Misplaced Pages

Virtual valuation

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.

In auction theory, particularly Bayesian-optimal mechanism design, a virtual valuation of an agent is a function that measures the surplus that can be extracted from that agent.

A typical application is a seller who wants to sell an item to a potential buyer and wants to decide on the optimal price. The optimal price depends on the valuation of the buyer to the item, v {\displaystyle v} . The seller does not know v {\displaystyle v} exactly, but he assumes that v {\displaystyle v} is a random variable, with some cumulative distribution function F ( v ) {\displaystyle F(v)} and probability distribution function f ( v ) := F ( v ) {\displaystyle f(v):=F'(v)} .

The virtual valuation of the agent is defined as:

r ( v ) := v 1 F ( v ) f ( v ) {\displaystyle r(v):=v-{\frac {1-F(v)}{f(v)}}}

Applications

A key theorem of Myerson says that:

The expected profit of any truthful mechanism is equal to its expected virtual surplus.

In the case of a single buyer, this implies that the price p {\displaystyle p} should be determined according to the equation:

r ( p ) = 0 {\displaystyle r(p)=0}

This guarantees that the buyer will buy the item, if and only if his virtual-valuation is weakly-positive, so the seller will have a weakly-positive expected profit.

This exactly equals the optimal sale price – the price that maximizes the expected value of the seller's profit, given the distribution of valuations:

p = argmax v v ( 1 F ( v ) ) {\displaystyle p=\operatorname {argmax} _{v}v\cdot (1-F(v))}

Virtual valuations can be used to construct Bayesian-optimal mechanisms also when there are multiple buyers, or different item-types.

Examples

1. The buyer's valuation has a continuous uniform distribution in [ 0 , 1 ] {\displaystyle } . So:

  • F ( v ) = v  in  [ 0 , 1 ] {\displaystyle F(v)=v{\text{ in }}}
  • f ( v ) = 1  in  [ 0 , 1 ] {\displaystyle f(v)=1{\text{ in }}}
  • r ( v ) = 2 v 1  in  [ 0 , 1 ] {\displaystyle r(v)=2v-1{\text{ in }}}
  • r 1 ( 0 ) = 1 / 2 {\displaystyle r^{-1}(0)=1/2} , so the optimal single-item price is 1/2.

2. The buyer's valuation has a normal distribution with mean 0 and standard deviation 1. w ( v ) {\displaystyle w(v)} is monotonically increasing, and crosses the x-axis in about 0.75, so this is the optimal price. The crossing point moves right when the standard deviation is larger.

Regularity

A probability distribution function is called regular if its virtual-valuation function is weakly-increasing. Regularity is important because it implies that the virtual-surplus can be maximized by a truthful mechanism.

A sufficient condition for regularity is monotone hazard rate, which means that the following function is weakly-increasing:

r ( v ) := f ( v ) 1 F ( v ) {\displaystyle r(v):={\frac {f(v)}{1-F(v)}}}

Monotone-hazard-rate implies regularity, but the opposite is not true.

The proof is simple: the monotone hazard rate implies 1 r ( v ) {\displaystyle -{\frac {1}{r(v)}}} is weakly increasing in v {\displaystyle v} and therefore the virtual valuation v 1 r ( v ) {\displaystyle v-{\frac {1}{r(v)}}} is strictly increasing in v {\displaystyle v} .

See also

References

  1. Myerson, Roger B. (1981). "Optimal Auction Design". Mathematics of Operations Research. 6: 58–73. doi:10.1287/moor.6.1.58.
  2. Chawla, Shuchi; Hartline, Jason D.; Kleinberg, Robert (2007). "Algorithmic pricing via virtual valuations". Proceedings of the 8th ACM conference on Electronic commerce – EC '07. p. 243. arXiv:0808.1671. doi:10.1145/1250910.1250946. ISBN 9781595936530.
  3. See this Desmos graph.
Category: