Misplaced Pages

Search and matching theory (economics)

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
(Redirected from Search and matching theory) Mathematical framework in economics Not to be confused with the matching approach in applied statistics.

Part of a series on
Macroeconomics
Federal Reserve
Basic concepts
Policies
Models
Related fields
SchoolsMainstream

Heterodox

People
See also

In economics, search and matching theory is a mathematical framework attempting to describe the formation of mutually beneficial relationships over time. It is closely related to stable matching theory.

Search and matching theory has been especially influential in labor economics, where it has been used to describe the formation of new jobs. Search and matching theory evolved from an earlier framework called 'search theory'. Where search theory studies the microeconomic decision of an individual searcher, search and matching theory studies the macroeconomic outcome when one or more types of searchers interact. It offers a way of modeling markets in which frictions prevent instantaneous adjustments of the level of economic activity. Among other applications, it has been used as a framework for studying frictional unemployment.

One of the founders of search and matching theory is Dale T. Mortensen of Northwestern University. A textbook treatment of the matching approach to labor markets is Christopher A. Pissarides' book Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. Mortensen and Pissarides, together with Peter A. Diamond, were awarded the 2010 Nobel Prize in Economics for 'fundamental contributions to search and matching theory'.

The matching function

A matching function is a mathematical relationship that describes the formation of new relationships (also called 'matches') from unmatched agents of the appropriate types. For example, in the context of job formation, matching functions are sometimes assumed to have the following 'Cobb–Douglas' form:

m t = M ( u t , v t ) = μ u t a v t b {\displaystyle m_{t}\;=\;M(u_{t},v_{t})\;=\;\mu u_{t}^{a}v_{t}^{b}}

where μ {\displaystyle \,\mu \,} , a {\displaystyle \,a\,} , and b {\displaystyle \,b\,} are positive constants. In this equation, u t {\displaystyle \,u_{t}\,} represents the number of unemployed job seekers in the economy at a given time t {\displaystyle \,t\,} , and v t {\displaystyle \,v_{t}\,} is the number of vacant jobs firms are trying to fill. The number of new relationships (matches) created (per unit of time) is given by m t {\displaystyle \,m_{t}\,} .

A matching function is in general analogous to a production function. However, whereas a production function usually represents the production of goods and services from inputs like labor and capital, a matching function represents the formation of new relationships from the pools of available unmatched individuals. Estimates of the labor market matching function suggest that it has constant returns to scale, that is, a + b 1 {\displaystyle a+b\approx 1} .

If the fraction of jobs that separate (due to firing, quits, and so forth) from one period to the next is δ {\displaystyle \,\delta \,} , then to calculate the change in employment from one period to the next we must add the formation of new matches and subtract off the separation of old matches. A period may be treated as a week, a month, a quarter, or some other convenient period of time, depending on the data under consideration. (For simplicity, we are ignoring the entry of new workers into the labor force, and the death or retirement of old workers, but these issues can be accounted for as well.) Suppose we write the number of workers employed in period t {\displaystyle \,t\,} as n t = L t u t {\displaystyle \,n_{t}=L_{t}-u_{t}\,} , where L t {\displaystyle \,L_{t}\,} is the labor force in period t {\displaystyle \,t\,} . Then given the matching function described above, the dynamics of employment over time would be given by

n t + 1 = μ u t a v t b + ( 1 δ ) n t {\displaystyle n_{t+1}\;=\mu u_{t}^{a}v_{t}^{b}+(1-\delta )n_{t}}

For simplicity, many studies treat δ {\displaystyle \,\delta \,} as a fixed constant. But the fraction of workers separating per period of time can be determined endogenously if we assume that the value of being matched varies over time for each worker-firm pair (due, for example, to changes in productivity).

Applications

Matching theory has been applied in many economic contexts, including:

  • Formation of jobs, from unemployed workers and vacancies opened by firms
  • Allocation of loans from banks to entrepreneurs
  • The role of money in facilitating sales when sellers and buyers meet

Controversy

Matching theory has been widely accepted as one of the best available descriptions of the frictions in the labor market, but some economists have recently questioned its quantitative accuracy. While unemployment exhibits large fluctuations over the business cycle, Robert Shimer has demonstrated that standard versions of matching models predict much smaller fluctuations in unemployment.

See also

References

  1. ^ Pissarides, Christopher (2000). Equilibrium Unemployment Theory (2nd ed.). MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-16187-9.
  2. Economic Prize Committee of the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, 'The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2010'
  3. Petrongolo, Barbara; Pissarides, Christopher (2001). "Looking into the black box: a survey of the matching function" (PDF). Journal of Economic Literature. 39 (2): 390–431. doi:10.1257/jel.39.2.390. JSTOR 2698244.
  4. ^ Mortensen, Dale; Pissarides, Christopher (1994). "Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment". Review of Economic Studies. 61 (3): 397–415. doi:10.2307/2297896. JSTOR 2297896.
  5. Haan, Wouter den; Ramey, Garey; Watson, Joel (2003). "Liquidity flows and the fragility of business enterprises" (PDF). Journal of Monetary Economics. 50 (6): 1215–1241. doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(03)00077-1. S2CID 10864047.
  6. Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro; Wright, Randall (1993). "A search-theoretic approach to monetary economics". American Economic Review. 83 (1): 63–77. JSTOR 2117496.
  7. Shimer, Robert (2005). "The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies". American Economic Review. 95 (1): 25–49. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.422.8639. doi:10.1257/0002828053828572.
Economics
Theoretical
Empirical
Applied
Schools
(history)
Economists
Lists
  • Category
  • Index
  • Lists
  • Outline
  • Publications
  • Business portal
  • Categories: