙ = Y δ K c L {\displaystyle {\dot {K}}=Y-\delta K-cL}

The relationship between the productive factors and aggregate output is described by the aggregate production function, Y = F ( K , L ) {\displaystyle Y=F(K,L)} . A common choice is the Cobb–Douglas production function F ( K , L ) = A K 1 α L α {\displaystyle F(K,L)=AK^{1-\alpha }L^{\alpha }} , but generally any production function satisfying the Inada conditions is permissible. Importantly, though, F {\displaystyle F} is required to be homogeneous of degree 1, which economically implies constant returns to scale. With this assumption, we can re-express aggregate output in per capita terms F ( K , L ) = L F ( K L , 1 ) = L f ( k ) {\displaystyle F(K,L)=L\cdot F\left({\frac {K}{L}},1\right)=L\cdot f(k)} For example, if we use the Cobb–Douglas production function with A = 1 , α = 0.5 {\displaystyle A=1,\alpha =0.5} , then f ( k ) = k 0.5 {\displaystyle f(k)=k^{0.5}} .

To obtain the first key equation of the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model, the dynamic equation for the capital stock needs to be expressed in per capita terms. Noting the quotient rule for d d t ( K L ) {\displaystyle {\tfrac {\mathrm {d} }{\mathrm {d} t}}\left({\tfrac {K}{L}}\right)} , we have

k ˙ = f ( k ) ( n + δ ) k c {\displaystyle {\dot {k}}=f(k)-(n+\delta )k-c}

a non-linear differential equation akin to the Solow–Swan model but incorporates endogenous consumption 𝑐, reflecting the model's microfoundations.

Maximizing welfare

If we ignore the problem of how consumption is distributed, then the rate of utility U {\displaystyle U} is a function of aggregate consumption. That is, U = U ( C , t ) {\displaystyle U=U(C,t)} . To avoid the problem of infinity, we exponentially discount future utility at a discount rate ρ ( 0 , ) {\displaystyle \rho \in (0,\infty )} . A high ρ {\displaystyle \rho } reflects high impatience.

The social planner's problem is maximizing the social welfare function U 0 = 0 e ρ t U ( C , t ) d t {\displaystyle U_{0}=\int _{0}^{\infty }e^{-\rho t}U(C,t)\,\mathrm {d} t} .

Assume that the economy is populated by identical immortal individuals with unchanging utility functions u ( c ) {\displaystyle u(c)} (a representative agent), such that the total utility is: U ( C , t ) = L u ( c ) = L 0 e n t u ( c ) {\displaystyle U(C,t)=Lu(c)=L_{0}e^{nt}u(c)} The utility function is assumed to be strictly increasing (i.e., there is no bliss point) and concave in c {\displaystyle c} , with lim c 0 u c = {\displaystyle \lim _{c\to 0}u_{c}=\infty } , where u c {\displaystyle u_{c}} is marginal utility of consumption u c {\displaystyle {\tfrac {\partial u}{\partial c}}} .

Thus we have the social planner's problem:

max c 0 e ( ρ n ) t u ( c ) d t {\displaystyle \max _{c}\int _{0}^{\infty }e^{-(\rho -n)t}u(c)\,\mathrm {d} t}
subject to c = f ( k ) ( n + δ ) k k ˙ {\displaystyle {\text{subject to}}\quad c=f(k)-(n+\delta )k-{\dot {k}}}

where an initial non-zero capital stock k ( 0 ) = k 0 > 0 {\displaystyle k(0)=k_{0}>0} is given.

To ensure that the integral is well-defined, we impose ρ > n {\displaystyle \rho >n} .

Solution

The solution, usually found by using a Hamiltonian function, is a differential equation that describes the optimal evolution of consumption,

c ˙ = σ ( c ) [ f k ( k ) δ ρ ] c {\displaystyle {\dot {c}}=\sigma (c)\left\cdot c}

the Keynes–Ramsey rule.

The term f k ( k ) δ ρ {\displaystyle f_{k}(k)-\delta -\rho } , where f k = k f {\displaystyle f_{k}=\partial _{k}f} is the marginal product of capital, reflects the marginal return on net investment, accounting for capital depreciation and time discounting.

Here σ ( c ) {\displaystyle \sigma (c)} is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution (EIS), defined by σ ( c ) = u c ( c ) c u c c ( c ) = d ln c d ln ( u ( c ) ) {\displaystyle \sigma (c)=-{\frac {u_{c}(c)}{c\cdot u_{cc}(c)}}=-{\frac {d\ln c}{d\ln(u'(c))}}} It is formally equivalent to the inverse of relative risk aversion. The quantity reflects the curvature of the utility function and indicates how much the representative agent wishes to smooth consumption over time. If the agent has high relative risk aversion, then it has low EIS, and thus would be more willing to smooth consumption over time.

It is often assumed that u {\displaystyle u} is strictly monotonically increasing and concave, thus σ > 0 {\displaystyle \sigma >0} . In particular, if utility is logarithmic, then it is constant: u ( c ) = u 0 ln c σ ( c ) = 1 {\displaystyle u(c)=u_{0}\ln c\implies \sigma (c)=1} We can rewrite the Ramsey rule as d d t ln c consumption delay rate = σ ( c ) EIS at current consumption level [ f k ( k ) δ ρ ] marginal return on net investment {\displaystyle \underbrace {{\frac {d}{dt}}\ln c} _{\text{consumption delay rate}}=\underbrace {\sigma (c)} _{{\text{EIS at current consumption level}}\quad }\underbrace {} _{\text{marginal return on net investment}}} where we interpret d d t ln c {\displaystyle {\frac {d}{dt}}\ln c} as the "consumption delay rate", indicating the rate at which current consumption is being postponed in favor of future consumption. A higher value implies that the agent is prioritizing saving over consuming today, thereby deferring consumption to a later period.

Graphical analysis in phase space

Phase diagram of the Ramsey model, for the case of f ( k ) = k 0.5 {\displaystyle f(k)=k^{0.5}} , and n , δ , ρ , σ = 1 , 1 , 1.1 , 1 {\displaystyle n,\delta ,\rho ,\sigma =1,1,1.1,1} .
Phase space graph (or phase diagram) of the Ramsey model. The blue line represents the dynamic adjustment (or saddle) path of the economy in which all the constraints present in the model are satisfied. It is a stable path of the dynamic system. The red lines represent dynamic paths which are ruled out by the transversality condition.

The two coupled differential equations for k {\displaystyle k} and c {\displaystyle c} form the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans dynamical system.

{ k ˙ = f ( k ) ( n + δ ) k c c ˙ = σ ( c ) [ f k ( k ) δ ρ ] c {\displaystyle {\begin{cases}{\dot {k}}=f(k)-(n+\delta )k-c\\{\dot {c}}=\sigma (c)\left\cdot c\end{cases}}}

A steady state ( k , c ) {\displaystyle (k^{\ast },c^{\ast })} for the system is found by setting k ˙ {\displaystyle {\dot {k}}} and c ˙ {\displaystyle {\dot {c}}} equal to zero. There are three solutions:

f k ( k ) = δ + ρ and c = f ( k ) ( n + δ ) k {\displaystyle f_{k}\left(k^{\ast }\right)=\delta +\rho \quad {\text{and}}\quad c^{\ast }=f\left(k^{\ast }\right)-(n+\delta )k^{\ast }}
( 0 , 0 ) {\displaystyle (0,0)}
f ( k ) = ( n + δ ) k  with  k > 0 , c = 0 {\displaystyle f(k^{*})=(n+\delta )k^{*}{\text{ with }}k^{*}>0,c^{*}=0}

The first is the only solution in the interior of the upper quadrant. It is a saddle point (as shown below). The second is a repelling point. The third is a degenerate stable equilibrium. By default, the first solution is meant, although the other two solutions are important to keep track of.

Any optimal trajectory must follow the dynamical system. However, since the variable c {\displaystyle c} is a control variable, at each capital intensity k {\displaystyle k} , to find its corresponding optimal trajectory, we still need to find its starting consumption rate c ( 0 ) {\displaystyle c(0)} . As it turns out, the optimal trajectory is the unique one that converges to the interior equilibrium point. Any other trajectory either converges to the all-saving equilibrium with k > 0 , c = 0 {\displaystyle k^{*}>0,c^{*}=0} , or diverges to k 0 , c {\displaystyle k\to 0,c\to \infty } , which means that the economy expends all its capital in finite time. Both achieve a lower overall utility than the trajectory towards the interior equilibrium point.

A qualitative statement about the stability of the solution ( k , c ) {\displaystyle (k^{\ast },c^{\ast })} requires a linearization by a first-order Taylor polynomial

[ k ˙ c ˙ ] J ( k , c ) [ ( k k ) ( c c ) ] {\displaystyle {\begin{bmatrix}{\dot {k}}\\{\dot {c}}\end{bmatrix}}\approx \mathbf {J} (k^{\ast },c^{\ast }){\begin{bmatrix}(k-k^{\ast })\\(c-c^{\ast })\end{bmatrix}}}

where J ( k , c ) {\displaystyle \mathbf {J} (k^{\ast },c^{\ast })} is the Jacobian matrix evaluated at steady state, given by

J ( k , c ) = [ ρ n 1 1 σ f k k ( k ) c 0 ] {\displaystyle \mathbf {J} \left(k^{\ast },c^{\ast }\right)={\begin{bmatrix}\rho -n&-1\\{\frac {1}{\sigma }}f_{kk}(k)\cdot c^{\ast }&0\end{bmatrix}}}

which has determinant | J ( k , c ) | = 1 σ f k k ( k ) c < 0 {\displaystyle \left|\mathbf {J} \left(k^{\ast },c^{\ast }\right)\right|={\frac {1}{\sigma }}f_{kk}(k)\cdot c^{\ast }<0} since c > 0 {\displaystyle c^{*}>0} , σ {\displaystyle \sigma } is positive by assumption, and f k k < 0 {\displaystyle f_{kk}<0} since f {\displaystyle f} is concave (Inada condition). Since the determinant equals the product of the eigenvalues, the eigenvalues must be real and opposite in sign.

Hence by the stable manifold theorem, the equilibrium is a saddle point and there exists a unique stable arm, or “saddle path”, that converges on the equilibrium, indicated by the blue curve in the phase diagram.

The system is called “saddle path stable” since all unstable trajectories are ruled out by the “no Ponzi scheme” condition:

lim t k e 0 t ( f k n δ ) d s 0 {\displaystyle \lim _{t\to \infty }k\cdot e^{-\int _{0}^{t}\left(f_{k}-n-\delta \right)\mathrm {d} s}\geq 0}

implying that the present value of the capital stock cannot be negative.

History

This section has multiple issues. Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page. (Learn how and when to remove these messages)
This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.
Find sources: "Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model" – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (December 2017) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
This section possibly contains original research. Please improve it by verifying the claims made and adding inline citations. Statements consisting only of original research should be removed. (December 2017) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
This section may lend undue weight to certain ideas, incidents, or controversies. Please help improve it by rewriting it in a balanced fashion that contextualizes different points of view. (December 2017) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
(Learn how and when to remove this message)

Spear and Young re-examine the history of optimal growth during the 1950s and 1960s, focusing in part on the veracity of the claimed simultaneous and independent development of Cass' "Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation" (published in 1965 in the Review of Economic Studies), and Tjalling Koopman's "On the concept of optimal economic growth" (published in Study Week on the Econometric Approach to Development Planning, 1965, Rome: Pontifical Academy of Science).

Over their lifetimes, neither Cass nor Koopmans ever suggested that their results characterizing optimal growth in the one-sector, continuous-time growth model were anything other than "simultaneous and independent". That the issue of priority ever became a discussion point was due only to the fact that in the published version of Koopmans' work, he cited the chapter from Cass' thesis that later became the RES paper. In his paper, Koopmans states in a footnote that Cass independently obtained conditions similar to what Koopmans finds, and that Cass also considers the limiting case where the discount rate goes to zero in his paper. For his part, Cass notes that "after the original version of this paper was completed, a very similar analysis by Koopmans came to our attention. We draw on his results in discussing the limiting case, where the effective social discount rate goes to zero". In the interview that Cass gave to Macroeconomic Dynamics, he credits Koopmans with pointing him to Frank Ramsey's previous work, claiming to have been embarrassed not to have known of it, but says nothing to dispel the basic claim that his work and Koopmans' were in fact independent.

Spear and Young dispute this history, based upon a previously overlooked working paper version of Koopmans' paper, which was the basis for Koopmans' oft-cited presentation at a conference held by the Pontifical Academy of Sciences in October 1963. In this Cowles Discussion paper, there is an error. Koopmans claims in his main result that the Euler equations are both necessary and sufficient to characterize optimal trajectories in the model because any solutions to the Euler equations which do not converge to the optimal steady-state would hit either a zero consumption or zero capital boundary in finite time. This error was apparently presented at the Vatican conference, although at the time of Koopmans' presenting it, no participant commented on the problem. This can be inferred because the discussion after each paper presentation at the Vatican conference is preserved verbatim in the conference volume.

In the Vatican volume discussion following the presentation of a paper by Edmond Malinvaud, the issue does arise because of Malinvaud's explicit inclusion of a so-called "transversality condition" (which Malinvaud calls Condition I) in his paper. At the end of the presentation, Koopmans asks Malinvaud whether it is not the case that Condition I simply guarantees that solutions to the Euler equations that do not converge to the optimal steady-state hit a boundary in finite time. Malinvaud replies that this is not the case, and suggests that Koopmans look at the example with log utility functions and Cobb-Douglas production functions.

At this point, Koopmans obviously recognizes he has a problem, but, based on a confusing appendix to a later version of the paper produced after the Vatican conference, he seems unable to decide how to deal with the issue raised by Malinvaud's Condition I.

From the Macroeconomic Dynamics interview with Cass, it is clear that Koopmans met with Cass' thesis advisor, Hirofumi Uzawa, at the winter meetings of the Econometric Society in January 1964, where Uzawa advised him that his student had solved this problem already. Uzawa must have then provided Koopmans with the copy of Cass' thesis chapter, which he apparently sent along in the guise of the IMSSS Technical Report that Koopmans cited in the published version of his paper. The word "guise" is appropriate here, because the TR number listed in Koopmans' citation would have put the issue date of the report in the early 1950s, which it clearly was not.

In the published version of Koopmans' paper, he imposes a new Condition Alpha in addition to the Euler equations, stating that the only admissible trajectories among those satisfying the Euler equations is the one that converges to the optimal steady-state equilibrium of the model. This result is derived in Cass' paper via the imposition of a transversality condition that Cass deduced from relevant sections of a book by Lev Pontryagin. Spear and Young conjecture that Koopmans took this route because he did not want to appear to be "borrowing" either Malinvaud's or Cass' transversality technology.

Based on this and other examination of Malinvaud's contributions in 1950s—specifically his intuition of the importance of the transversality condition—Spear and Young suggest that the neo-classical growth model might better be called the Ramsey–Malinvaud–Cass model than the established Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans honorific.

Notes

  1. This result is due not just to the endogeneity of the saving rate but also because of the infinite nature of the planning horizon of the agents in the model; it does not hold in other models with endogenous saving rates but more complex intergenerational dynamics, for example, in Samuelson's or Diamond's overlapping generations models.
  2. The assumption that lim c 0 u c = {\displaystyle \lim _{c\to 0}u_{c}=\infty } is in fact crucial for the analysis. If u c ( 0 ) < {\displaystyle u_{c}(0)<\infty } , then for low values of k {\displaystyle k} the optimal value of c {\displaystyle c} is 0 and therefore if k ( 0 ) {\displaystyle k(0)} is sufficiently low there exists an initial time interval where c ˙ = 0 {\displaystyle {\dot {c}}=0} even if f k δ ρ > 0 {\displaystyle f_{k}-\delta -\rho >0} , see Nævdal, E. (2019). "New Insights From The Canonical Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans Growth Model". Macroeconomic Dynamics. 25 (6): 1569–1577. doi:10.1017/S1365100519000786. S2CID 214268940.
  3. The Hamiltonian for the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans problem is
    H = e ρ t u ( c ) + μ [ f ( k ) ( n + δ ) k c ] {\displaystyle H=e^{-\rho t}u(c)+\mu \left}
    where μ {\displaystyle \mu } is the costate variable usually economically interpreted as the shadow price. Because the terminal value of k {\displaystyle k} is free but may not be negative, a transversality condition lim t μ k = 0 {\displaystyle \lim _{t\to \infty }\mu \cdot k=0} similar to the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker “complementary slackness” condition is required. From the first-order conditions for maximization of the Hamiltonian one can derive the equation of motion for consumption, see Ferguson, Brian S.; Lim, G. C. (1998). Introduction to Dynamic Economic Models. Manchester University Press. pp. 174–175. ISBN 978-0-7190-4997-2, or Gandolfo, Giancarlo (1996). Economic Dynamics (3rd ed.). Berlin: Springer. pp. 381–384. ISBN 978-3-540-60988-9.
  4. The problem can also be solved with classical calculus of variations methods, see Hadley, G.; Kemp, M. C. (1971). Variational Methods in Economics. New York: Elsevier. pp. 50–71. ISBN 978-0-444-10097-9.
  5. The Jacobian matrix of the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans system is
    J ( k , c ) = [ k ˙ k k ˙ c c ˙ k c ˙ c ] = [ f k ( k ) ( n + δ ) 1 1 σ f k k ( k ) c 1 σ [ f k ( k ) δ ρ ] ] {\displaystyle \mathbf {J} \left(k,c\right)={\begin{bmatrix}{\frac {\partial {\dot {k}}}{\partial k}}&{\frac {\partial {\dot {k}}}{\partial c}}\\{\frac {\partial {\dot {c}}}{\partial k}}&{\frac {\partial {\dot {c}}}{\partial c}}\end{bmatrix}}={\begin{bmatrix}f_{k}(k)-(n+\delta )&-1\\{\frac {1}{\sigma }}f_{kk}(k)\cdot c&{\frac {1}{\sigma }}\left\end{bmatrix}}}
    See Afonso, Oscar; Vasconcelos, Paulo B. (2016). Computational Economics : A Concise Introduction. New York: Routledge. p. 163. ISBN 978-1-138-85965-4.
  6. It can be shown that the “no Ponzi scheme” condition follows from the transversality condition on the Hamiltonian, see Barro, Robert J.; Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (2004). Economic Growth (Second ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. pp. 91–92. ISBN 978-0-262-02553-9.

References

  1. Ramsey, Frank P. (1928). "A Mathematical Theory of Saving". Economic Journal. 38 (152): 543–559. doi:10.2307/2224098. JSTOR 2224098.
  2. Cass, David (1965). "Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital Accumulation". Review of Economic Studies. 32 (3): 233–240. doi:10.2307/2295827. JSTOR 2295827.
  3. Koopmans, T. C. (1965). "On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth". The Economic Approach to Development Planning. Chicago: Rand McNally. pp. 225–287.
  4. Collard, David A. (2011). "Ramsey, saving and the generations". Generations of Economists. London: Routledge. pp. 256–273. ISBN 978-0-415-56541-7.
  5. Blanchard, Olivier Jean; Fischer, Stanley (1989). Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge: MIT Press. pp. 41–43. ISBN 978-0-262-02283-5.
  6. Beavis, Brian; Dobbs, Ian (1990). Optimization and Stability Theory for Economic Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press. p. 157. ISBN 978-0-521-33605-5.
  7. Roe, Terry L.; Smith, Rodney B. W.; Saracoglu, D. Sirin (2009). Multisector Growth Models: Theory and Application. New York: Springer. p. 48. ISBN 978-0-387-77358-2.
  8. Spear, S. E.; Young, W. (2014). "Optimum Savings and Optimal Growth: The Cass–Malinvaud–Koopmans Nexus". Macroeconomic Dynamics. 18 (1): 215–243. doi:10.1017/S1365100513000291. S2CID 1340808.
  9. Koopmans, Tjalling (December 1963). "On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth" (PDF). Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper 163.
  10. McKenzie, Lionel (2002). "Some Early Conferences on Growth Theory". In Bitros, George; Katsoulacos, Yannis (eds.). Essays in Economic Theory, Growth and Labor Markets. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. pp. 3–18. ISBN 978-1-84064-739-6.
  11. Pontryagin, Lev; Boltyansky, Vladimir; Gamkrelidze, Revaz; Mishchenko, Evgenii (1962). The Mathematical Theory of Optimal Processes. New York: John Wiley.

Further reading

External links

Economics
Theoretical
Empirical
Applied
Schools
(history)
Economists
Lists
  • Category
  • Index
  • Lists
  • Outline
  • Publications
  • Business portal
  • Categories: