Misplaced Pages

Great Depression: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 19:51, 18 December 2008 view sourceTempodivalse (talk | contribs)Autopatrolled, Extended confirmed users, Pending changes reviewers, Rollbackers15,794 editsm Reverted edits by 198.237.49.218 to last version by 206.226.139.1 (HG)← Previous edit Latest revision as of 02:10, 28 December 2024 view source Flurrious (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users7,634 edits Citation addedTag: Visual edit 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Worldwide economic depression (1929–1939)}}
{{pp-semi-vandalism|small=yes|expiry=December 18, 2008}}
{{redirect|The Great Depression}} {{About|the severe worldwide economic downturn in the 1930s|other uses|The Great Depression (disambiguation)}}
{{pp-vandalism|small=yes}}
]'s '']'' depicts destitute ] in ], centering on ], a mother of seven children, age 32, in ], March 1936.]]
{{Use dmy dates|date=May 2024}}{{Use American English|date=November 2023}}
The '''Great Depression''' was a worldwide economic ] starting in most places in ] and ending at different times in the 1930s or early 1940s for different countries. It was the largest and most important economic depression in modern history, and is used in the 21st century as an example of how far the world's economy can fall. The Great Depression originated in the United States; historians most often use as a starting date the ] on October 29, 1929, known as ]. The end of the depression in the U.S is associated with the onset of the ] of ], beginning around 1939.<ref>{{cite book |title=The Cambridge Economic History of the United States |last=L. Engerman |first=Stanley |authorlink=Stanley L. Engerman |coauthors= Gallman, Robert E. }} </ref>
] people lined up outside a ] opened in ] by ] during the Great Depression in February 1931|upright=1.35]]
The '''Great Depression''' was a severe global ] from 1929 to 1939. The period was characterized by high rates of ] and ]; drastic ], industrial production, and trade; and widespread bank and business failures around the world. The ] began in 1929 in the ], the largest economy in the world, with the devastating ] of October 1929 often considered the beginning of the Depression. Among the countries with the most unemployed were the U.S., the ], and ].


The Depression was preceded by a period of industrial growth and social development known as the "]". Much of the profit generated by the boom was invested in ], such as on the ], which resulted in growing ]. Banks were subject to minimal regulation under '']'' economic policies, resulting in loose lending and widespread debt. By 1929, declining spending had led to reductions in manufacturing output and rising unemployment. Share values continued to rise until the Wall Street crash, after which the slide continued for three years, accompanied by a loss of confidence in the financial system. By 1933, the unemployment rate in the U.S. had risen to 25 percent, about one-third of farmers had lost their land, and about half of its 25,000 banks had gone out of business. The ] under President ] was unwilling to intervene heavily in the economy. In the ], Hoover was defeated by ], who from 1933 pursued a set of expansive ] programs in order to provide relief and create jobs. In Germany, which depended heavily on U.S. loans, the crisis caused unemployment to rise to nearly 30% and fueled political extremism, paving the way for ]'s ] to rise to power in 1933.
The depression had devastating effects in the ] and ] worlds. International trade was deeply affected, as were personal ]s, ]s, ]s, and ]s. ] were hit hard, especially those dependent on ]. Construction was virtually halted in many countries. ] and rural areas suffered as crop prices fell by roughly 60 percent.<ref name="USBLS">{{cite web|url=http://www.bls.gov/data/|title=Commodity Data|publisher=US Bureau of Labor Statistics|accessdate=2008-11-30}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|author= Cochrane, Willard W.|title=Farm Prices, Myth and Reality|year=1958|pages=15}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|journal=]|title=World Economic Survey 1932–33|pages=43}}</ref> Facing plummeting demand with few alternate sources of jobs, areas dependent on ] such as farming, ] and ] suffered the most.<ref>{{cite book| last = Hakim | first = Joy | title = A History of Us: War, Peace and all that Jazz | publisher = ]| year = 1995| location = New York| isbn=0195094840}}</ref>
However, even shortly after the Wall Street Crash of 1929, optimism persisted; ] said that "These are days when many are discouraged. In the 93 years of my life, depressions have come and gone. Prosperity has always returned and will again."<ref>{{cite web
|url= http://us.history.wisc.edu/hist102/lectures/lecture18.html
|title= Crashing Hopes: The Great Depression
|accessdate= 2008-03-13
|last= Schultz
|first= Stanley K.
|year= 1999
|work= American History 102: Civil War to the Present
|publisher= ]
}}.</ref>


Between 1929 and 1932, worldwide ] (GDP) fell by an estimated 15%; in the U.S., the Depression resulted in a 30% contraction in GDP.<ref name=":5">{{Cite book |last=Friedman |first=Milton |title=A monetary history of the United States 1867-1960 |last2=Schwartz |first2=Anna Jacobson |date=2008 |publisher=Princeton University Press |isbn=978-0-691-00354-2 |edition=9th pbk. printing, 22nd printing |series=Princeton paperbacks |location=Princeton}}</ref> Recovery varied greatly around the world. Some economies, such as the U.S., Germany and Japan started to recover by the mid-1930s; others, like France, did not return to pre-shock growth rates until later in the decade.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Lewis |first=William Arthur |title=Economic survey: 1919 - 1939 |date=2003 |isbn=978-0-415-31359-9 |edition=Reprint 1949 |series=International economics |location=London : Routledge}}</ref> The Depression had devastating economic effects on both wealthy and poor countries: all experienced drops in ], prices (]), tax revenues, and profits. International trade fell by more than 50%, and unemployment in some countries rose as high as 33%.<ref name="Frank_Bernanke">{{cite book |last1=Frank |first1=Robert H. |title=Principles of Macroeconomics |last2=Bernanke |first2=Ben S. |publisher=McGraw-Hill/Irwin |year=2007 |isbn=978-0-07-319397-7 |edition=3rd |location=Boston |page=98}}</ref> ], especially those dependent on ], were heavily affected. Construction virtually halted in many countries, and farming communities and rural areas suffered as crop prices fell by up to 60%.<ref name="USBLS">{{cite web |title=Commodity Data |url=https://www.bls.gov/data/ |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190603140110/https://www.bls.gov/data/ |archive-date=3 June 2019 |access-date=30 November 2008 |publisher=U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |author=Cochrane, Willard W. |author-link=Willard Cochrane |title=Farm Prices, Myth and Reality |year=1958 |page=15}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |title=World Economic Survey 1932–33 |journal=] |page=43}}</ref> Faced with plummeting demand and few job alternatives, areas dependent on ] suffered the most.<ref>Mitchell, ''Depression Decade''</ref> The outbreak of ] in 1939 ended the Depression, as it stimulated factory production, providing jobs for women as militaries absorbed large numbers of young, unemployed men.
The Great Depression ended at different times in different countries; for subsequent history see ]. The majority of countries set up relief programs, and most underwent some sort of political upheaval, pushing them to the left or right. In some states, the desperate citizens turned toward nationalist ] - the most infamous being ] - setting the stage for ] in 1939.
{{TOClimit|limit=2}}


The precise causes for the Great Depression are disputed. One set of historians, for example, focuses on non-monetary economic causes. Among these, some regard the Wall Street crash itself as the main cause; others consider that the crash was a mere symptom of more general economic trends of the time, which had already been underway in the late 1920s.<ref name="Frank_Bernanke" /><ref name="Britannica"> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150509121741/https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/243118/Great-Depression|date=9 May 2015}}, ''Encyclopædia Britannica''</ref> A contrasting set of views, which rose to prominence in the later part of the 20th century,<ref>Thomas S. Coleman (2019). ''Milton Friedman, Anna Schwartz, and A Monetary History of the US.'' Draft Lecture, Harris School of Public Policy, University of Chicago.</ref> ascribes a more prominent role to failures of ]. According to those authors, while general economic trends can explain the emergence of the downturn, they fail to account for its severity and longevity; they argue that these were caused by the lack of an adequate response to the crises of liquidity that followed the initial economic shock of 1929 and the subsequent bank failures accompanied by a general collapse of the financial markets.<ref name=":5" />
==The deflation spiral==
]
The Great Depression was not triggered by a sudden, total collapse in the stock market. The stock market turned upward in early 1930, returning to early 1929 levels by April, though still almost 30 percent below the peak of September 1929.<ref>{{cite web|accessdate=2008-05-22|url=http://www.gold-eagle.com/editorials_98/vronsky060698.html|title=1998/99 Prognosis Based Upon 1929 Market Autopsy|publisher=Gold Eagle}}.</ref> Together, government and business actually spent more in the first half of 1930 than in the corresponding period of the previous year. But consumers, many of whom had suffered severe losses in the stock market the previous year, cut back their expenditures by ten percent, and a severe drought ravaged the agricultural heartland of the USA beginning in the summer of 1930.


== Overview ==
In early 1930, credit was ample and available at low rates, but people were reluctant to add new debt by borrowing. By May 1930, auto sales had declined to below the levels of 1928. Prices in general began to decline, but wages held steady in 1930, then began to drop in 1931. Conditions were worst in farming areas, where commodity prices plunged, and in mining and logging areas, where unemployment was high and there were few other jobs. The decline in the ] was the factor that pulled down most other countries at first, then internal weaknesses or strengths in each country made conditions worse or better. Frantic attempts to shore up the economies of individual nations through ] policies, such as the 1930 U.S. ] and retaliatory tariffs in other countries, exacerbated the collapse in global trade. By late in 1930, a steady decline set in which reached bottom by March 1933.
{{Multiple image
| image1 = US Unemployment from 1910-1960.svg
| image2 = 1929 wall street crash graph.svg
| caption1 = The unemployment rate in the U.S. during 1910–60, with the years of the Great Depression (1929–39) highlighted
| caption2 = The ], 1928–1930
| align = left
}}


=== The economic picture at the beginning of the crisis ===
==Causes ==
After the ], when the ] dropped from 381 to 198 over the course of two months, optimism persisted for some time. The stock market rose in early 1930, with the Dow returning to 294 (pre-depression levels) in April 1930, before steadily declining for years, to a low of 41 in 1932.<ref>{{cite web |title=1998/99 Prognosis Based Upon 1929 Market Autopsy |url=https://www.gold-eagle.com/editorials_98/vronsky060698.html |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080517075810/https://www.gold-eagle.com/editorials_98/vronsky060698.html |archive-date=17 May 2008 |access-date=22 May 2008 |publisher=Gold Eagle}}</ref>

At the beginning, governments and businesses spent more in the first half of 1930 than in the corresponding period of the previous year. On the other hand, consumers, many of whom suffered severe losses in the stock market the previous year, cut expenditures by 10%. In addition, beginning in the mid-1930s, a ] ravaged the agricultural heartland of the U.S.<ref name="drought">{{cite web |title=Drought: A Paleo Perspective&nbsp;– 20th Century Drought |url=https://www.ncdc.noaa.gov/paleo/drought/drght_history.html |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090330022940/http://www.ncdc.noaa.gov/paleo/drought/drght_history.html |archive-date=30 March 2009 |access-date=5 April 2009 |publisher=]}}</ref>

Interest rates dropped to low levels by mid-1930, but expected ] and the continuing reluctance of people to borrow meant that consumer spending and investment remained low.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Hamilton |first=James |year=1987 |title=Monetary Factors in the Great Depression |journal=Journal of Monetary Economics |volume=19 |issue=2 |pages=145–69 |doi=10.1016/0304-3932(87)90045-6| issn=0304-3932}}</ref> By May 1930, automobile sales declined to below the levels of 1928. Prices, in general, began to decline, although wages held steady in 1930. Then a ] started in 1931. Farmers faced a worse outlook; declining crop prices and a Great Plains drought crippled their economic outlook. At its peak, the Great Depression saw nearly 10% of all Great Plains farms change hands despite federal assistance.<ref>{{Cite web |title=The Great Depression |url=https://drought.unl.edu/DroughtBasics/DustBowl/TheGreatDepression.aspx |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180329184059/http://drought.unl.edu/DroughtBasics/DustBowl/TheGreatDepression.aspx |archive-date=29 March 2018 |access-date=29 March 2018 |website=drought.unl.edu |language=en-US}}</ref>

=== Beyond the U.S. ===
At first, the decline in the ] was the factor that triggered economic downturns in most other countries due to a decline in trade, capital movement, and global business confidence. Then, internal weaknesses or strengths in each country made conditions worse or better. For example, the U.K. economy, which experienced an economic downturn throughout most of the late 1920s, was less severely impacted by the shock of the depression than the U.S. By contrast, the German economy saw a similar decline in industrial output as that observed in the U.S.<ref name=cpk>{{Cite book |last=Kindleberger |first=Charles P. |title=The world in depression, 1929–1939 |date=1986 |publisher=University of California Press |isbn=978-0-520-05591-9 |edition=Rev. and enl. |series=History of the world economy in the twentieth century |location=Berkeley}}</ref> Some economic historians attribute the differences in the rates of recovery and relative severity of the economic decline to whether particular countries had been able to effectively devaluate their currencies or not. This is supported by the contrast in how the crisis progressed in, e.g., Britain, Argentina and Brazil, all of which devalued their currencies early and returned to normal patterns of growth relatively rapidly and countries which stuck to the ], such as France or Belgium.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Kindleberger |first=Charles Poor |title=The world in depression, 1929–1939 |date=1973 |publisher=University of California Press |isbn=978-0-520-05592-6 |edition=Rev. and enl. ed., 11. |series=History of the world economy in the twentieth century |location=Berkeley, Calif.}}</ref>

Frantic attempts by individual countries to shore up their economies through ] policies – such as the 1930 U.S. ] and retaliatory tariffs in other countries – exacerbated the collapse in global trade, contributing to the depression.<ref>{{cite book |title=Historic Events for Students: The Great Depression |date=July 2002 |publisher=Gale |isbn=978-0-7876-5701-7 |editor-last1=Richard |editor-first1=Clay Hanes |edition=Volume I}}</ref> By 1933, the economic decline pushed world trade to one third of its level compared to four years earlier.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Tignor |first= Robert L. |title=Worlds together, worlds apart: a history of the world from the beginnings of humankind to the present |date=28 October 2013 |isbn=978-0-393-92207-3 |edition=Fourth |location=New York |oclc=854609153 |publisher=W. W. Norton}}</ref>
{| class="wikitable" style="width: 50%;text-align: right;"
|+ Change in economic indicators 1929–1932<ref>], ], ], ''The European world: a history,'' (2nd ed 1970), 885 pp.</ref>
|-
! scope="col" style="width:36%;"|
! scope="col" style="width:16%; text-align:center;"| United States
! scope="col" style="width:16%; text-align:center;"| United Kingdom
! scope="col" style="width:16%; text-align:center;"| France
! scope="col" style="width:16%; text-align:center;"| Germany
|-
| style="text-align: left;"| Industrial production
| −46%
| −23%
| −24%
| −41%
|-
| style="text-align: left;"| Wholesale prices
| −32%
| −33%
| −34%
| −29%
|-
| style="text-align: left;"| Foreign trade
| −70%
| −60%
| −54%
| −61%
|-
| style="text-align: left;"| Unemployment
| +607%
| +129%
| +214%
| +232%
|}

== Course ==
] and Broad Street after the ]]]

=== Origins ===
While the precise causes for the occurrence of the Great depression are disputed and can be traced to both global and national phenomena, its immediate origins are most conveniently examined in the context of the U.S. economy, from which the initial crisis spread to the rest of the world.

In the aftermath of ], the ] brought considerable wealth to the United States and Western Europe.<ref name="Soule-1947">George H. Soule, ''Prosperity Decade: From War to Depression: 1917–1929,'' (1947).</ref> Initially, the year 1929 dawned with good economic prospects: despite a minor crash on 25 March 1929, the market seemed to gradually improve through September. Stock prices began to slump in September, and were volatile at the end of the month.<ref name="pbsstock2">{{cite web |title=Timeline: A selected Wall Street chronology |url=https://www.pbs.org/wgbh/amex/crash/timeline/timeline2.html |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080923040829/http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/amex/crash/timeline/timeline2.html |archive-date=23 September 2008 |access-date=30 September 2008 |publisher=]}}</ref> A large sell-off of stocks began in mid-October. Finally, on 24 October, ], the American stock market crashed 11% at the opening bell. Actions to stabilize the market failed, and on 28 October, Black Monday, the market crashed another 12%. The panic peaked the next day on Black Tuesday, when the market saw another 11% drop.<ref name=":02">{{Cite news |last1=Post |first1=Special to Financial |date=24 October 2011 |title=The Great Crash of 1929, some key dates |language=en-CA |website=Financial Post |url=https://financialpost.com/personal-finance/the-great-crash-of-1929-some-key-dates |access-date=22 July 2020}}</ref><ref name=":4">{{cite web |author=<!--ET Bureau--> |date=22 October 2017 |title=Market crash of 1929: Some facts of the economic downturn |url=https://economictimes.indiatimes.com/industry/miscellaneous/market-crash-of-1929-some-facts-of-the-economic-downturn/articleshow/61166918.cms |access-date=16 February 2019 |work=Economic Times |publisher=Times Inernet}}</ref>
Thousands of investors were ruined, and billions of dollars had been lost; many stocks could not be sold at any price.<ref name=":4" /> The market recovered 12% on Wednesday but by then significant damage had been done. Though the market entered a period of recovery from 14 November until 17 April 1930, the general situation had been a prolonged slump. From 17 April 1930 until 8 July 1932, the market continued to lose 89% of its value.<ref>According to the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data website, based on a monthly timeseries 1929 September – 1932 June, the Dow Jones Industrial Average lost 87.1% while the Cowles Commission and S&P's all stock index lost 85.0%: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=qj2m , https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=qj2l.</ref>

] in New York after its failure in 1931]]

Despite the crash, the worst of the crisis did not reverberate around the world until after 1929. The crisis hit panic levels again in December 1930, with a ] on the ], a former privately run bank, bearing no relation to the U.S. government (not to be confused with the ]). Unable to pay out to all of its creditors, the bank failed.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Gordon |first=John Steele |date=November–December 2018 |title=The Bank of United States |url=https://www.proquest.com/docview/2160290916 |journal=ABA Banking Journal |volume=110 |issue=6 |pages=58 |id={{ProQuest|2160290916}}}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal |last=Calomiris |first=Charles W. |date=November 2007 |title=Bank Failures in Theory and History: The Great Depression and Other "Contagious" Events |url=https://www.nber.org/papers/w13597 |journal=National Bureau of Economic Research|series=Working Paper Series |location=Cambridge, MA |doi=10.3386/w13597 |s2cid=154123748 |doi-access=free }}</ref>
Among the 608 American banks that closed in November and December 1930, the Bank of United States accounted for a third of the total $550 million deposits lost and, with its closure, bank failures reached a critical mass.<ref>{{Citation |last=Ferguson |first=Niall |title=The Ascent of Money |date=October 2009 |pages=163 |publisher=Penguin |isbn=978-986-173-584-9}}</ref>

=== The Smoot–Hawley Act and the Breakdown of International Trade ===
{{Main|Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act}}

] (left) and ] in April 1929, shortly before the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act passed the House of Representatives]]

In an initial response to the crisis, the U.S. Congress passed the ] on 17 June 1930. The Act was ostensibly aimed at protecting the American economy from foreign competition by imposing high tariffs on foreign imports. The consensus view among ]s and economic historians (including ]s, ]s and ]s) is that the passage of the Smoot–Hawley Tariff had, in fact, achieved an opposite effect to what was intended. It exacerbated the Great Depression<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Whaples |first=Robert |author-link=Robert Whaples |date=March 1995 |title=Where Is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions |journal=] |publisher=] |volume=55 |issue=1 |page=144 |doi=10.1017/S0022050700040602 |jstor=2123771 |s2cid=145691938}}</ref> by preventing economic recovery after domestic production recovered, hampering the volume of trade; still there is disagreement as to the precise extent of the Act's influence.

In the popular view, the Smoot–Hawley Tariff was one of the leading causes of the depression.<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210225033620/https://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/11/30/protectionism-and-the-great-depression/|date=25 February 2021}}, ], ''],'' 30 November 2009</ref><ref name="eichenirwin">Barry Eichengreen, Douglas Irwin (17 March 2009). . {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120524215509/http://voxeu.org/index.php?q=node%2F3280|date=24 May 2012}}. VOX.</ref> In a 1995 survey of American economic historians, two-thirds agreed that the ] at least worsened the Great Depression.<ref name="ReferenceB" /> According to the U.S. Senate website, the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act is among the most catastrophic acts in congressional history.<ref name="Senate_On_Smoot-Hawley Act">{{cite web |title=The Senate Passes the Smoot-Hawley Tariff |url=https://www.senate.gov/artandhistory/history/minute/Senate_Passes_Smoot_Hawley_Tariff.htm |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211020163037/https://www.senate.gov/artandhistory/history/minute/Senate_Passes_Smoot_Hawley_Tariff.htm |archive-date=20 October 2021 |access-date=3 May 2020 |website=United States Senate }}</ref>

Many economists have argued that the sharp decline in international trade after 1930 helped to worsen the depression, especially for countries significantly dependent on foreign trade. Most historians and economists blame the Act for worsening the depression by seriously reducing international trade and causing retaliatory tariffs in other countries. While foreign trade was a small part of overall economic activity in the U.S. and was concentrated in a few businesses like farming, it was a much larger factor in many other countries.<ref>{{cite web |title=The World in Depression |url=https://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/intrel/depress.htm |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080310145946/https://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/intrel/depress.htm |archive-date=10 March 2008 |access-date=22 May 2008 |publisher=]}}</ref> The average '']'' (value based) rate of duties on dutiable imports for 1921–1925 was 25.9% but under the new tariff it jumped to 50% during 1931–1935. In dollar terms, American exports declined over the next four years from about $5.2&nbsp;billion in 1929 to $1.7&nbsp;billion in 1933; so, not only did the physical volume of exports fall, but also the prices fell by about {{frac|1|3}} as written. Hardest hit were farm commodities such as wheat, cotton, tobacco, and lumber.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Parker |first=Selwyn |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/The_Great_Crash/iA05AgAAQBAJ?hl=en&gbpv=1&dq=Smoot-Hawley+wheat,+cotton,+tobacco,+and+lumber&pg=PT146&printsec=frontcover |title=The Great Crash: How the Stock Market Crash of 1929 Plunged the World into Depression |date=2010-09-02 |publisher=Little, Brown Book Group |isbn=978-0-7481-2231-8 |language=en}}</ref>

Governments around the world took various steps into spending less money on foreign goods such as: "imposing tariffs, import quotas, and exchange controls". These restrictions triggered much tension among countries that had large amounts of bilateral trade, causing major export-import reductions during the depression. Not all governments enforced the same measures of protectionism. Some countries raised tariffs drastically and enforced severe restrictions on foreign exchange transactions, while other countries reduced "trade and exchange restrictions only marginally":<ref name="Eichengreen">{{cite journal |last1=Eichengreen |first1=B. |last2=Irwin |first2=D. A. |year=2010 |title=The Slide to Protectionism in the Great Depression: Who Succumbed and Why? |url=https://www.nber.org/papers/w15142.pdf |url-status=live |journal=Journal of Economic History |volume=70 |issue=4 |pages=871–897 |doi=10.1017/s0022050710000756 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190514111715/https://www.nber.org/papers/w15142.pdf |archive-date=14 May 2019 |access-date=18 February 2022 |s2cid=18906612}}</ref>
* "Countries that remained on the gold standard, keeping currencies fixed, were more likely to restrict foreign trade." These countries "resorted to protectionist policies to strengthen the ] and limit gold losses." They hoped that these restrictions and depletions would hold the economic decline.<ref name="Eichengreen" />
* Countries that abandoned the gold standard allowed their currencies to ] which caused their balance of payments to strengthen. It also freed up monetary policy so that central banks could lower interest rates and act as lenders of last resort. They possessed the best policy instruments to fight the Depression and did not need protectionism.<ref name="Eichengreen" />
* "The length and depth of a country's economic downturn and the timing and vigor of its recovery are related to how long it remained on the ]. Countries abandoning the gold standard relatively early experienced relatively mild recessions and early recoveries. In contrast, countries remaining on the gold standard experienced prolonged slumps."<ref name="Eichengreen" />

=== The Gold Standard and the Spreading of Global Depression ===
The ] was the primary transmission mechanism of the Great Depression. Even countries that did not face bank failures and a monetary contraction first-hand were forced to join the deflationary policy since higher interest rates in countries that performed a deflationary policy led to a gold outflow in countries with lower interest rates. Under the gold standard's ], countries that lost gold but nevertheless wanted to maintain the gold standard had to permit their money supply to decrease and the domestic price level to decline (]).<ref>Peter Temin, Gianni Toniolo, ''The World Economy between the Wars'', Oxford University Press, 2008, {{ISBN|978-0-19-804201-3}}, p. 106</ref><ref>Randall E. Parker, ''Reflections on the Great Depression'', Elgar publishing, 2003, {{ISBN|978-1-84376-335-2}}, p. 22.</ref>

There is also consensus that protectionist policies, and primarily the passage of the ], helped to exacerbate, or even cause the Great Depression.<ref name="ReferenceB">{{Cite journal |last1=Whaples |first1=Robert |year=1995 |title=Where is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions |journal=The Journal of Economic History |volume=55 |issue=1 |pages=139–154 |doi=10.1017/S0022050700040602 |jstor=2123771 |s2cid=145691938}}</ref>

==== Gold standard ====
]

Some economic studies have indicated that the rigidities of the ] not only spread the downturn worldwide, but also suspended gold convertibility (devaluing the currency in gold terms) that did the most to make recovery possible.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Eichengreen |first=Barry |url=https://archive.org/details/goldenfettersgol00eich |title=Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939 |publisher=Oxford University Press |year=1992 |isbn=0-19-506431-3 |location=New York |author-link=Barry Eichengreen}}</ref>

Every major currency left the gold standard during the Great Depression. The UK was the first to do so. Facing ]s on the ] and depleting ], in September 1931 the ] ceased exchanging pound notes for gold and the pound was floated on foreign exchange markets. Japan and the Scandinavian countries followed in 1931. Other countries, such as Italy and the United States, remained on the gold standard into 1932 or 1933, while a few countries in the so-called "gold bloc", led by France and including Poland, Belgium and Switzerland, stayed on the standard until 1935–36.

According to later analysis, the earliness with which a country left the gold standard reliably predicted its economic recovery. For example, The UK and Scandinavia, which left the gold standard in 1931, recovered much earlier than France and Belgium, which remained on gold much longer. Countries such as China, which had a ], almost avoided the depression entirely. The connection between leaving the gold standard as a strong predictor of that country's severity of its depression and the length of time of its recovery has been shown to be consistent for dozens of countries, including ]. This partly explains why the experience and length of the depression differed between regions and states around the world.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Bernanke |first=Ben |date=2 March 2004 |title=Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke: Money, Gold and the Great Depression |journal=At the H. Parker Willis Lecture in Economic Policy, Washington and Lee University, Lexington, Virginia |url=https://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/200403022/default.htm |access-date=18 February 2022 |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220215053205/https://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/200403022/default.htm |archive-date=15 February 2022}}</ref>

==== German banking crisis of 1931 and British crisis ====
The financial crisis escalated out of control in mid-1931, starting with the collapse of the ] in Vienna in May.<ref>], ''Britain between the wars, 1918–1940'' (1955) pp. 379–385.</ref><ref name="William Ashworth 1962 pp. 237-244">William Ashworth, ''A short history of the international economy since 1850,'' (2nd ed. 1962), pp. 237–244.</ref> This put heavy pressure on Germany, which was already in political turmoil. With the rise in violence of National Socialist ('Nazi') and Communist movements, as well as investor nervousness at harsh government financial policies,<ref name="Isabel Schnabel 1931">Isabel Schnabel, "The German twin crisis of 1931". ''Journal of Economic History'' 64#3 (2004): 822–871.</ref> investors withdrew their short-term money from Germany as confidence spiraled downward. The Reichsbank lost 150&nbsp;million marks in the first week of June, 540&nbsp;million in the second, and 150&nbsp;million in two days, 19–20 June. Collapse was at hand. U.S. President Herbert Hoover called for a ]. This angered Paris, which depended on a steady flow of German payments, but it slowed the crisis down, and the moratorium was agreed to in July 1931. An International conference in London later in July produced no agreements but on 19 August a standstill agreement froze Germany's foreign liabilities for six months. Germany received emergency funding from private banks in New York as well as the Bank of International Settlements and the Bank of England. The funding only slowed the process. Industrial failures began in Germany, a major bank closed in July and a two-day holiday for all German banks was declared. Business failures were more frequent in July, and spread to ] and Hungary. The crisis continued to get worse in Germany, bringing political upheaval that finally led to the ] in January 1933.<ref name="V. Hodson, 1938 pp. 64-76">H. V. Hodson (1938), ''Slump and Recovery, 1929–1937'' (London), pp. 64–76.</ref>

The world financial crisis now began to overwhelm Britain; investors around the world started withdrawing their gold from London at the rate of £2.5&nbsp;million per day.<ref name="David Williams 1963">{{cite journal |last1=Williams |first1=David |year=1963 |title=London and the 1931 financial crisis |journal=Economic History Review |volume=15 |issue=3 |pages=513–528 |doi=10.2307/2592922 |jstor=2592922}}</ref> Credits of £25&nbsp;million each from the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and an issue of £15&nbsp;million fiduciary note slowed, but did not reverse, the British crisis. The financial crisis now caused a major political crisis in Britain in August 1931. With deficits mounting, the bankers demanded a balanced budget; the divided cabinet of Prime Minister Ramsay MacDonald's Labour government agreed; it proposed to raise taxes, cut spending, and most controversially, to cut unemployment benefits 20%. The attack on welfare was unacceptable to the Labour movement. MacDonald wanted to resign, but King George V insisted he remain and form an all-party coalition "]". The Conservative and Liberals parties signed on, along with a small cadre of Labour, but the vast majority of Labour leaders denounced MacDonald as a traitor for leading the new government. Britain went off the ], and suffered relatively less than other major countries in the Great Depression. In the 1931 British election, the Labour Party was virtually destroyed, leaving MacDonald as prime minister for a largely Conservative coalition.<ref>Mowat (1955), ''Britain between the wars, 1918–1940'', pp. 386–412.</ref><ref name="John Oxborrow 1976 pp. 67-73">Sean Glynn and John Oxborrow (1976), ''Interwar Britain : a social and economic history'', pp. 67–73.</ref>

=== Turning point and recovery ===
{{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100904025051/http://www.measuringworth.org/usgdp/|date=4 September 2010}}</ref>]]

In most countries of the world, recovery from the Great Depression began in 1933.<ref name="Britannica" /> In the U.S., recovery began in early 1933,<ref name="Britannica" /> but the U.S. did not return to 1929 GNP for over a decade and still had an unemployment rate of about 15% in 1940, albeit down from the high of 25% in 1933.

There is no consensus among economists regarding the motive force for the U.S. economic expansion that continued through most of the ] (and the 1937 recession that interrupted it). The common view among most economists is that Roosevelt's ] policies either caused or accelerated the recovery, although his policies were never aggressive enough to bring the economy completely out of recession. Some economists have also called attention to the positive effects from expectations of ] and rising nominal interest rates that Roosevelt's words and actions portended.<ref>Gauti B. Eggertsson, "Great Expectations and the End of the Depression", ''American Economic Review'' 98, No. 4 (September 2008): 1476–1516</ref><ref>"Was the New Deal Contractionary?" ] Staff Report 264, October 2006, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220212162504/https://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr264.html|date=12 February 2022}}</ref> It was the rollback of those same reflationary policies that led to the interruption of a recession beginning in late 1937.<ref>"The Mistake of 1937: A General Equilibrium Analysis", ''Monetary and Economic Studies'' 24, No. S-1 (December 2006), {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150811112759/https://www.imes.boj.or.jp/english/publication/mes/2006/abst/me24-s1-8.html|date=11 August 2015}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Eggertsson |first1=Gauti B. |title=A Reply to Steven Horwitz's Commentary on 'Great Expectations and the End of the Great Depression' |url=https://econjwatch.org/articles/a-reply-to-steven-horwitz-s-commentary-on-great-expectations-and-the-end-of-the-depression- |url-status=live |journal=Econ Journal Watch |volume=7 |issue=3 |pages=197–204 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220215053116/https://econjwatch.org/articles/a-reply-to-steven-horwitz-s-commentary-on-great-expectations-and-the-end-of-the-depression- |archive-date=15 February 2022 |access-date=18 February 2022}}</ref> One contributing policy that reversed reflation was the ], which effectively raised reserve requirements, causing a monetary contraction that helped to thwart the recovery.<ref>Steven Horwitz, "Unfortunately Unfamiliar with Robert Higgs and Others: A Rejoinder to Gauti Eggertsson on the 1930s", ''Econ Journal Watch'' 8(1), 2, January 2011. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220215053127/https://econjwatch.org/articles/unfortunately-unfamiliar-with-robert-higgs-and-others-a-rejoinder-to-gauti-eggertsson-on-the-1930s|date=15 February 2022}}.</ref> GDP returned to its upward trend in 1938.<ref name=":0" /> A revisionist view among some economists holds that the New Deal prolonged the Great Depression, as they argue that ] and ] restricted competition and established price fixing.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Hannsgen |first1=Greg |last2=Papadimitriou |first2=Dimitri |date=2010 |title=Did the New Deal Prolong or Worsen the Great Depression? |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/40722622 |journal=Challenge |volume=53 |issue=1 |pages=63–86 |doi=10.2753/0577-5132530103 |jstor=40722622 |s2cid=153490746 |issn=0577-5132}}</ref> ] did not think that the New Deal under Roosevelt single-handedly ended the Great Depression: "It is, it seems, politically impossible for a capitalistic democracy to organize expenditure on the scale necessary to make the grand experiments which would prove my case—except in war conditions."<ref>Quoted by P. Renshaw. ''Journal of Contemporary History''. 1999 vol. 34 (3). pp. 377–364</ref>

According to ], the money supply growth caused by huge international gold inflows was a crucial source of the recovery of the United States economy, and that the economy showed little sign of self-correction. The gold inflows were partly due to ] and partly due to deterioration of the political situation in Europe.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Romer |first=Christina D. |date=December 1992 |title=What Ended the Great Depression |url=https://elsa.berkeley.edu/~cromer/What%20Ended%20the%20Great%20Depression.pdf |url-status=dead |journal=Journal of Economic History |volume=52 |issue=4 |pages=757–84 |citeseerx=10.1.1.207.844 |doi=10.1017/S002205070001189X |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130117093624/https://elsa.berkeley.edu/~cromer/What%20Ended%20the%20Great%20Depression.pdf |archive-date=17 January 2013 |quote=monetary development were crucial to the recovery implies that self-correction played little role in the growth of real output}}</ref> In their book, '']'', ] and ] also attributed the recovery to monetary factors, and contended that it was much slowed by poor management of money by the ]. ] (2006–2014) ] agreed that monetary factors played important roles both in the worldwide economic decline and eventual recovery.<ref>Ben Bernanke. ''Essays on the Great Depression''. Princeton University Press. {{ISBN|978-0-691-01698-6}}. p. 7</ref> Bernanke also saw a strong role for institutional factors, particularly the rebuilding and restructuring of the financial system,<ref>Ben S. Bernanke, "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propaga-tion of the Great Depression", ''The American Economic Review 73'', No. 3 (June 1983): 257–276, available from the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank collection at {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160305072448/https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/scribd/?item_id=2348&filepath=%2Fdocs%2Fpublications%2Faer%2Faer_1983_bernanke_nonmonetary_effects.pdf|date=5 March 2016}}</ref> and pointed out that the Depression should be examined in an international perspective.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Bernanke |first=Ben S. |date=February 1995 |title=The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach |url=https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/scribd/?item_id=2399&filepath=/docs/meltzer/bermac95.pdf |url-status=live |journal=Journal of Money, Credit and Banking |publisher=Fraser.stlouisfed.org |volume=27 |issue=1 |pages=1–28 |doi=10.2307/2077848 |jstor=2077848 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304201917/https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/scribd/?item_id=2399&filepath=%2Fdocs%2Fmeltzer%2Fbermac95.pdf |archive-date=4 March 2016 |access-date=16 October 2014}}</ref>

==== Role of women and household economics ====
Women's primary role was as housewives; without a steady flow of family income, their work became much harder in dealing with food and clothing and medical care. Birthrates fell everywhere, as children were postponed until families could financially support them. The average birthrate for 14 major countries fell 12% from 19.3 births per thousand population in 1930, to 17.0 in 1935.<ref>W. S. Woytinsky and E. S. Woytinsky, ''World population and production: trends and outlook'' (1953) p. 148</ref> In Canada, half of Roman Catholic women defied Church teachings and used contraception to postpone births.<ref>Denyse Baillargeon, ''Making Do: Women, Family and Home in Montreal during the Great Depression'' (Wilfrid Laurier University Press, 1999), p. 159.</ref>

Among the few women in the labor force, layoffs were less common in the white-collar jobs and they were typically found in light manufacturing work. However, there was a widespread demand to limit families to one paid job, so that wives might lose employment if their husband was employed.<ref>{{cite book |last=Stephenson |first=Jill |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=-rqOAwAAQBAJ&pg=PA3 |title=Women in Nazi Germany |publisher=Taylor & Francis |year=2014 |isbn=978-1-317-87607-6 |pages=3–5 |access-date=27 June 2015 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210816172022/https://books.google.com/books?id=-rqOAwAAQBAJ&pg=PA3 |archive-date=16 August 2021 |url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |author=Susan K. Foley |url=https://archive.org/details/womeninfrancesin00fole |title=Women in France Since 1789: The Meanings of Difference |publisher=Palgrave Macmillan |year=2004 |isbn=978-0-230-80214-8 |pages=–90 |author-link1=Susan Foley |url-access=registration}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Srigley |first=Katrina |url=https://archive.org/details/breadwinningdaug00srig |title=Breadwinning Daughters: Young Working Women in a Depression-era City, 1929–1939 |publisher=University of Toronto Press |year=2010 |isbn=978-1-4426-1003-3 |page= |url-access=registration}}</ref> Across Britain, there was a tendency for married women to join the labor force, competing for part-time jobs especially.<ref>Jessica S. Bean, {{"'}}To help keep the home going': female labour supply in interwar London". ''Economic History Review'' (2015) 68#2 pp. 441–470.</ref><ref>Deirdre Beddoe, ''Back to Home and Duty: Women Between the Wars, 1918–1939'' (1989).</ref>

In France, very slow population growth, especially in comparison to Germany continued to be a serious issue in the 1930s. Support for increasing welfare programs during the depression included a focus on women in the family. The Conseil Supérieur de la Natalité campaigned for provisions enacted in the Code de la Famille (1939) that increased state assistance to families with children and required employers to protect the jobs of fathers, even if they were immigrants.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Camiscioli |first1=Elisa |author-link=Elisa Camiscioli |year=2001 |title=Producing Citizens, Reproducing the 'French Race': Immigration, Demography, and Pronatalism in Early Twentieth-Century France |journal=Gender & History |volume=13 |issue=3 |pages=593–621 |doi=10.1111/1468-0424.00245 |pmid=18198513 |s2cid=20333294}}</ref>

In rural and small-town areas, women expanded their operation of vegetable gardens to include as much food production as possible. In the United States, agricultural organizations sponsored programs to teach housewives how to optimize their gardens and to raise poultry for meat and eggs.<ref>Ann E. McCleary, {{"'}}I Was Really Proud of Them': Canned Raspberries and Home Production During the Farm Depression". ''Augusta Historical Bulletin'' (2010), Issue 46, pp. 14–44.</ref> Rural women made ]es and other items for themselves and their families and homes from feed sacks.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Vogelsang |first=Willem |title=3. Feedsacks and the Great Depression |url=https://trc-leiden.nl/trc-digital-exhibition/index.php/for-a-few-sacks-more/item/119-3-feedsacks-and-the-great-depression |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210415092351/https://trc-leiden.nl/trc-digital-exhibition/index.php/for-a-few-sacks-more/item/119-3-feedsacks-and-the-great-depression |archive-date=15 April 2021 |access-date=21 March 2020 |website=trc-leiden.nl |language=en-gb}}</ref> In American cities, African American women quiltmakers enlarged their activities, promoted collaboration, and trained neophytes. Quilts were created for practical use from various inexpensive materials and increased social interaction for women and promoted camaraderie and personal fulfillment.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Klassen |first1=Tari |year=2008 |title=How Depression-Era Quiltmakers Constructed Domestic Space: An Interracial Processual Study |journal=Midwestern Folklore |volume=34 |issue=2 |pages=17–47}}</ref>

Oral history provides evidence for how housewives in a modern industrial city handled shortages of money and resources. Often they updated strategies their mothers used when they were growing up in poor families. Cheap foods were used, such as soups, beans and noodles. They purchased the cheapest cuts of meat—sometimes even horse meat—and recycled the ] into sandwiches and soups. They sewed and patched clothing, traded with their neighbors for outgrown items, and made do with colder homes. New furniture and appliances were postponed until better days. Many women also worked outside the home, or took boarders, did laundry for trade or cash, and did sewing for neighbors in exchange for something they could offer. Extended families used mutual aid—extra food, spare rooms, repair-work, cash loans—to help cousins and in-laws.<ref>Baillargeon, ''Making Do: Women, Family and Home in Montreal during the Great Depression'' (1999), pp. 70, 108, 136–138, 159.</ref>

In Japan, official government policy was deflationary and the opposite of Keynesian spending. Consequently, the government launched a campaign across the country to induce households to reduce their consumption, focusing attention on spending by housewives.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Metzler |first1=Mark |year=2004 |title=Woman's Place in Japan's Great Depression: Reflections on the Moral Economy of Deflation |journal=Journal of Japanese Studies |volume=30 |issue=2 |pages=315–352 |doi=10.1353/jjs.2004.0045 |s2cid=146273711}}</ref>

In Germany, the government tried to reshape private household consumption under the Four-Year Plan of 1936 to achieve German economic self-sufficiency. The Nazi women's organizations, other propaganda agencies and the authorities all attempted to shape such consumption as economic self-sufficiency was needed to prepare for and to sustain the coming war. The organizations, propaganda agencies and authorities employed slogans that called up traditional values of thrift and healthy living. However, these efforts were only partly successful in changing the behavior of housewives.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Reagin |first1=N. R. |year=2001 |title=Marktordnung and Autarkic Housekeeping: Housewives and Private Consumption under the Four-Year Plan, 1936–1939 |journal=German History |volume=19 |issue=2 |pages=162–184 |doi=10.1191/026635501678771619 |pmid=19610237}}</ref>

==== World War II and recovery ====
]. Women entered the workforce as men were drafted into the armed forces.]]
The common view among economic historians is that the Great Depression ended with the advent of ]. Many economists believe that government spending on the war caused or at least accelerated recovery from the Great Depression, though some consider that it did not play a very large role in the recovery, though it did help in reducing unemployment.<ref name="Britannica" /><ref name="Galbraith">Referring to the effect of World War II spending on the economy, economist ] said, "One could not have had a better demonstration of the Keynesian ideas." {{cite video |url=https://www.pbs.org/wgbh/commandingheights/lo/story/ch_menu.html |title=Commanding Heights, see chapter 6 video or transcript |date=2002 |medium=TV documentary |publisher=] |location=U.S. |people=], William Cran (writers / producer)}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal |last=Romer |first=Christina D. |author-link=Christina Romer |year=1992 |title=What Ended the Great Depression? |journal=Journal of Economic History |volume=52 |issue=4 |pages=757–784 |doi=10.1017/S002205070001189X |quote=fiscal policy was of little consequence even as late as 1942, suggests an interesting twist on the usual view that World War II caused, or at least accelerated, the recovery from the Great Depression.}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal |last=Higgs |first=Robert |date=1 March 1992 |title=Wartime Prosperity? A Reassessment of the U.S. Economy in the 1940s |journal=The Journal of Economic History |volume=52 |issue=1 |pages=41–60 |doi=10.1017/S0022050700010251 |issn=1471-6372 |s2cid=154484756}}</ref>

The rearmament policies leading up to World War II helped stimulate the economies of Europe in 1937–1939. By 1937, unemployment in Britain had fallen to 1.5&nbsp;million. The ] of manpower following the outbreak of war in 1939 ended unemployment.<ref name="Great Depression and World War II"> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220124140816/https://www.americaslibrary.gov/jb/wwii/jb_wwii_subj.html|date=24 January 2022}}. Library of Congress.</ref>

The American mobilization for ] at the end of 1941 moved approximately ten million people out of the civilian labor force and into the war.<ref>Selective Service System. (27 May 2003). '' {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090507211238/http://www.sss.gov/induct.htm |date=7 May 2009 }}''. Retrieved 8 September 2013.</ref>
This finally eliminated the last effects from the Great Depression and brought the U.S. unemployment rate down below 10%.<ref name="Depression & World War II"> {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090625204217/https://www.americaslibrary.gov/cgi-bin/page.cgi/jb/wwii|date=25 June 2009}}. Americaslibrary.gov.</ref>

World War II had a dramatic effect on many parts of the American economy.<ref name="Bloomberg">{{cite news|url=http://www.bloombergview.com/articles/2011-12-16/how-did-world-war-ii-end-the-great-depression-echoes|publisher=Bloomberg|title=How Did World War II End the Great Depression?: Echoes|author=Hyman, Louis|author-link=Louis Hyman|date=16 December 2011|access-date=25 August 2015|archive-date=3 May 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160503051054/http://www.bloombergview.com/articles/2011-12-16/how-did-world-war-ii-end-the-great-depression-echoes|url-status=dead}}</ref> Government-financed capital spending accounted for only 5% of the annual U.S. investment in industrial capital in 1940; by 1943, the government accounted for 67% of U.S. capital investment.<ref name="Bloomberg"/> The massive war spending doubled economic growth rates, either masking the effects of the Depression or essentially ending the Depression. Businessmen ignored the mounting ] and heavy new taxes, redoubling their efforts for greater output to take advantage of generous government contracts.<ref>Richard J. Jensen, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211102124644/https://rjensen.people.uic.edu/causes-cures.pdf|date=2 November 2021}}. ''Journal of Interdisciplinary History'' 19.4 (1989): 553–583.</ref>

==Causes==
{{Main|Causes of the Great Depression}} {{Main|Causes of the Great Depression}}
]
{{Mergeto | Causes of the Great Depression| Talk:Great_Depression#Merge_Cause_section_and_provide_brief_summary.3F |date=December 2008 }}


===Attempts to return to the Gold Standard===
There were multiple causes for the first downturn in 1929, including the structural weaknesses and specific events that turned it into a major depression and the way in which the downturn spread from country to country. In relation to the 1929 downturn, historians emphasize structural factors like massive bank failures and the stock market crash, while economists (such as ] and ]) point to Britain's decision to return to the Gold Standard at pre-World War I parities (US$4.86:£1).
{{See also|Financial crisis of 1914}}
During ] many countries suspended their ] in varying ways. There was high inflation from WWI, and in the 1920s in the ], ], and throughout Europe. In the late 1920s there was a scramble to deflate prices to get the gold standard's conversation rates back on track to pre-WWI levels, by causing ] and high unemployment through monetary policy. In 1933 ] signed ] and in 1934 signed the ].<ref>{{Cite web |last=McCulloch |first=Hu |date=August 23, 2018 |title=World War I, Gold, and the Great Depression |url=https://www.cato.org/blog/world-war-i-gold-great-depression |access-date=2024-11-12 |website=]}}</ref>
{| class="wikitable"
|+ Gold Standard Policies by Country<ref>https://www.nber.org/system/files/chapters/c11482/c11482.pdf</ref>
! Country !! Return to Gold !! Suspension of Gold Standard !! Foreign Exchange Control !! Devaluation
|-
| Australia || April 1925 || December 1929 || — || March 1930
|-
| Austria || April 1925 || April 1933 || October 1931 || September 1931
|-
| Belgium || October 1926 || — || — || March 1935
|-
| Canada || July 1926 || October 1931 || — || September 1931
|-
| Czechoslovakia || April 1926 || — || September 1931 || February 1934
|-
| Denmark || January 1927 || September 1931 || November 1931 || September 1931
|-
| Estonia || January 1928 || June 1933 || November 1931 || June 1933
|-
| Finland || January 1926 || October 1931 || — || October 1931
|-
| France || August 1926-June 1928 || — || — || October 1936
|-
| Germany || September 1924 || — || July 1931 || —
|-
| Greece || May 1928 || April 1932 || September 1931 || April 1932
|-
| Hungary || April 1925 || — || July 1931 || —
|-
| Italy || December 1927 || — || May 1934 || October 1936
|-
| Japan || December 1930 || December 1931 || July 1932 || December 1931
|-
| Latvia || August 1922 || — || October 1931 || —
|-
| Netherlands || April 1925 || — || — || October 1936
|-
| Norway || May 1928 || September 1931 || — || September 1931
|-
| New Zealand || April 1925 || September 1931 || — || April 1930
|-
| Poland || October 1927 || — || April 1936 || October 1936
|-
| Romania || March 1927-February 1929 || — || May 1932 || —
|-
| Sweden || April 1924 || September 1931 || — || September 1931
|-
| Spain || — || — || May 1931 || —
|-
| United Kingdom || May 1925 || September 1931 || — || September 1931
|-
| United States || June 1919 || March 1933 || March 1933 || April 1933
|}

===Keynesian vs Monetarist view===
] and the ], when there were massive ] across the United States.]]
[[File:CPI 1914-2022.webp|thumb|upright=1.6|alt=CPI 1914–2022|
{{legend|#0076BA |]}}
{{legend|#EE220C |]}}
{{legend-line|#1DB100 solid 3px|] increases Year/Year}}
]]
The two classic competing economic theories of the Great Depression are the ] (demand-driven) and the ] explanation.<ref>{{Cite web|first1=Nick|last1=Lioudis|title=What is the difference between Keynesian and monetarist economics?|url=https://www.investopedia.com/ask/answers/012615/what-difference-between-keynesian-economics-and-monetarist-economics.asp|access-date=12 July 2021|website=Investopedia|language=en|archive-date=20 December 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211220193534/https://www.investopedia.com/ask/answers/012615/what-difference-between-keynesian-economics-and-monetarist-economics.asp|url-status=live}}</ref> There are also various ] that downplay or reject the explanations of the Keynesians and monetarists. The consensus among demand-driven theories is that a large-scale loss of confidence led to a sudden reduction in consumption and investment spending. Once panic and deflation set in, many people believed they could avoid further losses by keeping clear of the markets. Holding money became profitable as prices dropped lower and a given amount of money bought ever more goods, exacerbating the drop in demand.<ref>{{Cite web|title=Great Depression – Causes of the decline|url=https://www.britannica.com/event/Great-Depression|access-date=12 July 2021|website=Encyclopedia Britannica|language=en|archive-date=9 May 2015|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150509121741/https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/243118/Great-Depression|url-status=live}}</ref> Monetarists believe that the Great Depression started as an ordinary recession, but the shrinking of the ] greatly exacerbated the economic situation, causing a recession to descend into the Great Depression.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Hayes|first=Adam|title=What is a Monetarist?|url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/m/monetarist.asp|access-date=12 July 2021|website=Investopedia|language=en|archive-date=5 November 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211105044704/https://www.investopedia.com/terms/m/monetarist.asp|url-status=live}}</ref>

Economists and economic historians are almost evenly split as to whether the traditional monetary explanation that monetary forces were the primary cause of the Great Depression is right, or the traditional Keynesian explanation that a fall in autonomous spending, particularly investment, is the primary explanation for the onset of the Great Depression.<ref name="in JSTOR">{{cite journal|at=p. 150|jstor=2123771|url=https://www.employees.csbsju.edu/jolson/ECON315/Whaples2123771.pdf|title=Where is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions|journal=The Journal of Economic History|volume=55|issue=1|last1=Whaples|first1=Robert|year=1995|doi=10.1017/S0022050700040602|citeseerx=10.1.1.482.4975|s2cid=145691938 |access-date=18 February 2022|archive-date=4 November 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211104183848/http://www.employees.csbsju.edu/jolson/econ315/whaples2123771.pdf|url-status=live}}</ref> Today there is also significant academic support for the ] theory and the ] that – building on the monetary explanation of ] and ] – add non-monetary explanations.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Mendoza|first1=Enrique G.|last2=Smith|first2=Katherine A.|date=1 September 2006|title=Quantitative implications of a debt-deflation theory of Sudden Stops and asset prices|url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S002219960500098X|journal=Journal of International Economics|language=en|volume=70|issue=1|pages=82–114|doi=10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.06.016|issn=0022-1996|access-date=18 February 2022|archive-date=18 February 2022|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220218125338/https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S002219960500098X|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Buraschi|first1=Andrea|last2=Jiltsov|first2=Alexei|date=1 February 2005|title=Inflation risk premia and the expectations hypothesis|url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304405X04001333|journal=Journal of Financial Economics|language=en|volume=75|issue=2|pages=429–490|doi=10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.07.003|issn=0304-405X|access-date=18 February 2022|archive-date=18 February 2022|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220218125325/https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S0304405X04001333|url-status=live}}</ref>

There is a consensus that the ] should have cut short the process of monetary deflation and banking collapse, by expanding the money supply and acting as ]. If they had done this, the economic downturn would have been far less severe and much shorter.<ref>{{cite journal|at=p. 143|jstor=2123771|url=https://www.employees.csbsju.edu/jolson/ECON315/Whaples2123771.pdf|title=Where is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions|journal=The Journal of Economic History|volume=55|issue=1|last1=Whaples|first1=Robert|year=1995|doi=10.1017/S0022050700040602|citeseerx=10.1.1.482.4975|s2cid=145691938 |access-date=18 February 2022|archive-date=4 November 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211104183848/http://www.employees.csbsju.edu/jolson/econ315/whaples2123771.pdf|url-status=live}}</ref>

===Mainstream explanations===
]
Modern mainstream economists see the reasons in
* A money supply reduction (]) and therefore a banking crisis, reduction of credit, and bankruptcies.
* Insufficient demand from the ] and insufficient fiscal spending (]).
* Passage of the ] exacerbated what otherwise might have been a more "standard" ] (both ] and ]).<ref name="ReferenceB" />

Insufficient spending, the money supply reduction, and debt on margin led to falling prices and further bankruptcies (]'s debt deflation).

====Monetarist view====
] in 1996-Dollar (blue), ] (red), ] M2 (green) and number of banks (grey). All data adjusted to 1929 = 100%.]]
] early in the Great Depression]]

The monetarist explanation was given by American economists ] and ].<ref>''A Monetary History of the United States, 1857–1960''. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1963.</ref> They argued that the Great Depression was caused by the banking crisis that caused one-third of all banks to vanish, a reduction of bank shareholder wealth and more importantly ] of 35%, which they called "The ]". This caused a price drop of 33% (]).<ref>Randall E. Parker (2003), {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210818225154/https://books.google.com/books?id=Y-g4AgAAQBAJ&lpg=PR1&pg=PA11#v=snippet&q=%22Pin%20the%20blame%20squarely%20on%20the%20Federal%20Reserve%22 |date=18 August 2021 }}, Edward Elgar Publishing, {{ISBN|978-1-84376-550-9}}, pp. 11–12</ref> By not lowering interest rates, by not increasing the monetary base and by not injecting liquidity into the banking system to prevent it from crumbling, the Federal Reserve passively watched the transformation of a normal recession into the Great Depression. Friedman and Schwartz argued that the downward turn in the economy, starting with the stock market crash, would merely have been an ordinary recession if the Federal Reserve had taken aggressive action.<ref>{{cite book|last1=Friedman|first1=Milton|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=-lCArZfazBkC&q=%22Regarding%20the%20Great%20Depression%20You're%20right%20We%20did%20it%22|title=The Great Contraction, 1929–1933|author2=Anna Jacobson Schwartz|publisher=Princeton University Press|year=2008|isbn=978-0691137940|edition=New|access-date=18 February 2022|archive-date=16 January 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200116121531/https://books.google.com/books?id=-lCArZfazBkC&q=%22Regarding%20the%20Great%20Depression%20You%27re%20right%20We%20did%20it%22|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|last=Bernanke|first=Ben|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=c2OSWhLjzJkC&q=Schwartz&pg=PA6|title=Essays on the Great Depression|publisher=Princeton University Press|year=2000|isbn=0-691-01698-4|page=7|access-date=24 May 2021|archive-date=24 December 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211224221348/https://books.google.com/books?id=c2OSWhLjzJkC&q=Schwartz&pg=PA6|url-status=live}}</ref> This view was endorsed in 2002 by ] ] in a speech honoring Friedman and Schwartz with this statement:

{{blockquote|Let me end my talk by abusing slightly my status as an official representative of the Federal Reserve. I would like to say to Milton and Anna: Regarding the Great Depression, you're right. We did it. We're very sorry. But thanks to you, we won't do it again.|Ben S. Bernanke<ref>Ben S. Bernanke (8 November 2002), {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200324160935/https://www.federalreserve.gov/BOARDDOCS/SPEECHES/2002/20021108/default.htm |date=March 24, 2020 }} Conference to Honor Milton Friedman, University of Chicago</ref><ref name=FriedmanSchwartz>{{cite book|last1=Friedman|first1=Milton|last2=Schwartz|first2=Anna|title=The Great Contraction, 1929–1933|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=-lCArZfazBkC&q=%22Regarding%20the%20Great%20Depression%20You're%20right%20We%20did%20it%22|year=2008|publisher=Princeton University Press|page=247|isbn=978-0691137940|edition=New|access-date=18 February 2022|archive-date=16 January 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200116121531/https://books.google.com/books?id=-lCArZfazBkC&q=%22Regarding%20the%20Great%20Depression%20You%27re%20right%20We%20did%20it%22|url-status=live}}</ref>}}


The Federal Reserve allowed some large public bank failures – particularly that of the ] – which produced panic and widespread runs on local banks, and the Federal Reserve sat idly by while banks collapsed. Friedman and Schwartz argued that, if the Fed had provided emergency lending to these key banks, or simply bought ]s on the ] to provide liquidity and increase the quantity of money after the key banks fell, all the rest of the banks would not have fallen after the large ones did, and the money supply would not have fallen as far and as fast as it did.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Krugman|first=Paul|date=15 February 2007|title=Who Was Milton Friedman?|url=https://www.nybooks.com/articles/19857|journal=]|volume=54 |issue=2 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080410200144/https://www.nybooks.com/articles/19857|archive-date=10 April 2008|access-date=22 May 2008}}</ref>
Recession cycles are thought to be a normal part of living in a world of inexact balances between ]. What turns a usually mild and short recession or "ordinary" ] into a great depression is a subject of debate and concern. Scholars have not agreed on the exact causes and their relative importance. The search for causes is closely connected to the question of how to avoid a future depression, and so the political and policy viewpoints of scholars are mixed into the analysis of historic events eight decades ago. The even larger question is whether it was largely a failure on the part of ]s or largely a failure on the part of governments to curtail widespread bank failures, the resulting panics, and reduction in the money supply. Those who believe in a large role for the state in the economy believe it was mostly a failure of the free markets and those who believe in free markets believe it was mostly a failure of government that compounded the problem.


With significantly less money to go around, businesses could not get new loans and could not even get their old loans renewed, forcing many to stop investing. This interpretation blames the Federal Reserve for inaction, especially the ].<ref>{{cite book|author=G. Edward Griffin|url=https://archive.org/details/TheCreatureFromJekyllIslandByG.EdwardGriffin|title=The Creature from Jekyll Island: A Second Look at the Federal Reserve|year=1998|isbn=978-0-912986-39-5|edition=3d|page=|publisher=American Media }}</ref>
Current theories may be broadly classified into three main points of view. First, there is orthodox ]: ], ] and ], all of which focus on the ] effects of ] and the supply of gold which backed many currencies before the Great Depression, including ] and ].
]


One reason why the Federal Reserve did not act to limit the decline of the money supply was the ]. At that time, the amount of credit the Federal Reserve could issue was limited by the ], which required 40% gold backing of Federal Reserve Notes issued. By the late 1920s, the Federal Reserve had almost hit the limit of allowable credit that could be backed by the gold in its possession. This credit was in the form of Federal Reserve demand notes.<ref name="text">Frank Freidel (1973), ], ch. 19, Little, Brown & Co.</ref> A "promise of gold" is not as good as "gold in the hand", particularly when they only had enough gold to cover 40% of the Federal Reserve Notes outstanding. During the bank panics, a portion of those demand notes was redeemed for Federal Reserve gold. Since the Federal Reserve had hit its limit on allowable credit, any reduction in gold in its vaults had to be accompanied by a greater reduction in credit. On 5 April 1933, President Roosevelt signed ] making the private ownership of ]s, coins and bullion illegal, reducing the pressure on Federal Reserve gold.<ref name="text" />
Second, there are structural theories, most importantly ], but also including those of ], that point to ] and overinvestment (]), ] by bankers and industrialists, or incompetence by government officials. The only consensus viewpoint is that there was a large-scale lack of confidence. Unfortunately, once panic and deflation set in, many people believed they could make more money by keeping clear of the markets as prices got lower and lower and a given amount of money bought ever more goods.


====Keynesian view====
Third, there is the ] critique of political economy. This emphasizes the tendency of capitalism to create unbalanced accumulations of wealth, leading to overaccumulations of capital and a repeating cycle of devaluations through economic crises. Marx saw recession and depression as unavoidable under free-market capitalism as there are no restrictions on accumulations of capital other than the market itself.
British economist ] argued in '']'' that lower ]s in the economy contributed to a massive decline in income and to employment that was well below the average. In such a situation, the economy reached equilibrium at low levels of economic activity and high unemployment.


Keynes's basic idea was simple: to keep people fully employed, governments have to run deficits when the economy is slowing, as the private sector would not invest enough to keep production at the normal level and bring the economy out of recession. Keynesian economists called on governments during times of ] to pick up the slack by increasing ] or cutting taxes.
===Debt deflation===
] early in the Great Depression.]]


As the Depression wore on, ] tried ], ], and other devices to restart the U.S. economy, but never completely gave up trying to balance the budget. According to the Keynesians, this improved the economy, but Roosevelt never spent enough to bring the economy out of recession until the start of ].<ref>{{Cite journal| author-link=Lawrence Klein|first=Lawrence R.|last=Klein|title=The Keynesian Revolution|year=1947| pages=56–58, 169, 177–179|location=New York|publisher=Macmillan}}; {{Cite book|first=Theodore|last=Rosenof|title=Economics in the Long Run: New Deal Theorists and Their Legacies, 1933–1993|year=1997|location=Chapel Hill|publisher=University of North Carolina Press|isbn=0-8078-2315-5}}</ref>
] argued that the predominant factor leading to the Great Depression was overindebtedness and deflation. Fisher tied loose credit to over-indebtedness, which fueled speculation and asset bubbles.<ref name="Fisher33">{{cite journal|last=Fisher|first=Irving|date=October 1933|title=The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions|journal=Econometrica|volume=1|pages=337-357}}</ref> He then outlined 9 factors interacting with one another under conditions of debt and deflation to create the mechanics of boom to bust. The chain of events proceeded as follows:


=====Debt deflation=====
]
] argued that the predominant factor leading to the Great Depression was a vicious circle of deflation and growing over-indebtedness.<ref name="Fisher33">{{cite journal|last=Fisher|first=Irving|s2cid=35564016|date= October 1933|title=The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions|journal=Econometrica|volume=1| pages=337–57|doi=10.2307/1907327|issue=4|publisher=The Econometric Society|jstor=1907327}}</ref> He outlined nine factors interacting with one another under conditions of debt and deflation to create the mechanics of boom to bust. The chain of events proceeded as follows:
# Debt liquidation and distress selling # Debt liquidation and distress selling
# Contraction of the money supply as bank loans are paid off # Contraction of the money supply as bank loans are paid off
# A fall in the level of asset prices # A fall in the level of asset prices
# A still greater fall in the net worths of business, precipitating bankruptcies # A still greater fall in the net worth of businesses, precipitating bankruptcies
# A fall in profits # A fall in profits
# A reduction in output, in trade and in employment. # A reduction in output, in trade and in employment
# Pessimism and loss of confidence # ] and loss of confidence
# Hoarding of money # Hoarding of money
# A fall in nominal interest rates and a rise in deflation adjusted interest rates.''<ref name="Fisher33" /> # A fall in nominal interest rates and a rise in deflation adjusted interest rates<ref name="Fisher33"/>


During the Crash of 1929 preceeding the Great Depression, margin requirements were only 10%. Brokerage firms, in other words, would lend $9 for every $1 an investor had deposited. When the market fell, brokers called in these loans, which could not be paid back. Banks began to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors attempted to withdraw their deposits en masse, triggering multiple ]s. Government guarantees and Federal Reserve banking regulations to prevent such panics were ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to the loss of billions of dollars in assets.<ref name = "lhf-30s">{{cite web|accessdate=2008-05-22|url=http://www.livinghistoryfarm.org/farminginthe30s/money_08.html|title=Bank Failures |publisher=Living History Farm}}</ref> Outstanding debts became heavier, because prices and incomes fell by 20–50% but the debts remained at the same dollar amount. After the panic of 1929, and during the first 10 months of 1930, 744 US banks failed. (In all, 9,000 banks failed during the 1930s). By April 1933, around $7 billion in deposits had been frozen in failed banks or those left unlicensed after the March Bank Holiday.<ref> "Friedman and Schwartz, Monetary History of the United States", 352 </ref> During the Crash of 1929 preceding the Great Depression, margin requirements were only 10%.<ref name="Margin Requirements">{{cite journal|last=Fortune|first=Peter|date=September–October 2000|title=Margin Requirements, Margin Loans, and Margin Rates: Practice and Principles – analysis of history of margin credit regulations – Statistical Data Included|journal=New England Economic Review|url=https://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m3937/is_2000_Sept-Oct/ai_80855422/pg_5|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150811102239/http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m3937/is_2000_Sept-Oct/ai_80855422/pg_5|url-status=dead|archive-date=11 August 2015|access-date=18 February 2022}}</ref> Brokerage firms, in other words, would lend $9 for every $1 an investor had deposited. When the market fell, brokers ], which could not be paid back.<ref name="lhf-30s">{{cite web|access-date=22 May 2008|url=https://www.livinghistoryfarm.org/farminginthe30s/money_08.html|title=Bank Failures|publisher=Living History Farm|archive-url=http://webarchive.loc.gov/all/20090219185825/https://livinghistoryfarm.org/farminginthe30s/money_08.html|archive-date=19 February 2009|url-status=dead}}</ref> Banks began to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors attempted to withdraw their deposits {{Lang|fr|en masse}}, triggering multiple ]s. Government guarantees and Federal Reserve banking regulations to prevent such panics were ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to the loss of billions of dollars in assets.<ref name="lhf-30s"/>


Bank failures snowballed as desperate bankers called in loans which the borrowers did not have time or money to repay. With future profits looking poor, ] and construction slowed or completely ceased. In the face of bad loans and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks became even more conservative in their lending.<ref name = "lhf-30s"/> Banks built up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A ] developed and the downward spiral accelerated. Outstanding debts became heavier, because prices and incomes fell by 20–50% but the debts remained at the same dollar amount. After the panic of 1929 and during the first 10 months of 1930, 744 U.S. banks failed. (In all, 9,000 banks failed during the 1930s.) By April 1933, around $7&nbsp;billion in deposits had been frozen in failed banks or those left unlicensed after the ].<ref>"Friedman and Schwartz, Monetary History of the United States", 352</ref> Bank failures snowballed as desperate bankers called in loans that borrowers did not have time or money to repay. With future profits looking poor, ] and construction slowed or completely ceased. In the face of bad loans and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks became even more conservative in their lending.<ref name="lhf-30s"/> Banks built up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A ] developed and the downward spiral accelerated.


The liquidation of debt could not keep up with the fall of prices which it caused. The mass effect of the stampede to liquidate increased the value of each dollar owed, relative to the value of declining asset holdings. The very effort of individuals to lessen their burden of debt effectively increased it. Paradoxically, the more the debtors paid, the more they owed.<ref name="Fisher33" /> This self-aggravating process turned a 1930 recession into a 1933 great depression. The liquidation of debt could not keep up with the fall of prices that it caused. The mass effect of the stampede to liquidate increased the value of each dollar owed, relative to the value of declining asset holdings. The very effort of individuals to lessen their burden of debt effectively increased it. Paradoxically, the more the debtors paid, the more they owed.<ref name="Fisher33"/> This self-aggravating process turned a 1930 recession into a 1933 great depression.


Fisher's debt-deflation theory initially lacked mainstream influence because of the counter-argument that debt-deflation represented no more than a redistribution from one group (debtors) to another (creditors). Pure re-distributions should have no significant macroeconomic effects.
]s including ], the current chairman of the ], have revived the debt-deflation view of the Great Depression originated by Fisher.<ref name="Bernanke83">{{cite journal|last=Bernanke|first=Ben S|date=June 1983|title= Non-Monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression|journal=THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW|publisher=The American Economic Association|volume=73|issue=3|pages=257-276|url=http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198306%2973%3A3%3C257%3ANEOTFC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-0&origin=repec}}</ref><ref name="Mishkin78">{{cite journal|last=Mishkin|first=Fredric|date=December 1978|title=The Household Balance and the Great Depression|journal=Journal of Economic History|volume=38|pages=918-37}}</ref>


Building on both the monetary hypothesis of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz and the debt deflation hypothesis of Irving Fisher, ] developed an alternative way in which the financial crisis affected output. He builds on Fisher's argument that dramatic declines in the price level and nominal incomes lead to increasing real debt burdens, which in turn leads to debtor insolvency and consequently lowers ]; a further price level decline would then result in a debt deflationary spiral. According to Bernanke, a small decline in the price level simply reallocates wealth from debtors to creditors without doing damage to the economy. But when the deflation is severe, falling asset prices along with debtor bankruptcies lead to a decline in the nominal value of assets on bank balance sheets. Banks will react by tightening their credit conditions, which in turn leads to a ] that seriously harms the economy. A credit crunch lowers investment and consumption, which results in declining aggregate demand and additionally contributes to the deflationary spiral.<ref>Randall E. Parker, ''Reflections on the Great Depression'', Edward Elgar Publishing, 2003, {{ISBN|978-1-84376-550-9}}, pp. 14–15</ref><ref name="Bernanke83">{{cite journal |last=Bernanke |first=Ben S. |date=June 1983 |title=Non-Monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression |url=https://faculty.arts.ubc.ca/dpaterson/econ532/10twenties/bernanke.pdf |url-status=dead |journal=The American Economic Review |publisher=The American Economic Association |volume=73 |issue=3 |pages=257–276 |jstor=1808111 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171118070151/https://faculty.arts.ubc.ca/dpaterson/econ532/10twenties/bernanke.pdf |archive-date=18 November 2017 |access-date=22 February 2021}}</ref><ref name="Mishkin78">{{cite journal|doi=10.1017/S0022050700087167|last=Mishkin|first= Fredric|date=December 1978|title=The Household Balance and the Great Depression|journal=Journal of Economic History|volume=38|issue=4|pages=918–937|s2cid=155049545 }}</ref>
===Trade decline and the U.S. Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act===
{{main|Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act}}
Many economists have argued that the sharp decline in international trade after 1930 helped to worsen the depression, especially for countries significantly dependent on foreign trade. Most historians and economists partly blame the American ] (enacted June 17, 1930) for worsening the depression by seriously reducing international trade and causing retaliatory tariffs in other countries. Foreign trade was a small part of overall economic activity in the United States and was concentrated in a few businesses like farming; it was a much larger factor in many other countries.<ref>{{cite web|accessdate=2008-05-22|url=http://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/intrel/depress.htm|title=The World in Depression|publisher=]}}</ref> The average '']'' rate of duties on dutiable imports for 1921–1925 was 25.9% but under the new tariff it jumped to 50% in 1931–1935.


=====Expectations hypothesis=====
In dollar terms, American exports declined from about $5.2 billion in 1929 to $1.7 billion in 1933; but prices also fell, so the physical volume of exports only fell by half. Hardest hit were farm commodities such as wheat, cotton, tobacco, and lumber. According to this theory, the collapse of farm exports caused many American farmers to default on their loans, leading to the ]s on small rural banks that characterized the early years of the Great Depression.


Since economic mainstream turned to the ], expectations are a central element of macroeconomic models. According to ], Barry Wigmore, Gauti B. Eggertsson and ], the key to recovery and to ending the Great Depression was brought about by a successful management of public expectations. The thesis is based on the observation that after years of deflation and a very severe recession important economic indicators turned positive in March 1933 when ] took office. Consumer prices turned from deflation to a mild inflation, industrial production bottomed out in March 1933, and investment doubled in 1933 with a turnaround in March 1933. There were no monetary forces to explain that turnaround. Money supply was still falling and short-term interest rates remained close to zero. Before March 1933, people expected further deflation and a recession so that even interest rates at zero did not stimulate investment. But when Roosevelt announced major regime changes, people began to expect inflation and an economic expansion. With these positive expectations, interest rates at zero began to stimulate investment just as they were expected to do. Roosevelt's fiscal and monetary policy regime change helped make his policy objectives credible. The expectation of higher future income and higher future inflation stimulated demand and investment. The analysis suggests that the elimination of the policy dogmas of the gold standard, a balanced budget in times of crisis and small government led endogenously to a large shift in expectation that accounts for about 70–80% of the recovery of output and prices from 1933 to 1937. If the regime change had not happened and the Hoover policy had continued, the economy would have continued its free fall in 1933, and output would have been 30% lower in 1937 than in 1933.<ref>Gauti B. Eggertsson, , {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160125070317/https://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257%2Faer.98.4.1476|date=25 January 2016}}, American Economic Review 2008, 98: 4, pp. 1476–1516.</ref><ref>Christina Romer, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211129132620/https://www.nytimes.com/2012/10/21/business/how-the-fiscal-stimulus-helped-and-could-have-done-more.html |date=29 November 2021 }}, ''The New York Times'', 20 October 2012.</ref><ref>Peter Temin, ''Lessons from the Great Depression'', MIT Press, 1992, {{ISBN|978-0-262-26119-7}}, pp. 87–101.</ref>
===U.S. Federal Reserve and money supply===
]s, including ] and current ] chairman ], argue that the Great Depression was caused by ], the consequence of poor policymaking by the American ] and continuous crisis in the banking system.<ref>{{cite book|author= ]|year=2000|title=Essays on the Great Depression|publisher=]|page=7|isbn=0691016984}}</ref><ref>
{{cite web
|url=http://www.worldnetdaily.com/index.php?fa=PAGE.view&pageId=59405
|title=Bernanke: Federal Reserve caused Great Depression
|publisher=]
|accessdate=2008-03-21
}}
</ref> In this view, the Federal Reserve, by not acting, allowed the money supply as measured by the ] to shrink by one-third from 1929 to 1933. Friedman argued<ref>{{cite book|title=A Monetary History of the United States}}</ref> that the downward turn in the economy, starting with the stock market crash, would have been just another recession. The problem was that some large, public bank failures, particularly that of the ], produced panic and widespread runs on local banks, and that the Federal Reserve sat idly by while banks fell. He claimed that, if the Fed had provided emergency lending to these key banks, or simply bought ]s on the ] to provide liquidity and increase the quantity of money after the key banks fell, all the rest of the banks would not have fallen after the large ones did, and the money supply would not have fallen as far and as fast as it did.<ref>{{cite web|accessdate=2008-05-22|url=http://www.nybooks.com/articles/19857|title=Who Was Milton Friedman?|work=]|date=2007-02-15|author=Krugman, Paul}}</ref> With significantly less money to go around, businessmen could not get new loans and could not even get their old loans renewed, forcing many to stop investing. This interpretation blames the Federal Reserve for inaction, especially the New York branch.<ref>{{cite book
| first = G. Edward
| title = The Creature from Jekyll Island: A Second Look at the Federal Reserve
| last = Griffin
| publisher = ]
| year = 2002
| isbn = 0912986395
| isbn-13 = 978-0912986395 }}</ref>


The ], which slowed down economic recovery from the Great Depression, is explained by fears of the population that the moderate tightening of the monetary and fiscal policy in 1937 were first steps to a restoration of the pre-1933 policy regime.<ref>{{cite journal|jstor=29730131|at=p. 1480|title=Great Expectations and the End of the Depression|journal=The American Economic Review|volume=98|issue=4|last1=Eggertsson|first1=Gauti B.|year=2008|doi=10.1257/aer.98.4.1476|hdl=10419/60661|hdl-access=free}}</ref>
One reason why the Federal Reserve did not act to limit the decline of the money supply was regulation. At that time the amount of credit the Federal Reserve could issue was limited by laws which required partial gold backing of that credit. By the late 1920s the Federal Reserve had almost hit the limit of allowable credit that could be backed by the gold in its possession. This credit was in the form of Federal Reserve demand notes. Since a "promise of gold" is not as good as "gold in the hand", during the bank panics a portion of those demand notes were redeemed for Federal Reserve gold. Since the Federal Reserve had hit its limit on allowable credit, any reduction in gold in its vaults had to be accompanied by a greater reduction in credit. On April 5 1933 President Roosevelt signed ] making the private ownership of gold illegal,<ref>http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=14611&st=&st1=</ref> reducing the pressure on Federal Reserve gold.{{fact|date=December 2008}}


===Austrian School explanations=== ====Common position====
There is common consensus among economists today that the government and the central bank should work to keep the interconnected macroeconomic aggregates of ] and ] on a stable growth path. When threatened by expectations of a depression, ]s should expand liquidity in the banking system and the government should cut taxes and accelerate spending in order to prevent a collapse in money supply and ].<ref name="nber.org">{{cite journal |first=J. Bradford |last=De Long |title='Liquidation' Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression |journal=NBER Working Paper No. 3546 |date=December 1990 |page=1 |location=Cambridge, MA |doi=10.3386/w3546 |doi-access=free }}</ref>
Another explanation comes from the ] of economics. Theorists of the "Austrian School" who wrote about the Depression include Austrian economist ] and American economist ], who wrote '']'' (1963). In their view, the key cause of the Depression was the expansion of the money supply in the 1920s that led to an unsustainable credit-driven boom. In their view, the Federal Reserve, which was created in 1913, shoulders much of the blame.


At the beginning of the Great Depression, most economists believed in ] and the equilibrating powers of the market, and failed to understand the severity of the Depression. Outright leave-it-alone ] was a common position, and was universally held by ] economists.<ref name="Randall E. Parker 2003, p. 9"/> The liquidationist position held that a depression worked to liquidate failed businesses and investments that had been made obsolete by technological development – releasing ] (capital and labor) to be redeployed in other more productive sectors of the dynamic economy. They argued that even if self-adjustment of the economy caused mass bankruptcies, it was still the best course.<ref name="Randall E. Parker 2003, p. 9" />
In opinion, Hayek, writing for the Austrian Institute of Economic Research Report in February 1929<ref>{{cite journal|title=Austrian Institute of Economic Research Report|month=February | year=1929}}</ref> predicted the economic downturn, stating that "the boom will collapse within the next few months."


Economists like ] and ] note that President ] tried to keep the federal budget balanced until 1932, when he lost confidence in his Secretary of the Treasury ] and replaced him.<ref name="Randall E. Parker 2003, p. 9">Randall E. Parker, ''Reflections on the Great Depression'', Elgar Publishing, 2003, {{ISBN|978-1-84376-335-2}}, p. 9</ref><ref name="WhiteLawrence">{{cite journal|first=Lawrence|last=White|title=Did Hayek and Robbins Deepen the Great Depression?|journal=Journal of Money, Credit and Banking|volume=40|issue=4|pages=751–768|year=2008|doi=10.1111/j.1538-4616.2008.00134.x|url=https://dergipark.org.tr/tr/pub/liberal/issue/48188/609854|access-date=7 November 2019|archive-date=15 April 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210415095946/https://dergipark.org.tr/tr/pub/liberal/issue/48188/609854|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |first=J. Bradford |last=De Long |title='Liquidation' Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression |journal=NBER Working Paper No. 3546 |date=December 1990 |page=5 |location=Cambridge, MA |doi=10.3386/w3546 |doi-access=free }}</ref> An increasingly common view among economic historians is that the adherence of many Federal Reserve policymakers to the liquidationist position led to disastrous consequences.<ref name="WhiteLawrence" /> Unlike what liquidationists expected, a large proportion of the capital stock was not redeployed but vanished during the first years of the Great Depression. According to a study by ] and ], the recession caused a drop of net ] to pre-1924 levels by 1933.<ref>{{cite journal |first=J. Bradford |last=De Long |title='Liquidation' Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression |journal=NBER Working Paper No. 3546 |date=December 1990 |page=33 |location=Cambridge, MA |doi=10.3386/w3546 |doi-access=free }}</ref> Milton Friedman called leave-it-alone liquidationism "dangerous nonsense".<ref name="nber.org" /> He wrote:
Ludwig von Mises also expected this financial catastrophe, and is quoted as stating "A great crash is coming, and I don't want my name in any way connected with it,"<ref>{{cite book|author= Mises, Margit von|title=My Years with Ludwig von Mises|publisher=Arlington House|year=1976|page=31}}</ref> when he turned down an important job at the Kreditanstalt Bank in early 1929.
{{blockquote|I think the Austrian business-cycle theory has done the world a great deal of harm. If you go back to the 1930s, which is a key point, here you had the Austrians sitting in London, Hayek and Lionel Robbins, and saying you just have to let the bottom drop out of the world. You've just got to let it cure itself. You can't do anything about it. You will only make it worse. ... I think by encouraging that kind of do-nothing policy both in Britain and in the United States, they did harm.<ref name="WhiteLawrence" />}}


===Heterodox theories===
One reason for the monetary inflation was to help Great Britain, which, in the 1920s, was struggling with its plans to return to the gold standard at pre-war (]) parity. Returning to the gold standard at this rate meant that the British economy was facing deflationary pressure.<ref name="rothbard 2002 141">{{harvnb|Rothbard|2002|p=141}}</ref> According to Rothbard, the lack of price flexibility in Britain meant that unemployment shot up, and the American government was asked to help. The United States was receiving a net inflow of gold, and inflated further in order to help Britain return to the gold standard. ], head of the Bank of England, had an especially good relationship with ], the ''de facto'' head of the Federal Reserve. Norman pressured the heads of the central banks of France and Germany to inflate as well, but unlike Strong, they refused.<ref name="rothbard 2002 141" /> Rothbard says American inflation was meant to allow Britain to inflate as well, because under the gold standard, Britain could not inflate on its own.


====Austrian School====
In the Austrian view it was this inflation of the money supply that led to an unsustainable boom in both asset prices (stocks and bonds) and capital goods. By the time the Fed belatedly tightened in 1928, it was far too late and, in the Austrian view, a depression was inevitable.
Two prominent theorists in the ] on the Great Depression include Austrian economist ] and American economist ], who wrote '']'' (1963). In their view, much like the monetarists, the ] (created in 1913) shoulders much of the blame; however, unlike the ], they argue that the key cause of the Depression was the expansion of the ] in the 1920s which led to an unsustainable credit-driven boom.<ref name="America's Great Depression, pp. 159-163">Murray Rothbard, ''America's Great Depression'' (Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2000), pp. 159–163.</ref>


In the Austrian view, it was this inflation of the money supply that led to an unsustainable boom in both asset prices (stocks and bonds) and ]. Therefore, by the time the Federal Reserve tightened in 1928 it was far too late to prevent an economic contraction.<ref name="America's Great Depression, pp. 159-163" /> In February 1929 ] published a paper predicting the Federal Reserve's actions would lead to a crisis starting in the ] and ] markets.<ref>Steele, G. R. (2001). ''Keynes and Hayek''. Routledge. p. 9. {{ISBN|978-0-415-25138-9}}.</ref>
The artificial interference in the economy was a disaster prior to the Depression, and government efforts to prop up the economy after the crash of 1929 only made things worse. According to Rothbard, government intervention delayed the market's adjustment and made the road to complete recovery more difficult.<ref>{{harvnb|Rothbard|2002|p=25}}</ref>


According to Rothbard, the government support for failed enterprises and efforts to keep wages above their market values actually prolonged the Depression.<ref>Rothbard, ''America's Great Depression'', pp. 19–21.</ref> Unlike ], after 1970 ] believed that the Federal Reserve had further contributed to the problems of the Depression by permitting the money supply to shrink during the earliest years of the Depression.<ref>
Furthermore, Rothbard criticizes Milton Friedman's assertion that the central bank failed to inflate the supply of money. Rothbard asserts that the Federal Reserve bought $1.1 billion of government securities from February to July 1932, raising its total holding to $1.8 billion. Total bank reserves rose by only $212 million, but Rothbard argues that this was because the American populace lost faith in the banking system and began hoarding more cash, a factor quite beyond the control of the Central Bank. The potential for a run on the banks caused local bankers to be more conservative in lending out their reserves, and this, Rothbard argues, was the cause of the Federal Reserve's inability to inflate.<ref>{{harvnb|Rothbard|2002|pp=293–294}}</ref>
For Hayek's view, see:
* Diego Pizano, ''Conversations with Great Economists: Friedrich A. Hayek, John Hicks, Nicholas Kaldor, Leonid V. Kantorovich, Joan Robinson, Paul A.Samuelson, Jan Tinbergen'' (Jorge Pinto Books, 2009).
For Rothbard's view, see:
* Murray Rothbard, ''A History of Money and Banking in the United States'' (Ludwig von Mises Institute), pp. 293–294.</ref> However, during the Depression (in 1932<ref name=":1" /> and in 1934)<ref name=":1" /> Hayek had criticized both the ] and the ] for not taking a more contractionary stance.<ref name=":1">], Robert D. Wood, ''Friedrich A. Hayek'', Taylor & Francis, 2004, {{ISBN|978-0-415-31057-4}}, p. 115.</ref>


] argued that most ] that plagued the American economy, such as those in ], ], ], ], ], and ], were generated by government creating a boom through easy money and credit, which was soon followed by the inevitable bust.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://fee.org/articles/the-great-depression/|title=The Great Depression|access-date=23 October 2016|work=]|first=Hans|last=Sennholz|date=1 October 1969|archive-date=24 December 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211224092014/https://fee.org/articles/the-great-depression/|url-status=live}}</ref>
]


] wrote in the 1930s: "Credit expansion cannot increase the supply of real goods. It merely brings about a rearrangement. It diverts capital investment away from the course prescribed by the state of economic wealth and market conditions. It causes production to pursue paths which it would not follow unless the economy were to acquire an increase in material goods. As a result, the upswing lacks a solid base. It is not real prosperity. It is illusory prosperity. It did not develop from an increase in economic wealth, i.e. the accumulation of savings made available for productive investment. Rather, it arose because the credit expansion created the illusion of such an increase. Sooner or later, it must become apparent that this economic situation is built on sand."<ref>{{cite web|url=https://mises.org/library/causes-economic-crisis-and-other-essays-and-after-great-depression|title=The Causes of the Economic Crisis, and Other Essays Before and After the Great Depression|access-date=24 October 2016|work=]|first=Ludwig|last=Mises|date=18 August 2014|archive-date=5 December 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211205164755/https://mises.org/library/causes-economic-crisis-and-other-essays-and-after-great-depression|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.businessinsider.com/buying-bad-debt-to-return-bank-solvency-2011-2?op=1|title=Buying Bad Debt to Return Bank Solvency|access-date=24 October 2016|work=]|first=Bill|last=Bonner|date=25 February 2011|archive-date=24 October 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161024214604/http://www.businessinsider.com/buying-bad-debt-to-return-bank-solvency-2011-2?op=1|url-status=live}}</ref>
===Business===
], elected in 1932 and inaugurated March 4, 1933, primarily blamed the excesses of big business for causing an unstable bubble-like economy. Democrats believed the problem was that business had too much money, and the ] was intended as a remedy, by empowering ] and farmers and by raising taxes on corporate profits. Regulation of the economy was a favorite remedy. Some New Deal regulation (the ] and ]) was declared unconstitutional by the ]. Most New Deal regulations were abolished or scaled back in the 1970s and 1980s in a bipartisan wave of ].<ref>{{cite book|author= Vietor, Richard H. K.|title=Contrived Competition: Regulation and Deregulation in America|year=1994}}</ref> However the ], ], and ] won widespread support.


==== Marxist ====
===Lack of government deficit spending===
] generally argue that the Great Depression was the result of the inherent instability of the ].<ref>{{Cite book |last=Corey |first=Lewis |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=fAW8AAAAIAAJ |title=The Decline of American Capitalism |date=1934 |publisher=Covici Friede Publishers |isbn=978-0-405-04116-7 |language=en}}</ref> According to '']'', "The idea that capitalism caused the Great Depression was widely held among intellectuals and the general public for many decades."<ref>{{Cite web |last=Fleisher |first=Larry |date=30 October 2009 |title=The Great Depression And The Great Recession |url=https://www.forbes.com/2009/10/29/depression-recession-gdp-imf-milton-friedman-opinions-columnists-bruce-bartlett.html |access-date= |website=] |language=en}}</ref>
British economist ] argued in '']'' that lower aggregate expenditures in the economy contributed to a massive decline in income and to employment that was well below the average. In this situation, the economy might have reached a perfect balance, at a cost of high unemployment. Keynesian economists called on governments during times of ] to pick up the slack by increasing ] and/or cutting taxes.


====Inequality====
Massive increases in ], new ], and boosting farm prices did start turning the U.S. economy around in 1933 as shown in the three graphs above, but it was a slow and painful process. The U.S. had not returned to 1929's GNP for over a decade and still had an unemployment rate of about 15% in 1940 — down from 25% in 1933.
] displaces tenants from the land in the western dry cotton area. ], 1938.]]


Two economists of the 1920s, ] and ], popularized a theory that influenced many policy makers, including ], ], ], and ]. It held the economy produced more than it consumed, because the consumers did not have enough income. Thus the unequal ] throughout the 1920s caused the Great Depression.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Dorfman |first=Joseph |url=https://worldcat.org/oclc/71400420 |title=The economic mind in American civilization. |date=1959 |publisher=The Viking Press |oclc=71400420 |access-date=18 February 2022 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220218125334/https://www.worldcat.org/title/economic-mind-in-american-civilization-vol-5-1918-1933/oclc/71400420 |archive-date=18 February 2022 |url-status=live}}</ref><ref name="Allgoewer">{{cite journal|last=Allgoewer|first=Elisabeth|date=May 2002|title=Underconsumption theories and Keynesian economics. Interpretations of the Great Depression|journal=Discussion Paper No. 2002–14|url=https://www.vwa.unisg.ch/RePEc/usg/dp2002/dp0214allgoewer_ganz.pdf|access-date=18 February 2022|archive-date=4 March 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304134117/http://www1.vwa.unisg.ch/RePEc/usg/dp2002/dp0214allgoewer_ganz.pdf|url-status=live}}</ref>
===Inequality of wealth and income===
], who served as ]'s ] from November 1934 to February 1948, detailed what he believed caused the Depression in his memoirs, ''Beckoning Frontiers'' (New York, Alfred A. Knopf, 1951)<ref name=Beckoning>{{cite book | last = Eccles | first = Marriner S. | authorlink = Marriner S. Eccles | title = Beckoning Frontiers: Public and Personal Recollections | publisher = Alfred A. Knopf |edition = 1st | year = 1951 | location = New York | pages = 499 | oclc = 3720103}}</ref>:
<blockquote>
''As mass production has to be accompanied by mass consumption, mass consumption, in turn, implies a distribution of wealth -- not of existing wealth, but of wealth as it is currently produced -- to provide men with buying power equal to the amount of goods and services offered by the nation's economic machinery.''
<p>
Instead of achieving that kind of distribution, a giant suction pump had by 1929-30 drawn into a few hands an increasing portion of currently produced wealth. This served them as capital accumulations. But by taking purchasing power out of the hands of mass consumers, the savers denied to themselves the kind of effective demand for their products that would justify a reinvestment of their capital accumulations in new plants. In consequence, as in a poker game where the chips were concentrated in fewer and fewer hands, the other fellows could stay in the game only by borrowing. When their credit ran out, the game stopped.
<p>
That is what happened to us in the twenties. We sustained high levels of employment in that period with the aid of an exceptional expansion of debt outside of the banking system. This debt was provided by the large growth of business savings as well as savings by individuals, particularly in the upper-income groups where taxes were relatively low. Private debt outside of the banking system increased about fifty per cent. This debt, which was at high interest rates, largely took the form of mortgage debt on housing, office, and hotel structures, consumer installment debt, brokers' loans, and foreign debt. The stimulation to spend by debt-creation of this sort was short-lived and could not be counted on to sustain high levels of employment for long periods of time. Had there been a better distribution of the current income from the national product -- in other words, had there been less savings by business and the higher-income groups and more income in the lower groups -- we should have had far greater stability in our economy. Had the six billion dollars, for instance, that were loaned by corporations and wealthy individuals for stock-market speculation been distributed to the public as lower prices or higher wages and with less profits to the corporations and the well-to-do, it would have prevented or greatly moderated the economic collapse that began at the end of 1929.
<p>
The time came when there were no more poker chips to be loaned on credit. Debtors thereupon were forced to curtail their consumption in an effort to create a margin that could be applied to the reduction of outstanding debts. This naturally reduced the demand for goods of all kinds and brought on what seemed to be overproduction, but was in reality underconsumption when judged in terms of the real world instead of the money world. This, in turn, brought about a fall in prices and employment.
<p>
Unemployment further decreased the consumption of goods, which further increased unemployment, thus closing the circle in a continuing decline of prices. Earnings began to disappear, requiring economies of all kinds in the wages, salaries, and time of those employed. And thus again the vicious circle of deflation was closed until one third of the entire working population was unemployed, with our national income reduced by fifty per cent, and with the aggregate debt burden greater than ever before, not in dollars, but measured by current values and income that represented the ability to pay. Fixed charges, such as taxes, railroad and other utility rates, insurance and interest charges, clung close to the 1929 level and required such a portion of the national income to meet them that the amount left for consumption of goods was not sufficient to support the population.
<p>
This then, was my reading of what brought on the depression.
<p>
</blockquote>


According to this view, the root cause of the Great Depression was a global over-investment in heavy industry capacity compared to wages and earnings from independent businesses, such as farms. The proposed solution was for the government to pump money into the consumers' pockets. That is, it must redistribute purchasing power, maintaining the industrial base, and re-inflating prices and wages to force as much of the inflationary increase in purchasing power into ]. The economy was overbuilt, and new factories were not needed. Foster and Catchings recommended<ref>{{Cite book|last1=Foster|first1=William Trufant|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=BDNBAAAAIAAJ|title=The Road to Plenty|last2=Catchings|first2=Waddill|date=1928|publisher=Houghton Mifflin|language=en|access-date=28 December 2021|archive-date=18 February 2022|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220218125332/https://books.google.com/books?id=BDNBAAAAIAAJ|url-status=live}}</ref> federal and state governments to start large construction projects, a program followed by Hoover and Roosevelt.
===The Great Depression ended===
The turning point in the depression was in 1933, as can be seen in the above Industrial Production graph. Some economists attribute the subsequent recovery to monetary expansion that began after the ] a few days after Roosevelt was inaugrated on March 4, 1933 and devaluation of the U.S. dollar that was then tied to gold.<ref>Romer, Christina D., "What Ended the Great Depression", ''Journal of Economic History'', December 1992, vol 52, num 4, pages 757-784</ref>


====Productivity shock====
==Literature==
{{blockquote|It cannot be emphasized too strongly that the trends we are describing are long-time trends and were thoroughly evident before 1929. These trends are in nowise the result of the present depression, nor are they the result of the World War. On the contrary, the present depression is a collapse resulting from these long-term trends.|]<ref>{{Cite journal |last1 = Hubbert |first1 = M. King |title = Man Hours and Distribution, Derived from ''Man Hours: A Declining Quantity'', Technocracy, Series A, No. 8, August 1936 |year = 1940 |url = https://www.scribd.com/doc/22289589/Man-Hours-and-Distribution-M-King-Hubbert |journal = |access-date = September 9, 2017 |archive-date = April 7, 2020 |archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20200407132524/https://www.scribd.com/doc/22289589/Man-Hours-and-Distribution-M-King-Hubbert |url-status = live }}</ref>}}
The U.S. Depression has been the subject of much writing, as the country has sought to re-evaluate an era that caused emotional as well as financial trauma to its people. Perhaps the most noteworthy and famous novel written on the subject is '']'', published in 1939 and written by ], who was awarded both the ] for literature and the ] for the work. The novel focuses on a poor family of sharecroppers who are forced from their home as drought, economic hardship, and changes in the ] occur during the Great Depression. Steinbeck's '']'' is another important novel about a journey during the Great Depression. ''The Great Depression'' is a novella written by Alon Bersharder about a sad, disgruntled temporary worker, making the title both a homage to the historical event and a pun. Additionally, Harper Lee's '']'' is set during the Great Depression. Margaret Atwood's Booker prize-winning '']'' is likewise set in the Great Depression, centering on a privileged socialite's love affair with a Marxist revolutionary.

The first three decades of the 20th century saw economic output surge with ], ], and motorized farm machinery, and because of the rapid growth in productivity there was a lot of excess production capacity and the work week was being reduced. The dramatic rise in ] of major industries in the U.S. and the effects of productivity on output, wages and the workweek are discussed by Spurgeon Bell in his book ''Productivity, Wages, and National Income'' (1940).<ref>{{Cite book |last1= Bell |first1=Spurgeon|title= Productivity, Wages and National Income, The Institute of Economics of the Brookings Institution |year= 1940}}</ref>

==Effects by country==
{{More citations needed section|date=May 2016}}
]
The majority of countries set up relief programs and most underwent some sort of political upheaval, pushing them to the ]. Many of the countries in Europe and Latin America, that were democracies, saw their democratic governments overthrown by some form of dictatorship or authoritarian rule, most famously ]. ] its ], becoming the only region ever to voluntarily relinquish democracy. There, too, were severe impacts across the Middle East and North Africa, including economic decline which led to social unrest.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Anderson |first=Betty S. |url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/945376555 |title=A history of the modern Middle East : rulers, rebels, and rogues |date=2016 |isbn=978-0-8047-9875-4 |location=Stanford, California |oclc=945376555 |access-date=13 February 2022 |archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20220218125354/https://www.worldcat.org/title/history-of-the-modern-middle-east-rulers-rebels-and-rogues/oclc/945376555 |archive-date=18 February 2022 |url-status=live}}</ref><ref>James Overton, "Economic Crisis and the End of Democracy: Politics in Newfoundland During the Great Depression." ''Labour'' 1990 (26): 85–124. {{ISSN|0700-3862}}</ref>

=== Argentina ===
{{Expand section|date=April 2024}}
Decline in foreign trade hit Argentina hard. The British decision to stop importing Argentine beef led to the signing of the ], which preserved a quota in exchange for significant concessions to British exports. By 1935, the economy had recovered to 1929 levels, and the same year, the ] was formed.<ref>{{Cite book |last=della Paolera |first=Gerardo |title=Straining at the Anchor: The Argentine Currency Board and the Search for Macroeconomic Stability, 1880-1935 |last2=Taylor |first2=Alan M. |author-link2=Alan M. Taylor |publisher=] |year=2001 |pages=188–189 |chapter=Steering through the Great Depression: Institutions, Expectations, and the Change of Macroeconomic Regime |chapter-url=http://www.nber.org/chapters/c8845}}</ref> However, the Great Depression was the last time when Argentina was one of the richer countries of the world, as it stopped growing in the decades thereafter, and became underdeveloped.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Spruk |first=Rok |date=15 November 2019 |title=The rise and fall of Argentina |journal=Latin American Economic Review |volume=28 |issue=1 |pages=16 |doi=10.1186/s40503-019-0076-2 |doi-access=free |issn=2196-436X}}</ref>


==Effects==
===Australia=== ===Australia===
{{main|Great Depression in Australia}} {{Main|Great Depression in Australia}}
Australia's extreme dependence on agricultural and industrial ]s meant it was one of the hardest-hit countries in the ], amongst the likes of Canada and Germany. Falling export demand and commodity prices placed massive downward pressures on wages. Further, ] reached a record high of almost 32% in 1932, with incidents of ] becoming common. After 1932, an increase in wool and meat prices led to a gradual recovery. Australia's dependence on agricultural and industrial exports meant it was one of the hardest-hit developed countries.<ref>Geoffrey Lawrence, ''Capitalism and the Countryside: The rural crisis in Australia'' (Pluto Press, 1987).</ref> Falling export demand and commodity prices placed massive downward pressures on wages. Unemployment reached a record high of 29% in 1932,<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211231105618/https://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/abs@.nsf/Previousproducts/1301.0Feature%20Article142001?opendocument&tabname=Summary&prodno=1301.0&issue=2001&num=&view= |date=31 December 2021}}, Australian Bureau of Statistics</ref> with incidents of ] becoming common.<ref>John Birmingham (2000). Leviathan: The unauthorised biography of Sydney. Random House. {{ISBN|978-0-09-184203-1}}.</ref> After 1932, an increase in wool and meat prices led to a gradual recovery.<ref>Judy Mackinolty, ed. ''The Wasted Years?: Australia's Great Depression'' (Allen & Unwin, 1981).</ref>


===Canada=== ===Canada===
{{Main|Great Depression in Canada}}
]
], ], Canada.]]
{{main|Great Depression in Canada}}

Harshly impacted by both the global economic downturn and the ], Canadian industrial production had fallen to only 58% of the 1929 level by 1932, the second lowest level in the world after the United States, and well behind nations such as Britain, which saw it fall only to 83% of the 1929 level. Total national income fell to 56% of the 1929 level, again worse than any nation apart from the United States.
Harshly affected by both the global economic downturn and the ], Canadian industrial production had by 1932 fallen to only 58% of its 1929 figure, the second-lowest level in the world after the United States, and well behind countries such as Britain, which fell to only 83% of the 1929 level. Total ] fell to 56% of the 1929 level, again worse than any country apart from the United States. Unemployment reached 27% at the depth of the Depression in 1933.<ref> {{webarchive |url= https://web.archive.org/web/20090127051620/https://canadianeconomy.gc.ca/english/economy/1929_39depression.html |date=27 January 2009}}, Source: Bank of Canada</ref>

===Chile===
{{Main|Great Depression in Chile}}
The ] labeled ] the country hardest-hit by the Great Depression, because 80% of government revenue came from exports of copper and nitrates, which were in low demand. Chile initially felt the impact of the Great Depression in 1930, when GDP dropped 14%, mining income declined 27%, and export earnings fell 28%. By 1932, GDP had shrunk to less than half of what it had been in 1929, exacting a terrible toll in unemployment and business failures.

Influenced profoundly by the Great Depression, many government leaders promoted the development of local industry in an effort to insulate the economy from future external shocks. After six years of government ], which succeeded in reestablishing Chile's creditworthiness, Chileans elected to office during the 1938–58 period a succession of center and left-of-center governments interested in promoting economic growth through government intervention.

Prompted in part by the devastating ], the ] government of ] created the Production Development Corporation (Corporación de Fomento de la Producción, ]) to encourage with subsidies and direct investments &mdash; an ambitious program of ]. Consequently, as in other Latin American countries, ] became an entrenched aspect of the Chilean economy.

===China===
{{Main|Nanjing Decade}}
China was largely unaffected by the Depression, mainly by having stuck to the ]. However, the U.S. silver purchase act of 1934 created an intolerable demand on China's silver coins, and so, in the end, the silver standard was officially abandoned in 1935 in favor of the four Chinese national banks'{{Which|date=September 2020}} "legal note" issues. China and the ], which followed suit in this regard in September 1935, would be the last to abandon the silver standard. In addition, the ] also acted energetically to modernize the legal and penal systems, stabilize prices, amortize debts, reform the banking and currency systems, build railroads and highways, improve public health facilities, legislate against traffic in narcotics, and augment industrial and agricultural production. On 3 November 1935, the government instituted the fiat currency (fapi) reform, immediately stabilizing prices and also raising revenues for the government.

===European African colonies===
The sharp fall in commodity prices and the steep decline in exports hurt the economies of the European colonies in Africa and Asia.<ref>Anthony Latham and John Heaton, ''The Depression and the Developing World, 1914–1939'' (1981).</ref><ref>{{cite journal |jstor=3601244 |language=fr |title=Mutation de l'Impérialisme Colonial Français dans les Années 30 |journal=African Economic History |issue=4 |pages=103–152 |last1=Coquery-Vidrovitch |first1=C. |year=1977 |doi=10.2307/3601244}}</ref> The agricultural sector was especially hard-hit. For example, ] had recently become a major export crop in Kenya and Tanganyika. During the depression, it suffered severely from low prices and marketing problems that affected all colonial commodities in Africa. Sisal producers established centralized controls for the export of their fibre.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Westcott |first1=Nicholas |year=1984 |title=The East African sisal industry, 1929–1949: the marketing of a colonial commodity during depression and war |journal=Journal of African History |volume=25 |issue=4 |pages=445–461 |doi=10.1017/s0021853700028486 |s2cid=161203218}}</ref> There was widespread unemployment and hardship among peasants, labourers, colonial auxiliaries, and artisans.<ref>R. Olufeni Ekundare, ''An Economic History of Nigeria 1860–1960'' (1973) . {{Webarchive |url= https://web.archive.org/web/20211231120210/https://www.sahistory.org.za/archive/economic-history-nigeria-1860-1960-r-olufeni-ekundare |date=31 December 2021}}, pp. 104–226.</ref> The budgets of colonial governments were cut, which forced the reduction in ongoing infrastructure projects, such as the building and upgrading of roads, ports, and communications.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Olubomehin |first1=O.O. |year=2002 |title=Road Transportation and the Economy of South-Western Nigeria, 1920–1939 |journal=Lagos Historical Review |volume=2 |pages=106–121}}</ref> The budget cuts delayed the schedule for creating systems of higher education.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Lungu |first1=Gatian F. |year=1993 |title=Educational Policy-Making in Colonial Zambia: The Case of Higher Education for Africans from 1924 to 1964 |journal=The Journal of Negro History |volume=78 |issue=4 |pages=207–232 |doi=10.2307/2717416 |jstor=2717416 |s2cid=149538992}}</ref>

The depression severely hurt the export-based ] economy because of the drop in international demand for raw materials and for agricultural products. For example, the price of peanuts fell from 125 to 25 centimes. In some areas, as in the ] mining region, employment declined by 70%. In the country as a whole, the wage labour force decreased by 72,000 people, and many men returned to their villages. In Leopoldville, the population decreased by 33% because of this labour migration.<ref>R. Anstey, ''King Leopold's Legacy: The Congo under Belgian Rule 1908–1960'' (1966), p. 109.</ref>

Political protests were not common. However, there was a growing demand, that the paternalistic claims be honored by colonial governments to respond vigorously. The theme was, that economic reforms were more urgently needed than political reforms.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Ochonu |first1=Moses |year=2009 |title=Critical convergence: the Great Depression and the meshing of Nigerian and British anti-colonial polemic |journal=Canadian Journal of African Studies |volume=43 |issue=2 |pages=245–281 |doi=10.1080/00083968.2010.9707572 |s2cid=142695035}}</ref> French West Africa launched an extensive program of educational reform, in which "rural schools", designed to modernize agriculture, would stem the flow of under-employed farm workers to cities where unemployment was high. Students were trained in traditional arts, crafts, and farming techniques and were then expected to return to their own villages and towns.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Gamble |first1=Harry |year=2009 |title=Les paysans de l'empire: écoles rurales et imaginaire colonial en Afrique occidentale française dans les années 1930 |language=French |journal=Cahiers d'Études Africaines |volume=49 |issue=3 |pages=775–803 |doi=10.4000/etudesafricaines.15630 |doi-access=free}}</ref>


===France=== ===France===
{{main|Great Depression in France}} {{Main|Great Depression in France}}
]
The Depression began to affect France from about 1931. France's relatively high degree of self-sufficiency meant the damage was considerably less than in nations like Germany. However, hardship and unemployment were high enough to lead to rioting and the rise of the ] ].
The crisis affected France a bit later than other countries, hitting hard around 1931.<ref>{{Cite journal |jstor=2601740 |title=France and the Depression |journal=International Affairs |volume=15 |issue=2 |pages=202–224 |last1=Laufenburger |first1=Henry |year=1936 |doi=10.2307/2601740}}</ref> While the 1920s grew at the very strong rate of 4.43% per year, the 1930s rate fell to only 0.63%.<ref>Jean-Pierre Dormois, ''The French Economy in the Twentieth Century'' (2004) p. 31</ref>

The depression was relatively mild: unemployment peaked under 5%, the fall in production was at most 20% below the 1929 output; there was no banking crisis.<ref>{{cite journal |doi=10.1006/redy.2001.0143 |title=The French Depression in the 1930s |journal=Review of Economic Dynamics |volume=5 |pages=73–99 |year=2002 |last1=Beaudry |first1=Paul |last2=Portier |first2=Franck |issue=1}}</ref>

However, the depression had drastic effects on the local economy, and partly explains the ] and even more the formation of the ], led by ] ], which won the elections in 1936. Ultra-nationalist groups also saw increased popularity, though democracy prevailed into ].

France's relatively high degree of self-sufficiency meant the damage was considerably less than in neighbouring states like Germany.


===Germany=== ===Germany===
{{Main|Weimar Republic}}
{{main|Great Depression in Central Europe}}
]
Germany's ] was hit hard by the depression, as American loans to help rebuild the German economy now stopped. Unemployment soared, especially in larger cities, and the ] veered toward ]. Repayment of the war reparations due by Germany were suspended in 1932 following the ]. By that time Germany had repaid 1/8th of the reparations. ]'s ] came to power in January 1933.
The Great Depression hit Germany hard. The impact of the ] forced American banks to end the new loans that had been funding the repayments under the ] and the ]. The financial crisis escalated out of control in mid-1931, starting with the collapse of the ] in Vienna in May.<ref name="William Ashworth 1962 pp. 237-244"/> This put heavy pressure on Germany, which was already in political turmoil with the rise in violence of ] and ] movements, as well as with investor nervousness at harsh government financial policies,<ref name="Isabel Schnabel 1931"/> investors withdrew their short-term money from Germany as confidence spiraled downward. The Reichsbank lost 150&nbsp;million marks in the first week of June, 540&nbsp;million in the second, and 150&nbsp;million in two days, 19–20 June. Collapse was at hand. U.S. President Herbert Hoover called for a moratorium on payment of war reparations. This angered Paris, which depended on a steady flow of German payments, but it slowed the crisis down, and the moratorium was agreed to in July 1931. An international conference in London later in July produced no agreements, but on 19 August, a standstill agreement froze Germany's foreign liabilities for six months. Germany received emergency funding from private banks in New York as well as the Bank of International Settlements and the Bank of England. The funding only slowed the process. Industrial failures began in Germany, a major bank closed in July, and a two-day holiday for all German banks was declared. Business failures became more frequent in July, and spread to Romania and Hungary.<ref name="V. Hodson, 1938 pp. 64-76"/>

In 1932, 90% of German reparation payments were cancelled (in the 1950s, Germany repaid all its missed reparations debts). Widespread unemployment reached 25%, as every sector was hurt. The government did not increase government spending to deal with Germany's growing crisis, as they were afraid, that a high-spending policy could lead to a return of the ] that had affected Germany in 1923. Germany's ] was hit hard by the depression, as American loans to help rebuild the German economy now stopped.<ref> {{Webarchive |url= https://web.archive.org/web/20081220090243/http://www.english.uiuc.edu/maps/depression/about.htm |date=20 December 2008}}, University of Illinois</ref> The unemployment rate reached nearly 30% in 1932.<ref name="pbs"/>

] operating a screw press against a workman, Nazi propaganda ], obverse]]

]

The German political landscape was dramatically altered, leading to ]. The ] rose from being peripheral to winning 18.3% of the vote in the ], and the ] also made gains, while moderate forces, like the ], the ], and the ] lost seats. The next two years were marked by increased street violence between Nazis and Communists, while governments under President ] increasingly relied on ], bypassing the ].<ref>{{cite book |last=Bullock |first=Alan |author-link=Alan Bullock |title=Hitler: A Study in Tyranny |year=1991 |orig-year=1962 |publisher=Harper Perennial |location=New York; London |isbn=978-1-56852-036-0 |title-link = Hitler: A Study in Tyranny}}</ref> Hitler ran for the Presidency in 1932, and while he lost to the incumbent Hindenburg in the election, it marked a point during which both Nazi Party and the Communist parties rose in the years following the crash to altogether possess a Reichstag majority following the ].<ref name="pbs"> {{Webarchive |url= https://web.archive.org/web/20211231133720/https://www.pbs.org/wgbh/commandingheights/lo/countries/de/de_economic.html |date=31 December 2021}}, Public Broadcasting Service (PBS).</ref><ref>{{Cite web |url=https://www.historyplace.com/worldwar2/riseofhitler/runs.htm |title=The History Place – Rise of Hitler: Hitler Runs for President |website=History Place |access-date=23 October 2016 |archive-date=3 November 2016 |archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20161103215044/http://www.historyplace.com/worldwar2/riseofhitler/runs.htm |url-status=live}}</ref> Although the Nazis lost seats in ], they remained the largest party, and Hitler was appointed as Chancellor the following January. The government formation deal was designed to give Hitler's conservative coalition partners many checks on his power, but over the next few months, the Nazis manoeuvred to consolidate a single-party dictatorship.<ref name="Kershaw98">{{cite book |author=Kershaw |first=Ian |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=nV-N10gyoFwC |title=Hitler, 1889–1936: Hubris |publisher=W.W. Norton |year=1998 |isbn=978-0-393-32035-0 |page=411}}</ref>

] speaking in 1935]]
Hitler followed an economic policy of ], creating a network of client states and economic allies in central Europe and Latin America. By cutting wages and taking control of labor unions, plus public works spending, unemployment fell significantly by 1935. Large-scale military spending played a major role in the recovery.<ref>], ''The Wages of Destruction: The Making and Breaking of the Nazi Economy'' (2007)</ref> The policies had the effect of driving up the cost of food imports and depleting foreign currency reserves, leading to economic impasse by 1936. Nazi Germany faced a choice of either reversing course or pressing ahead with rearmament and autarky. Hitler chose the latter route, which, according to ], "could only be partially accomplished without territorial expansion" and therefore war.<ref>], "Misjudging Hitler", pp. 93–115 from ''The Origins of the Second World War Reconsidered'' edited by Gordon Martel, Routledge: London, England, 1999, pp. 98–99.</ref><ref>Kershaw, Ian ''To Hell and Back: Europe 1914–1949'', Ch. 5</ref>

===Greece===
{{Main|Economic history of Greece and the Greek world}}
The reverberations of the Great Depression hit Greece in 1932. The ] tried to adopt deflationary policies to stave off the crises that were going on in other countries, but these largely failed. For a brief period, the drachma was pegged to the U.S. dollar, but this was unsustainable given the country's large trade deficit and the only long-term effects of this were Greece's foreign exchange reserves being almost totally wiped out in 1932. Remittances from abroad declined sharply, and the value of the drachma began to plummet from 77 drachmas to the dollar in March 1931 to 111 drachmas to the dollar in April 1931. This was especially harmful to Greece, as the country relied on imports from the UK, France, and the Middle East for many necessities. Greece went off the gold standard in April 1932, and declared a moratorium on all interest payments. The country also adopted protectionist policies, such as import quotas, which several European countries also did during the period.

Protectionist policies coupled with a weak drachma and the stifling of imports allowed the Greek industry to expand during the Great Depression. In 1939, the Greek industrial output was 179% that of 1928. These industries were for the most part "built on sand", as one report of the Bank of Greece put it, as without massive protection, they would not have been able to survive. Despite the global depression, Greece managed to suffer comparatively little, averaging an average growth rate of 3.5% from 1932 to 1939. The dictatorial regime of ] took over the Greek government in 1936, and economic growth was strong in the years leading up to the Second World War.

===Iceland===
{{Main|Economic history of Iceland}}
Icelandic post-World War I prosperity came to an end with the outbreak of the Great Depression. The Depression hit Iceland hard, as the value of exports plummeted. The total value of Icelandic exports fell from 74&nbsp;million kronur in 1929 to 48&nbsp;million in 1932, and was not to rise again to the pre-1930 level until after 1939.<ref name=":3">{{Cite book |title=History of Iceland |last=Karlsson |first=Gunnar |year=2000 |pages=308–12}}</ref> Government interference in the economy increased: "Imports were regulated, trade with foreign currency was monopolized by state-owned banks, and loan capital was largely distributed by state-regulated funds".<ref name=":3" /> Due to the outbreak of the ], which cut Iceland's exports of saltfish by half, the Depression lasted in Iceland until the outbreak of World War II (when prices for fish exports soared).<ref name=":3" />

===India===
{{Main|Great Depression in India}}
How much India was affected, has been hotly debated. Historians have argued, that the Great Depression slowed long-term industrial development.<ref>{{cite book |title=A Colonial Economy in the Great Depression, Madras (1929–1937) |first=K. A. |last=Manikumar |year=2003 |ref=Manikumar}}</ref> Apart from two sectors — ] and coal — the economy was little-affected. However, there were major negative impacts on the jute industry, as world demand fell and prices plunged.<ref>Samita Sen, "Labour, Organization and Gender: The Jute Industry in India in the 1930s", in Helmut Konrad and Wolfgang Maderthaner, eds. ''Routes Into the Abyss: Coping with Crises in the 1930s'' (2013) pp. 152–66.</ref> Otherwise, conditions were fairly stable. Local markets in agriculture and small-scale industry showed modest gains.<ref>{{Cite journal |jstor=312643 |title=The Great Depression and Indian Industry: Changing Interpretations and Changing Perceptions |journal=Modern Asian Studies |volume=21 |issue=3 |pages=585–623 |last1=Simmons |first1=Colin |year=1987 |doi=10.1017/S0026749X00009215 |s2cid=145538790}}</ref>

===Ireland===
{{Main|Economic history of the Republic of Ireland}}
Frank Barry and ] have argued that:
:Ireland was a largely agrarian economy, trading almost exclusively with the UK at the time of the Great Depression. Beef and dairy products comprised the bulk of exports, and Ireland fared well relative to many other commodity producers, particularly in the early years of the depression.<ref>Frank Barry and Mary F. Daly, "Concurrent Irish Perspectives on the Great Depression" (2010) </ref><ref>Frank Barry and Mary E. Daly, "Irish Perceptions of the Great Depression" in Michael Psalidopoulos, ''The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context'' (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012), pp. 395–424.</ref><ref>See also B. Girvin, ''Between Two Worlds: Politics and Economy in Independent Ireland'' (Dublin: Gill and Macmillan, 1989).</ref><ref>Barry, Frank, and Mary E. Daly. "Irish Perceptions of the Great Depression" (No. iiisdp349. IIIS, 2011.) {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150811154311/https://www.tcd.ie/iiis/documents/discussion/pdfs/iiisdp349.pdf |date=11 August 2015 }}</ref>

===Italy===
{{Main|Economic history of Italy}}
]
] giving a speech at the ] ] factory in Turin, 1932]]
The Great Depression hit ] very hard.<ref>Vera Zamagni, ''The economic history of Italy 1860–1990'' (Oxford University Press, 1993)</ref> As industries came close to failure they were bought out by the banks in a largely illusionary bail-out—the assets used to fund the purchases were largely worthless. This led to a financial crisis peaking in 1932 and major government intervention. The ] (IRI) was formed in January 1933 and took control of the bank-owned companies, suddenly giving Italy the largest state-owned industrial sector in Europe (excluding the USSR). IRI did rather well with its new responsibilities—restructuring, modernising and rationalising as much as it could. It was a significant factor in post-1945 development. But it took the Italian economy until 1935 to recover the manufacturing levels of 1930—a position that was only 60% better than that of 1913.<ref>Fabrizio Mattesini, and Beniamino Quintieri. "Italy and the Great Depression: An analysis of the Italian economy, 1929–1936." ''Explorations in Economic History'' (1997) 34#3 pp: 265–294.</ref><ref>Fabrizio Mattesini and Beniamino Quintieri. "Does a reduction in the length of the working week reduce unemployment? Some evidence from the Italian economy during the Great Depression." ''Explorations in Economic History'' (2006), 43#3, pp. 413–37.</ref>


===Japan=== ===Japan===
The Great Depression did not strongly affect Japan. The Japanese economy shrank by 8% during 1929&ndash;31. However, Japan's Minister of Finance (MoF) ] implemented the first version of ] policies: first, by increasing ]; and second, by devaluing ]. The MoF believed that the deficit spending could easily be paid for when productivity improved.{{Fact|date=November 2008}} The Great Depression did not strongly affect Japan. The Japanese economy shrank by 8% during 1929–31. Japan's Finance Minister ] was the first to implement what have come to be identified as ] economic policies: first, by large fiscal stimulus involving ]; and second, by devaluing ]. Takahashi used the Bank of Japan to sterilize the deficit spending and minimize resulting inflationary pressures. Econometric studies have identified the fiscal stimulus as especially effective.<ref>Myung Soo Cha, "Did Takahashi Korekiyo Rescue Japan from the Great Depression?", ''The Journal of Economic History'' 63, No. 1 (March 2003): 127–144.</ref>


The devaluation of the currency had an immediate effect. Japanese textiles began to displace British textiles in export markets. The deficit spending, however proved to be most profound. The deficit spending went into the purchase of munitions for the armed forces. By 1933, Japan was already out of the depression. By 1934 the MoF realized that the economy was in danger of overheating, and to avoid inflation, moved to reduce the deficit spending that went towards armaments and munitions. This resulted in a strong and swift negative reaction from nationalists, especially those in the Army, culminating in an assassination attempt on the MoF, leading to his eventual demise from poor health some months later. This had a ] on all civilian bureaucrats in the Japanese government. From 1934, the military's dominance of the government continued to grow. Instead of reducing deficit spending, the government introduced price controls and rationing schemes that reduced, but did not eliminate inflation, which would remain a problem until the end of ]. The devaluation of the currency had an immediate effect. Japanese textiles began to displace British textiles in export markets. The deficit spending proved to be most profound and went into the purchase of munitions for the armed forces. By 1933, Japan was already out of the depression. By 1934, Takahashi realized that the economy was in danger of overheating, and to avoid inflation, moved to reduce the deficit spending that went towards armaments and munitions.


This resulted in a strong and swift negative reaction from nationalists, especially those in the army, culminating in his assassination in the course of the ]. This had a ] on all civilian bureaucrats in the Japanese government. From 1934, the military's dominance of the government continued to grow. Instead of reducing deficit spending, the government introduced price controls and rationing schemes that reduced, but did not eliminate inflation, which remained a problem until the end of World War&nbsp;II.
The deficit spending had a transformative effect on Japan. Japan's industrial production doubled during the 1930s. Further, in 1929 the list of the largest firms in Japan was dominated by light industries, especially textile companies (many of Japan's automakers, like ], have their roots in the textile industry). By 1940 light industry had been displaced by heavy industry as the largest firms inside the Japanese economy. (For more on the Japanese economy in the 1930s see "MITI and the Japanese Miracle" by Chalmers Johnson).


The deficit spending had a transformative effect on Japan. Japan's industrial production doubled during the 1930s. Further, in 1929 the list of the largest firms in Japan was dominated by light industries, especially textile companies (many of Japan's automakers, such as ], have their roots in the textile industry). By 1940 ] had been displaced by heavy industry as the largest firms inside the Japanese economy.<ref>(For more on the Japanese economy in the 1930s see "MITI and the Japanese Miracle" by ].)</ref>
These events helped set the stage for World War II. In 1929, Japan's GNP was about a sixth of the U.S. and its per capita GNP was about a third.{{Fact|date=November 2008}} However, during the 1930s, the U.S. economy contracted by a third. By 1939, Japan's GNP was nearly half that of the United States, and its per capita GNP was nearly equal to the United States. Faced with having to face two Oceans, it was easy to see how some Japanese planners felt that they had an even chance against the U.S. What they may not have considered is that the U.S. had yet to truly kick in deficit financing for munitions until after 1940 - where upon the United States would experience its own doubling of industrial production in four short years.


===Latin America=== ===Latin America===
{{Main|Great Depression in Latin America}} {{Main|Great Depression in Latin America}}
Because of high levels of United States investment in Latin American economies, they were severely damaged by the Depression. Within the region, ], ] and ] were particularly badly affected. One result of the Depression in this area was the rise of ] movements. Because of high levels of U.S. investment in Latin American economies, they were severely damaged by the Depression. Within the region, ], ] and ] were particularly badly affected.<ref>Rosemary Thorp, ''Latin America in the 1930s: the role of the periphery in world crisis'' (Palgrave Macmillan, 2000).</ref>

{{Fact|date=October 2008}}
Before the 1929 crisis, links between the world economy and ]n economies had been established through American and British investment in Latin American exports to the world. As a result, Latin Americans export industries felt the depression quickly. World prices for commodities such as wheat, coffee and copper plunged. Exports from all of Latin America to the U.S. fell in value from $1.2&nbsp;billion in 1929 to $335&nbsp;million in 1933, rising to $660&nbsp;million in 1940.

But on the other hand, the depression led the area governments to develop new local industries and expand consumption and production. Following the example of the New Deal, governments in the area approved regulations and created or improved welfare institutions that helped millions of new industrial workers to achieve a better standard of living.


===Netherlands=== ===Netherlands===
{{main|Great Depression in the Netherlands}} {{Main|Great Depression in the Netherlands}}
]
From roughly 1931 until 1937, the Netherlands suffered a deep and exceptionally long depression. This depression was partly caused by the after-effects of the ] in the United States, and partly by internal factors in the Netherlands. Government policy, especially the very late dropping of the ], played a role in prolonging the depression. The Great Depression in the Netherlands led to some political instability and riots, and can be linked to the rise of the Dutch national-socialist party ]. The depression in the Netherlands eased off somewhat at the end of 1936, when the government finally dropped the ], but real economic stability did not return until after ].
From roughly 1931 to 1937, the ] suffered a deep and exceptionally long depression. This depression was partly caused by the after-effects of the American stock-market crash of 1929, and partly by internal factors in the Netherlands. Government policy, especially the very late dropping of the Gold Standard, played a role in prolonging the depression. The Great Depression in the Netherlands led to some political instability and riots, and can be linked to the rise of the Dutch fascist political party ]. The depression in the Netherlands eased off somewhat at the end of 1936, when the government finally dropped the Gold Standard, but real economic stability did not return until after World War II.<ref>E. H. Kossmann, ''The Low Countries: 1780–1940'' (1978).</ref>

===New Zealand===
{{Main|History of New Zealand#Great Depression}}
] was especially vulnerable to worldwide depression, as it relied almost entirely on agricultural exports to the United Kingdom for its economy. The drop in exports led to a lack of disposable income from the farmers, who were the mainstay of the local economy. Jobs disappeared and wages plummeted, leaving people desperate and charities unable to cope. Work relief schemes were the only government support available to the unemployed, the rate of which by the early 1930s was officially around 15%, but unofficially nearly twice that level (official figures excluded Māori and women). In 1932, riots occurred among the unemployed in three of the country's main cities (], ], and ]). Many were arrested or injured through the tough official handling of these riots by police and volunteer "special constables".<ref>" {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160307070443/http://tepapa.govt.nz/whatson/exhibitions/sliceofheaven/exhibition/socialwelfare/pages/greatdepression.aspx |date=March 7, 2016 }}", ].</ref>

=== Persia ===
{{Expand section|date=April 2024}}
In Iran, then known as the ], the Great Depression had negative impacts on its exports. In 1933 a new concession was signed with the ].<ref>{{Cite web |last=Foundation |first=Encyclopaedia Iranica |title=Welcome to Encyclopaedia Iranica |url=https://iranicaonline.org/ |access-date=17 April 2024 |website=iranicaonline.org |language=en-US}}</ref>

=== Poland ===
{{Main|Second Polish Republic#Economy}}
Poland was affected by the Great Depression longer and stronger than other countries due to inadequate economic response of the government and the pre-existing economic circumstances of the country. At that time, Poland was under the authoritarian rule of ], whose leader, ], was opposed to leaving the ] until his death in 1935. As a result, Poland was unable to perform a more active monetary and budget policy. Additionally, Poland was a relatively young country that emerged merely 10 years earlier after being partitioned between ], ] and the ] for over a century. Prior to independence, the Russian part exported 91% of its exports to Russia proper, while the German part exported 68% to Germany proper. After independence, these markets were largely lost, as Russia transformed into ] that was mostly a closed economy, and Germany was in a tariff war with Poland throughout the 1920s.<ref>{{Cite web|date=3 November 2018|title=II RP była gospodarczą porażką. Mity na jej temat są bardzo szkodliwe |url=https://forsal.pl/artykuly/1330494,ii-rp-byla-gospodarcza-porazka-mity-na-jej-temat-sa-bardzo-szkodliwe.html|access-date=29 July 2021|website=forsal.pl|language=pl|archive-date=19 October 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211019024334/https://forsal.pl/artykuly/1330494,ii-rp-byla-gospodarcza-porazka-mity-na-jej-temat-sa-bardzo-szkodliwe.html|url-status=live}}</ref>

] fell significantly: in 1932 ] production was down 27% compared to 1928, ] production was down 61%, and ] production noted an 89% decrease.<ref name=":2">{{Cite web|title=Wielki kryzys gospodarczy w Polsce|url=https://histmag.org/Wielki-kryzys-gospodarczy-w-Polsce-9980|access-date=29 July 2021|website=histmag.org|archive-date=29 July 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210729011419/https://histmag.org/Wielki-kryzys-gospodarczy-w-Polsce-9980|url-status=live}}</ref> On the other hand, electrotechnical, leather, and paper industries noted marginal increases in production output. Overall, industrial production decreased by 41%.<ref>{{Cite web|date=9 November 2020|title=Wielki kryzys w Polsce. Zbankrutowało niemal 25% firm, a produkt krajowy spadł o ponad połowę|url=https://wielkahistoria.pl/wielki-kryzys-w-polsce-zbankrutowalo-niemal-25-firm-a-produkt-krajowy-spadl-o-ponad-polowe/|access-date=29 July 2021|website=WielkaHistoria|language=pl-PL|archive-date=29 July 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210729012308/https://wielkahistoria.pl/wielki-kryzys-w-polsce-zbankrutowalo-niemal-25-firm-a-produkt-krajowy-spadl-o-ponad-polowe/|url-status=live}}</ref> A distinct feature of the Great Depression in Poland was the de-concentration of industry, as larger conglomerates were less flexible and paid their workers more than smaller ones.

] rose significantly (up to 43%) while nominal ]s fell by 51% in 1933 and 56% in 1934, relative to 1928. However, real wages fell less due to the government's policy of decreasing cost of living, particularly food expenditures (food prices were down by 65% in 1935 compared to 1928 price levels). Material conditions deprivation led to strikes, some of them violent or violently pacified – like in ] ({{Interlanguage link|Marsz Głodnych w Sanoku|lt=March of the Hungry in Sanok|pl|Marsz Głodnych w Sanoku}} 6 March 1930), ] (] 21 June – 9 July 1932) and ] ({{Interlanguage link|Krwawy piątek (1930)|lt=Bloody Friday (1930)|pl|Bloody Friday (1930)}} 18 April 1930).

To adapt to the crisis, Polish government employed deflation methods such as high ]s, credit limits and budget ] to keep a ] with currencies tied to the gold standard. Only in late 1932 did the government effect a plan to fight the economic crisis.<ref>{{Cite web|title=140 lat temu urodził się Bolesław Wieniawa-Długoszowski|url=https://dzieje.pl/wiadomosci/140-lat-temu-urodzil-sie-boleslaw-wieniawa-dlugoszowski|access-date=29 July 2021|website=dzieje.pl|language=pl|archive-date=12 August 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210812060931/https://dzieje.pl/wiadomosci/140-lat-temu-urodzil-sie-boleslaw-wieniawa-dlugoszowski|url-status=live}}</ref> Part of the plan was mass ] scheme, employing up to 100,000 people in 1935.<ref name=":2" /> After Piłsudski's death, in 1936 the gold standard regime was relaxed, and launching the development of the ] kicked off the economy, to over 10% annual growth rate in the 1936–1938 period.

===Portugal===
{{Main|Economic history of Portugal}}
Already under the rule of a dictatorial junta, the ], Portugal suffered no turbulent political effects of the Depression, although ], already appointed Minister of Finance in 1928 greatly expanded his powers and in 1932 rose to ] to found the ], an ] ] dictatorship. With the budget balanced in 1929, the effects of the depression were relaxed through harsh measures towards ] and ], causing social discontent but stability and, eventually, an impressive economic growth.<ref>José Cardozo, "The great depression and Portugal" in Michael Psalidopoulos, ed. (2012). ''The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context'' Athens: Alpha Bank, {{ISBN|978-960-99793-6-8}}. pp. 361–394 . {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170313092132/http://www.ics.ul.pt/rdonweb-docs/ICS_JLCardoso_Great_AI.pdf|date=13 March 2017}}.</ref>

===Puerto Rico===
In the years immediately preceding the depression, negative developments in the island and world economies perpetuated an unsustainable cycle of subsistence for many Puerto Rican workers. The 1920s brought a dramatic drop in Puerto Rico's two primary exports, raw sugar and coffee, due to a devastating hurricane in 1928 and the plummeting demand from global markets in the latter half of the decade. 1930 unemployment on the island was roughly 36% and by 1933 Puerto Rico's per capita income dropped 30% (by comparison, unemployment in the United States in 1930 was approximately 8% reaching a height of 25% in 1933).<ref>{{Cite book|title=A New Deal for the Tropics|last=Rodriguez|first=Manuel|publisher=Markus Wiener|year=2011|location=Princeton|page=23}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|url=https://herb.ashp.cuny.edu/items/show/1510|title=Graph of U.S. Unemployment Rate: 1930–1945|website=American Social History Project|access-date=19 April 2017|archive-date=23 January 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210123225658/https://herb.ashp.cuny.edu/items/show/1510|url-status=live}}</ref> To provide relief and economic reform, the United States government and Puerto Rican politicians such as ] and ] created and administered first the Puerto Rico Emergency Relief Administration (PRERA) 1933 and then in 1935, the ] (PRRA).<ref>{{Cite book|title=Economic History of Puerto Rico|last=Dietz|first=James|publisher=Princeton University Press|year=1986|isbn=0-691-02248-8|location=Princeton|pages=154–55|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=MeI9DwAAQBAJ|access-date=4 February 2018|archive-date=18 August 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210818032634/https://books.google.com/books?id=MeI9DwAAQBAJ|url-status=live}}</ref>

===Romania===
{{Main|Great Depression in Romania}}
Romania was also affected by the Great Depression.<ref>{{cite journal|url=https://nbs.rs/export/sites/NBS_site/documents/publikacije/konferencije/seemhn_conf/SEEMHN_14_Rumunija.pdf|title=The National Bank of Romania during the Great Depression – 1929–1933|first1=Elisabeta|last1=Blejan|first2=Brîndușa|last2=Costache|first3=Adriana|last3=Aloman|publisher=]|journal=Fourth Conference of Southeast Europe Monetary History Network (SEEMHN)|issue=8|pages=1–34|year=2009|access-date=21 March 2021|archive-date=19 November 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211119000002/https://www.nbs.rs/export/sites/NBS_site/documents/publikacije/konferencije/seemhn_conf/SEEMHN_14_Rumunija.pdf|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|url=https://www.gredeg.cnrs.fr/working-papers/GREDEG-WP-2019-43.pdf|title=Romania's unsustainable stabilization: 1929–1933|first1=Raphaël|last1=Chiappini|first2=Dominique|last2=Torre|first3=Elise|last3=Tosi|journal=GREDEG Working Papers|publisher=Groupe de Recherche en Droit, Economie, Gestion|issue=2019–43|pages=1–32|year=2009|access-date=18 February 2022|archive-date=8 July 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210708140527/http://www.gredeg.cnrs.fr/working-papers/GREDEG-WP-2019-43.pdf|url-status=live}}</ref>


===South Africa=== ===South Africa===
{{main|Great Depression in South Africa}} {{Main|Great Depression in South Africa}}
As world trade slumped, demand for South African agricultural and mineral exports fell drastically. It is believed that the social discomfort caused by the depression was a contributing factor in the 1933 split between the "gesuiwerde" (purified) and "smelter" (fusionist) factions within the ] and the National Party's subsequent fusion with the ].{{Fact|date=November 2008}} As world trade slumped, demand for South African agricultural and mineral exports fell drastically. The ] had concluded in 1931 that nearly one-third of ]s lived as paupers. The social discomfort caused by the depression was a contributing factor in the 1933 split between the "gesuiwerde" (purified) and "smelter" (fusionist) factions within the ] and the National Party's subsequent fusion with the ].<ref>Dan O'Meara, ''Volkskapitalisme: class, capital, and ideology in the development of Afrikaner nationalism, 1934–1948'' (Cambridge University Press, 1983).</ref><ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220102205937/https://www.country-studies.com/south-africa/the-great-depression-and-the-1930s.html |date=2 January 2022 }}, Federal Research Division of the Library of Congress.</ref> Unemployment programs were begun that focused primarily on the white population.<ref>{{cite journal | last1 = Minnaar | first1 = Anthony | year = 1994 | title = Unemployment and relief measures during the Great Depression (1929–1934) | journal = Kleio | volume = 26 | issue = 1| pages = 45–85 | doi = 10.1080/00232084.1994.10823193 }}</ref>


===Soviet Union=== ===Soviet Union===
The Soviet Union was the only major ] in the world and had very little international trade. Its economy was not tied to the rest of the world and was mostly unaffected by the Great Depression.<ref>Robert William Davies, Mark Harrison, and Stephen G. Wheatcroft, eds. ''The economic transformation of the Soviet Union, 1913–1945'' (Cambridge University Press, 1994)</ref>
{{main|Economy of the Soviet Union#Economic development}}

Having removed itself from the capitalist ] both by choice and as a result of efforts of the capitalist powers to isolate it, the Great Depression had little effect on the Soviet Union. This was a period of industrial expansion for the USSR as it recovered from revolution and civil war, and its apparent immunity to the Great Depression seemed to validate the theory of Marxism and contributed to ] and ] agitation in affected nations. This in turn increased fears of Communist revolution in the ], strengthening support for ], both moderate and extreme.
At the time of the Depression, the Soviet economy was growing steadily, fuelled by intensive investment in heavy industry. The apparent economic success of the Soviet Union at a time when the capitalist world was in crisis led many Western intellectuals to view the Soviet system favorably. Jennifer Burns wrote:

{{blockquote|As the Great Depression ground on and unemployment soared, intellectuals began unfavorably comparing their faltering capitalist economy to Russian Communism. Karl Marx had predicted that capitalism would fall under the weight of its own contradictions, and now with the economic crisis gripping the West, his predictions seem to be coming true. By contrast Russia seemed an emblematic modern nation, making the staggering leap from a feudal past to an industrial future with ease.<ref>Jennifer Burns (2009). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210415123811/https://books.google.com/books?id=z6e9X6JxHpMC&pg=PA34 |date=April 15, 2021 }}, p. 34. Oxford University Press. {{ISBN|0-19-532487-0}}</ref>}}

The early years of the Great Depression caused mass immigration to the Soviet Union, including 10,000 to 15,000 from Finland and thousands more from Poland, Sweden, Germany, and other nearby countries. The Kremlin was at first happy to help these immigrants settle, believing that they were victims of capitalism who had come to help the Soviet cause. However, by 1933, the worst of the Depression had come to an end in many countries, and word had been received that illegal migrants to the Soviet Union were being sent to Siberia.{{Citation needed|date=December 2024}} These factors caused immigration to the Soviet Union to slow significantly, and roughly a tenth of Finnish migrants returned to Finland, either legally or illegally.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.genealogia.fi/emi/art/article237e.htm|title=Illegal Emigration to the U.S.S.R. During the Great Depression|website=www.genealogia.fi|access-date=19 September 2016|archive-date=24 February 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210224141430/https://www.genealogia.fi/emi/art/article237e.htm|url-status=dead}}</ref>

===Spain===
{{Main|Economic history of Spain}}
Spain had a relatively isolated economy, with high protective tariffs and was not one of the main countries affected by the Depression. The banking system held up well, as did agriculture.<ref>Gabriel Tortella and Jordi Palafox, "Banking and Industry in Spain 1918–1936", ''Journal of European Economic History'' (1984), 13#2 Special Issue, pp. 81–110.</ref>

By far the most serious negative impact came after 1936 from the heavy destruction of infrastructure and manpower by the ]. Many talented workers were forced into permanent exile. By staying neutral in the Second World War, and selling to both sides{{clarify|date=March 2020}}, the economy avoided further disasters.<ref>R. J. Harrison, ''Economic History of Modern Spain'' (1978), pp. 129–149.</ref>

===Sweden===
{{Main|Economy of Sweden}}
By the 1930s, Sweden had what America's '']'' called in 1938 the "world's highest standard of living". Sweden was also the first country worldwide to recover completely from the Great Depression. Taking place amid a short-lived government and a less-than-a-decade old Swedish democracy, events such as those surrounding ] (who eventually committed suicide) remain infamous in Swedish history. The ] under ] formed their first long-lived government in 1932 based on strong ] and ] policies, monopolizing the office of ] until 1976 with the sole and short-lived exception of ]'s "summer cabinet" in 1936. During forty years of hegemony, it was the most successful political party in the history of Western liberal democracy.<ref>], "A Unique Chapter in the History of Democracy: The Swedish Social Democrats", in K. Misgeld et al. (eds), ''Creating Social Democracy'', University Park, Penn State University Press, 1996.</ref>

===Thailand===
In Thailand, then known as the ], the Great Depression contributed to the end of the ] in the ].<ref>{{cite book |last=Handley |first=Paul M. |title=The King Never Smiles: A Biography of Thailand's Bhumibol Adulyadej |publisher=Yale University Press |year=2006 |location=New Haven and London|page=37 }}</ref>

=== Turkey ===
{{Expand section|date=April 2024}}
Turkey was badly affected by the Great Depression and it came at a time when the state was still reforming its economic policy following the end of the ] era. Exports of grapes, which held an important share, were down considerably which had already started beforehand due to drought.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Yankın |first=Yeşim Ertem |date=2018 |title=THE EFFECT OF THE GREAT DEPRESSION OVER AEGEAN GRAPES (REPERCUSSIONS) |url=https://journals.indexcopernicus.com/search/article?articleId=2267876 |journal=Journal of Atatürk and the History of Turkish Republic |volume=1 |issue=3 |pages=147-160}}</ref>


===United Kingdom=== ===United Kingdom===
{{main|Great Depression in the United Kingdom}} {{Main|Great Depression in the United Kingdom|Interwar Britain}}
]
The world depression broke at a time when the United Kingdom had still not fully recovered from the effects of the ] more than a decade earlier. The country was driven off the ] in 1931.

The world financial crisis began to overwhelm Britain in 1931; investors around the world started withdrawing their gold from London at the rate of £2.5&nbsp;million per day.<ref name="David Williams 1963"/> Credits of £25&nbsp;million each from the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and an issue of £15&nbsp;million fiduciary note slowed, but did not reverse the British crisis. The financial crisis now caused a major political crisis in Britain in August 1931. With deficits mounting, the bankers demanded a balanced budget; the divided cabinet of Prime Minister Ramsay MacDonald's Labour government agreed; it proposed to raise taxes, cut spending and most controversially, to cut unemployment benefits by 20%. The attack on welfare was totally unacceptable to the Labour movement. MacDonald wanted to resign, but King George V insisted he remain and form an all-party coalition "]". The Conservative and Liberals parties signed on, along with a small cadre of Labour, but the vast majority of Labour leaders denounced MacDonald as a traitor for leading the new government. Britain went off the gold standard, and suffered relatively less than other major countries in the Great Depression. In the 1931 British election, the Labour Party was virtually destroyed, leaving MacDonald as prime minister for a largely Conservative coalition.<ref>Charles Loch Mowat, ''Britain between the wars, 1918–1940'' (1955) pp. 386–412.</ref><ref name="John Oxborrow 1976 pp. 67-73"/>

The effects on the northern industrial areas of Britain were immediate and devastating, as demand for traditional industrial products collapsed. By the end of 1930 unemployment had more than doubled from 1&nbsp;million to 2.5&nbsp;million (20% of the insured workforce), and exports had fallen in value by 50%. In 1933, 30% of ] were unemployed due to the severe decline in heavy industry. In some towns and cities in the north east, unemployment reached as high as 70% as shipbuilding fell by 90%.<ref> {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090124124118/https://thegreatdepression.co.uk/unemployment-during-the-great-depression |date=24 January 2009 }}, thegreatdepression.co.uk</ref> The ] of September–October 1932 was the largest<ref>Cook, Chris and Bewes, Diccon; ''What Happened Where: A Guide To Places And Events In Twentieth-Century History'' p. 115; Routledge, 1997 {{ISBN|1-85728-533-6}}</ref> of a series of ] in Britain in the 1920s and 1930s. About 200,000 unemployed men were sent to the work camps, which continued in operation until 1939.<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220106193754/http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/uk_news/scotland/7842448.stm |date=6 January 2022 }}, BBC News.</ref>

In the less industrial ] and ], the effects were short-lived and the later 1930s were a prosperous time. Growth in modern manufacture of electrical goods and a boom in the motor car industry was helped by a growing southern population and an expanding ]. Agriculture also saw a boom during this period.<ref name="Social Conditions in Britain 1918–1939">] (1983), ''Social Conditions in Britain 1918–1939'', {{ISBN|0-416-36010-6}}</ref>


===United States=== ===United States===
{{main|Great Depression in the United States}} {{Main|Great Depression in the United States|The New Deal}}
]
====Early response====
] ] advised ] that ] would be the best response: "Liquidate labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate the farmers, liquidate ].... That will purge the rottenness out of the system. High costs of living and high living will come down. People will work harder, live a more moral life. Values will be adjusted, and enterprising people will pick up the wrecks from less competent people."<ref>{{cite book|author=Hoover, Herbert|title=The memoirs of Herbert Hoover|chapter=3:9}}</ref> Hoover rejected this advice, and started numerous programs, all of which failed to reverse the downturn.<Ref> Waren, ''Herbert Hoover and the Great Depression''</ref>


Hoover's first measures to combat the depression were based on encouraging businesses not to reduce their workforce or cut wages but businesses had little choice: wages were reduced, workers were laid off, and investments postponed.<ref name="Peter Clemens 1954, p. 114">Peter Clemens, ''Prosperity, Depression and the New Deal: The USA 1890–1954'', Hodder Education, 4. Auflage, 2008, {{ISBN|978-0-340-96588-7}}, p. 114.</ref><ref>Charles R. Morris, ''A Rabble of Dead Money: The Great Crash and the Global Depression: 1929–1939'' (PublicAffairs, 2017), 389 pp. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170424184720/https://www.nytimes.com/2017/04/21/books/review/rabble-of-dead-money-charles-r-morris-great-depression-wall-street.html |date=24 April 2017 }}</ref>
Hoover launched a series of programs to increase farm prices, which failed, expanded federal spending in public works such as dams, and launched the ] (RFC) which aided cities, banks and railroads, and continued as a major agency under the New Deal. To provide unemployment relief he set up the Emergency Relief Agency (ERA) that operated until 1935 as the Federal Emergency Relief Agency. Quarter by quarter the economy went downhill, as prices, profits and employment fell, leading to the political realignment in 1932 that brought to power the ].


In June 1930, Congress approved the ] which raised tariffs on thousands of imported items. The intent of the Act was to encourage the purchase of American-made products by increasing the cost of imported goods, while raising revenue for the federal government and protecting farmers. Most countries that traded with the U.S. increased tariffs on American-made goods in retaliation, reducing international trade, and worsening the Depression.<ref> {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090312055958/https://future.state.gov/when/timeline/1921_timeline/smoot_tariff.html |date=12 March 2009 }}, ''U.S. Department of State''.</ref>
====The New Deal====
{{Main|New Deal}}
Shortly after President Roosevelt was inaugurated in 1933, drought and erosion combined to cause the ], shifting hundreds of thousands of ] off their farms in the midwest. From his inauguration onward, Roosevelt argued that restructuring of the economy would be needed to prevent another depression or avoid prolonging the current one. New Deal programs sought to stimulate ] and provide work and relief for the impoverished through increased government spending and institute financial reforms. The ] comprehensively regulated the securities industry. This was followed by the ] which created the ]. Though amended, key provisions of both Acts are still in force. Federal insurance of ] was provided by the ], and the ]. The institution of the ] (NRA) remains a controversial act to this day. The NRA made a number of sweeping changes to the American economy until it ] by the ] in 1935.


In 1931, Hoover urged bankers to set up the ]<ref>{{cite encyclopedia|url=https://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/butkiewicz.finance.corp.reconstruction |title=Reconstruction Finance Corporation|encyclopedia=EH.net Encyclopedia|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20131029205418/https://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/butkiewicz.finance.corp.reconstruction |archive-date=29 October 2013 }}</ref> so that big banks could help failing banks survive. But bankers were reluctant to invest in failing banks, and the National Credit Corporation did almost nothing to address the problem.<ref>Clemens, ''Prosperity, Depression and the New Deal'', 2008, p. 113.</ref>
Early changes by the Roosevelt administration included:
* Instituting regulations to fight deflationary "cut-throat competition" through the NRA.
* Setting minimum prices and ], labor standards, and competitive conditions in all industries through the NRA.
* Encouraging unions that would raise wages, to increase the ] of the ].
* Cutting farm production to raise prices through the ] and its successors.
* Forcing businesses to work with government to set price codes through the NRA.


] (World War I veterans) after the marchers with their wives and children were driven out by the regular Army by order of ], 1932<ref>, The Eleanor Roosevelt Papers. {{webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081223191011/https://www.nps.gov/archive/elro/glossary/great-depression.htm |date=23 December 2008 }}</ref>]]
These reforms, together with several other relief and recovery measures are called the ]. New regulations and attempts at economic stimulus through a new ] set up in 1933 and 1934 and previously extant agencies such as the ] did not halt economic stagnation.{{Fact|date=December 2008}} By 1935, the "]" added ], a national ] (the ], WPA) and, through the ], a strong stimulus to the growth of labor unions. Unemployment declined by over one-third in Roosevelt's first term (from 25% to 14.3%, 1933 to 1937), but faster than the economic upturn came 1938's "recession within a depression" and unemployment zoomed to 19%, then declined somewhat until the ] to fight ] lowered it more. In 1929, federal expenditures constituted only 3% of the ]. Expenditures as a proportion of GDP tripled{{Fact|date=September 2008}} between 1933 and 1939, accompanied by sizable deficits.{{Fact|date=September 2008}} The debt as a proportion of GNP rose under Hoover from 20% to 40%. Roosevelt kept it at 40% until the war began, when it soared to 128%. After the ], conservatives were able to form a bipartisan ] to stop further expansion of the New Deal and, by 1943, had abolished all of the relief programs. In 1946, large-scale relaxation of government controls{{Fact|date=September 2008}} over the wartime economy, including a sharp reduction of taxes, allowed for increased innovation in consumer goods and a marked increase in consumer spending. Unemployment rates also returned to normal levels.{{Fact|date=September 2008}}
By 1932, unemployment had reached 23.6%, peaking in early 1933 at 25%.<ref>{{cite journal |last1= Swanson |first1= Joseph | last2 = Williamson |first2= Samuel |year= 1972 |title = Estimates of national product and income for the United States economy, 1919–1941 |journal= Explorations in Economic History |volume= 10 |issue= 1 |pages= 53–73 |doi = 10.1016/0014-4983(72)90003-4 }}</ref> Those released from prison during this period had an especially difficult time finding employment given the stigma of their criminal records, which often led to recidivism out of economic desperation.<ref name="PDN2"/> Drought persisted in the agricultural heartland, businesses and families defaulted on record numbers of loans, and more than 5,000 banks had failed.<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20091028014002/http://encarta.msn.com/encyclopedia_761584403/Great_Depression_in_the_United_States.html |date=28 October 2009 }}, ''Microsoft Encarta''. 31 October 2009.</ref> Hundreds of thousands of Americans found themselves homeless, and began congregating in ]s – dubbed "]s" – that began to appear across the country.<ref>Joyce Bryant, {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160721191938/http://www.yale.edu/ynhti/curriculum/units/1998/4/98.04.04.x.html |date=21 July 2016 }}, ''Yale-New Haven Teachers Institute''.</ref> In response, President Hoover and Congress approved the ], to spur new home construction, and reduce foreclosures. The final attempt of the Hoover Administration to stimulate the economy was the passage of the ] (ERA) which included funds for ] programs such as dams and the creation of the ] (RFC) in 1932. The Reconstruction Finance Corporation was a Federal agency with the authority to lend up to $2&nbsp;billion to rescue banks and restore confidence in financial institutions. But $2&nbsp;billion was not enough to save all the banks, and ]s and bank failures continued.<ref name="Peter Clemens 1954, p. 114"/> Quarter by quarter the economy went downhill, as prices, profits and employment fell, leading to the ] in 1932 that brought to power ].


], May 1936. The ] on the Great Plains coincided with the Great Depression.<ref>, Geoff Cunfer, Southwest Minnesota State University. {{webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081228070418/https://eh.net/encyclopedia/article/Cunfer.DustBowl |date=28 December 2008 }}</ref>]]
====Recession of 1937====
{{Main|Recession of 1937}}
In 1937 the American economy took an unexpected nosedive, lasting through most of 1938. Production declined sharply, as did profits and employment. Unemployment jumped from 14.3% in 1937 to 19.0% in 1938. The Roosevelt administration reacted by launching a rhetorical campaign against ], which was cast as the cause of the depression, and by appointing ] to act; Arnold's effectiveness ended once ] began and corporate energies had to be directed to winning the war.


Shortly after President ] was inaugurated in 1933, drought and erosion combined to cause the ], shifting hundreds of thousands of ] off their farms in the Midwest. From his inauguration onward, Roosevelt argued that restructuring of the economy would be needed to prevent another depression or avoid prolonging the current one. New Deal programs sought to stimulate ] and provide work and relief for the impoverished through increased government spending and the institution of financial reforms.
The administration's other response to the 1937 deepening of the Great Depression had more tangible results. Ignoring the pleas of the ], Roosevelt embarked on an antidote to the depression, reluctantly abandoning his efforts to balance the budget and launching a $5 billion spending program in the spring of 1938, an effort to increase mass purchasing power. Business-oriented observers explained the recession and recovery in very different terms from the Keynesians. They argued that the New Deal had been very hostile to business expansion in 1935–37, had encouraged massive strikes which had a negative impact on major industries such as automobiles, and had threatened massive antitrust legal attacks on big corporations. All those threats diminished sharply after 1938. For example, the antitrust efforts fizzled out without major cases. The CIO and AFL unions started battling each other more than with the corporations, and ] became more favorable to long-term growth, according to this argument.


During a "bank holiday" that lasted five days, the ] was signed into law. It provided for a system of reopening sound banks under ] supervision, with federal loans available if needed. The ] comprehensively regulated the securities industry. This was followed by the ] which created the ]. Although amended, key provisions of both Acts are still in force. Federal insurance of ] was provided by the ], and the ].
On the other hand, according to economist ], when looking only at the supply of consumer goods, significant ] resumed only in 1946 (Higgs does not estimate the value to consumers of collective, intangible goods like victory in war). To Keynesians, the ] showed just how large the fiscal stimulus required to end the downturn of the Depression was, and it led, at the time, to fears that as soon as America demobilized, it would return to Depression conditions, and industrial output would fall to pre-war levels. That incorrect Keynesian prediction that a new depression would start after the war failed to take into account massive savings and pent-up consumer demand, along with the ending of the restrictive wartime regulations in most consumer industries, and the cutting of high tax rates starting in 1946. In any case, government spending and changing regulations (first tightening them, then loosening them) appear to have contributed to the recovery, as consumer and producer behavior changed.


The ] provided incentives to cut farm production in order to raise farming prices. The ] (NRA) made a number of sweeping changes to the American economy. It forced businesses to work with government to set price codes through the NRA to fight ]ary "cut-throat competition" by the setting of minimum prices and ], labor standards, and competitive conditions in all industries. It encouraged unions that would raise wages, to increase the ] of the ]. The NRA ] by the ] in 1935.
==Keynesian models==
In the early 1930s, before ] wrote ], he was advocating ] programs and deficits as a way to get the British economy out of the Depression. Although Keynes never mentions fiscal policy in ''The General Theory'', and instead advocates the need to socialize investments, Keynes ushered in more of a theoretical revolution than a policy one. His basic idea was simple: to keep people fully employed, governments have to run deficits when the economy is slowing because the private sector will not invest enough to increase production and reverse the recession.


] workers constructing drainage culvert, 1933. Over 3 million unemployed young men were taken out of the cities and placed into 2,600+ work camps managed by the CCC.<ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.nationalparkstraveler.com/2008/09/park-history-spirit-civilian-conservation-corps |title=National Park History: "The Spirit of the Civilian Conservation Corps" |publisher=Nationalparkstraveler.com |access-date=4 September 2010 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100905182850/https://www.nationalparkstraveler.com/2008/09/park-history-spirit-civilian-conservation-corps |archive-date=5 September 2010 |url-status=dead }}</ref>]]
As the Depression wore on, Roosevelt tried public works, ], and other devices to restart the economy, but never completely gave up trying to balance the budget. According to the Keynesians, he needed to spend much more money; they were unable to say how much more. With ], however, government could provide the needed Keynesian spending by decreasing taxes, increasing government spending, and increasing individuals' incomes. As incomes increased, they would spend more. As they spent more, the ] would take over and expand the effect on the initial spending. The Keynesians did not estimate what the size of the multiplier was. Keynesian economists assumed poor people would spend new incomes; however, they saved much of the new money; that is, they paid back debts owed to landlords, grocers and family {{Fact|date=September 2008}}, which might have then spent the money. Keynesian ideas of the ] have been challenged, most notably in the 1950s by ] and ].
These reforms, together with several other relief and recovery measures, are called the ]. Economic stimulus was attempted through a new ] set up in 1933 and 1934 and previously extant agencies such as the ]. By 1935, the "]" added ] (which was later considerably extended through the ]), a jobs program for the unemployed (the ], WPA) and, through the ], a strong stimulus to the growth of labor unions. In 1929, federal expenditures constituted only 3% of the ]. The national debt as a proportion of GNP rose under Hoover from 20% to 40%. Roosevelt kept it at 40% until the war began, when it soared to 128%.


By 1936, the main ]s had regained the levels of the late 1920s, except for unemployment, which remained high at 11%, although this was considerably lower than the 25% unemployment rate seen in 1933. In the spring of 1937, American industrial production exceeded that of 1929 and remained level until June 1937. In June 1937, the Roosevelt administration cut spending and increased taxation in an attempt to balance the federal budget.<ref>Robert Goldston, ''The Great Depression'', Fawcett Publications, 1968, p. 228.</ref>
== Neoclassical approach ==
The American economy then took a sharp downturn, lasting for 13 months through most of 1938. Industrial production fell almost 30 per cent within a few months and production of ]s fell even faster. Unemployment jumped from 14.3% in 1937 to 19.0% in 1938, rising from 5&nbsp;million to more than 12&nbsp;million in early 1938.<ref>''Economic Fluctuations'', Maurice W. Lee, Chairman of Economics Dept., Washington State College, published by R.D. Irwin Inc, Homewood, Illinois, 1955, p. 236.</ref> Manufacturing output fell by 37% from the 1937 peak and was back to 1934 levels.<ref>''Business Cycles'', James Arthur Estey, Purdue University, Prentice-Hall, 1950, pp. 22–23 chart.</ref>
Recent work from a neoclassical perspective focuses on the decline in productivity that caused the initial decline in output and a prolonged recovery due to policies that affected the labor market. This work, collected by Kehoe and Prescott,<ref>{{cite book|author=Kehoe, Timothy J.; Prescott, Edward C.|title=Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century|publisher=]|year=2007}}</ref> decomposes the economic decline into a decline in the labor force, capital stock, and the productivity with which these inputs are used. This study suggests that theories of the Great Depression have to explain an initial severe decline but rapid recovery in productivity, relatively little change in the capital stock, and a prolonged depression in the labor force. This analysis rejects theories that focus on the role of savings and posit a decline in the capital stock.


] employed 2–3 million at unskilled labor.]]
==Gold standard==
Every major currency left the ] during the Great Depression. Great Britain was the first to do so. Facing speculative attacks on the ] and depleting gold reserves, in September 1931 the ] ceased exchanging pound notes for gold and the pound was floated on foreign exchange markets.


Producers reduced their expenditures on durable goods, and inventories declined, but personal income was only 15% lower than it had been at the peak in 1937. As unemployment rose, consumers' expenditures declined, leading to further cutbacks in production. By May 1938 retail sales began to increase, employment improved, and industrial production turned up after June 1938.<ref>Maurice W. Lee, 1955.</ref> After the recovery from the Recession of 1937–38, conservatives were able to form a bipartisan ] to stop further expansion of the New Deal and, when unemployment dropped to 2% in the early 1940s, they abolished WPA, CCC and the PWA relief programs. Social Security remained in place.
Great Britain, Japan, and the Scandinavian countries left the gold standard in 1931. Other countries, such as Italy and the United States, remained on the gold standard into 1932 or 1933, while a few countries in the so-called "gold bloc", led by France and including Poland, Belgium and Switzerland, stayed on the standard until 1935-1936.


Between 1933 and 1939, federal expenditure tripled, and Roosevelt's critics charged that he was turning America into a ] state.<ref>Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. ''The Coming of the New Deal: 1933–1935.'' Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003 . {{ISBN|0-618-34086-6}}; Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. ''The Politics of Upheaval: 1935–1936.'' Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003 . {{ISBN|0-618-34087-4}}</ref> The Great Depression was a main factor in the implementation of ] and ] in European countries after World War II (see ]). ] generally remained the most influential economic school in the United States and in parts of Europe until the periods between the 1970s and the 1980s, when ] and other ] economists formulated and propagated the newly created theories of ] and incorporated them into the ] as an alternative approach to the study of economics. Neoliberalism went on to challenge the dominance of the Keynesian school of Economics in the mainstream academia and policy-making in the United States, having reached its peak in popularity in the election of the presidency of ] in the United States, and ] in the ].<ref>], ''Milton Friedman: A Biography'' (2007).</ref>
According to later analysis, the earliness with which a country left the gold standard reliably predicted its economic recovery. For example, Great Britain and Scandinavia, which left the gold standard in 1931, recovered much earlier than France and Belgium, which remained on gold much longer. Countries such as China, which had a ], almost avoided the depression entirely. The connection between leaving the gold standard as a strong predictor of that country's severity of its depression and the length of time of its recovery has been shown to be consistent for dozens of countries, including developing countries. This partly explains why the experience and length of the depression differed between national economies.<ref>{{citation |last=Bernanke |first=Ben |date=March 2, 2004 |title=Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke: Money, Gold and the Great Depression |journal=At the H. Parker Willis Lecture in Economic Policy, Washington and Lee University, Lexington, Virginia |url=http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/200403022/default.htm}}</ref>


==Literature==
==Rearmament and recovery==
{{Quote box|quote=And the great owners, who must lose their land in an upheaval, the great owners with access to history, with eyes to read history and to know the great fact: when property accumulates in too few hands it is taken away. And that companion fact: when a majority of the people are hungry and cold they will take by force what they need. And the little screaming fact that sounds through all history: repression works only to strengthen and knit the repressed.|width=40%|source=–John Steinbeck, ''The Grapes of Wrath''<ref>'']'', by ], Penguin, 2006, 0143039431, p. 238</ref>}}
The massive rearmament policies to counter the threat from ] helped stimulate the economies of Europe in 1937-39. By 1937, unemployment in Britain had fallen to 1.5 million. The mobilization of manpower following the outbreak of war in 1939 finally ended unemployment.


The Great Depression has been the subject of much writing, as authors have sought to evaluate an era that caused both financial and emotional trauma. Perhaps the most noteworthy and famous novel written on the subject is '']'', published in 1939 and written by ], who was awarded the ] for the work, and in 1962 was awarded the ] for literature. The novel focuses on a poor family of sharecroppers who are forced from their home as drought, economic hardship, and changes in the ] occur during the Great Depression. Steinbeck's '']'' is another important novella about a journey during the Great Depression. Additionally, Harper Lee's '']'' is set during the Great Depression. Margaret Atwood's Booker prize-winning '']'' is likewise set in the Great Depression, centering on a privileged socialite's love affair with a Marxist revolutionary. The era spurred the resurgence of social realism, practiced by many who started their writing careers on relief programs, especially the ] in the U.S.<ref>David Taylor, ''Soul of a People: The WPA Writers' Project Uncovers Depression America'' (2009).</ref><ref>Jerre Mangione, ''The Dream and the Deal: The Federal Writers' Project, 1935–1943'' (1996)</ref><ref>Jerrold Hirsch, ''Portrait of America: A Cultural History of the Federal Writers' Project'' (2006)</ref><ref>Stacy I. Morgan, ''Rethinking Social Realism: African American art and literature, 1930–1953 '' (2004), p. 244.</ref> Nonfiction works from this time also capture important themes. The 1933 memoir ''Prison Days and Nights'' by ] provides insight into criminal justice ramifications of the Great Depression, especially in regard to patterns of recidivism due to lack of economic opportunity.<ref name="PDN2">''Prison Days and Nights'', by Victor F. Nelson (New York: Garden City Publishing Co., Inc., 1936)</ref>
In the United States, the massive war spending doubled the ], either masking the effects of the Depression or essentially ending the Depression. Businessmen ignored the mounting ] and heavy new taxes, redoubling their efforts for greater output to take advantage of ]. Productivity soared: most people worked ] and gave up leisure activities to make money after so many hard years. People accepted ] and ] for the first time as a way of expressing their support for the ]. ] in munitions contracts guaranteed businesses a profit no matter how many mediocre workers they employed or how inefficient the techniques they used. The demand was for a vast quantity of war supplies as soon as possible, regardless of cost. Businesses hired every person in sight, even driving sound trucks up and down city streets begging people to apply for jobs. New workers were needed to replace the 11 million working-age men serving in the military. These events magnified the role of the federal government in the national economy. In 1929, federal expenditures accounted for only 3% of GNP. Between 1933 and 1939, federal expenditure tripled, and Roosevelt's critics charged that he was turning America into a ] state.<ref>Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. ''The Coming of the New Deal: 1933-1935.'' Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003. (First published in 1958) ISBN 0618340866; Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. ''The Politics of Upheaval: 1935-1936.'' Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003. (First published in 1960) ISBN 0618340874</ref> However, spending on the New Deal was far smaller than on the war effort.


A number of works for younger audiences are also set during the Great Depression, among them the ] series of '']'' books written by ] and illustrated by ], released to tie in with the dolls and playsets sold by the company. The stories, which take place during the early to mid 1930s in ], focuses on the changes brought by the Depression to the titular character's family and how the Kittredges dealt with it.<ref name="Communications2000">{{cite book|last=Harry|first=Lou|title=Cincinnati Magazine|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=2O0CAAAAMBAJ&pg=PA59|access-date=10 July 2017|date=1 October 2010|publisher=Emmis Communications|pages=59–63|archive-date=15 April 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210415123527/https://books.google.com/books?id=2O0CAAAAMBAJ&pg=PA59|url-status=live}}</ref> A theatrical adaptation of the series entitled '']'' was later released in 2008 to positive reviews.<ref name="Morency">{{cite book|last=Morency|first=Philip|title=On the Aisle, Volume 2: Film Reviews by Philip Morency|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=AGyM0Bhsr-QC&pg=PA133|publisher=Dorrance Publishing|isbn=978-1-4349-7709-0|pages=133–|access-date=22 August 2017|archive-date=17 August 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210817050620/https://books.google.com/books?id=AGyM0Bhsr-QC&pg=PA133|url-status=live}}</ref><ref name="Pimpare2017">{{cite book|last=Pimpare|first=Stephen|title=Ghettos, Tramps, and Welfare Queens: Down and Out on the Silver Screen|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=SCrADgAAQBAJ&pg=PA216|access-date=10 July 2017|year=2017|publisher=Oxford University Press|isbn=978-0-19-066072-7|pages=216–|archive-date=15 April 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210415123813/https://books.google.com/books?id=SCrADgAAQBAJ&pg=PA216|url-status=live}}</ref> Similarly, ''Christmas After All'', part of the '']'' series of books for older girls, take place in 1930s ]; while ''Kit Kittredge'' is told in a third-person viewpoint, ''Christmas After All'' is in the form of a fictional journal as told by the protagonist Minnie Swift as she recounts her experiences during the era, especially when her family takes in an orphan cousin from Texas.<ref name="Smith2006">{{cite book|last=Smith|first=Robert W.|title=Spotlight on America: The Great Depression|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=lZhrdFflrzEC|access-date=10 July 2017|date=26 January 2006|publisher=Teacher Created Resources|isbn=978-1-4206-3218-7|archive-date=15 April 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210415134347/https://books.google.com/books?id=lZhrdFflrzEC|url-status=live}}</ref>
==Political consequences==
The crisis had many political consequences, among which was the abandonment of classic ] approaches, which Roosevelt replaced in the United States with Keynesian policies. It was a main factor in the implementation of ] and ] in European countries after ]. (see ]). Although ] had challenged Keynesianism since the 1920s, it was not until 1974, when the ] was awarded to ] notably for being ''"one of the few economists who gave warning of the possibility of a major economic crisis before the great crash came in the autumn of 1929"'',<ref></ref> and the beginning of ], that the Keynesian approach was politically questioned, leading the way to ].{{Fact|date=February 2007}}


==Naming==
== Facts and figures ==
{{Further|Economic depression}}
Effects of depression in the United States<ref>http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/business/7655472.stm</ref>:
*13 million people became unemployed.
*Industrial production fell by nearly 45% between the years 1929 and 1932.
*Home-building dropped by 80% between the years 1929 and 1932.
*From the years 1929 to 1932, about 5,000 banks went out of business.


The term "The Great Depression" is most frequently attributed to British economist ], whose 1934 book ''The Great Depression'' is credited with formalizing the phrase,<ref name="hnn">{{cite web|url=https://hnn.us/articles/61931.html|title=When Did the Great Depression Receive Its Name? (And Who Named It?) – History News Network|website=hnn.us|access-date=18 February 2022|archive-date=9 January 2022|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220109204651/http://hnn.us/articles/61931.html|url-status=live}}</ref> though Hoover is widely credited with popularizing the term,<ref name="hnn"/><ref>William Manchester, ''The Glory and the Dream: A Narrative History of America, 1932–1972''.</ref> informally referring to the downturn as a depression, with such uses as "Economic depression cannot be cured by legislative action or executive pronouncement" (December 1930, Message to Congress), and "I need not recount to you that the world is passing through a great depression" (1931).
== Other great depressions ==

There have been other downturns called a "Great Depression," but none has been as worldwide for so long. British economic historians use the term "Great depression" to describe British conditions in the late 19th century, especially in agriculture, 1873-1896, a period also referred to as the ].<ref> T. W. Fletcher, "The Great Depression of English Agriculture 1873-1896," ''The Economic History Review,'' Vol. 13, No. 3 (1961), pp. 417-432 </ref> Several Latin American countries had severe downturns in the 1980s. Finnish economists refer to the ] around the breakup of the Soviet Union (1989-1994) as a great depression. Kehoe and Prescott define a great depression to be a period of diminished economic output with at least one year where output is 20% below the trend. By this definition ], ], ], and ] experienced great depressions in the 1980s, and Argentina experienced ] in 1998-2002. This definition also includes the economic performance of ] from 1974-1992 and ] from 1973 to the present, although this designation for Switzerland has been controversial.<ref>{{cite journal|author=Abrahamsen Y, R.; Aeppli, E.; Atukeren, M.; Graff, C.; Müller; Schips, B.|title=The Swiss disease: Facts and artefacts. A reply to Kehoe and Prescott|journal=]|volume=8|year=2005|issue=3|pages=749–758|doi=10.1016/j.red.2004.06.003}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|author=Kehoe, T. J.; Ruhl, K. J.|year=2005|title=Is Switzerland in a Great Depression?|publisher=]|volume=8|pages=759–775}}</ref>
] and ] followed.]]
The term "]" to refer to an economic downturn dates to the 19th century, when it was used by varied Americans and British politicians and economists. The first major American economic crisis, the ], was described by then-president ] as "a depression",<ref name="hnn"/> and the most recent economic crisis, the ], had been referred to as a "depression" by then-president ].

Financial crises were traditionally referred to as "panics", most recently the major ], and the minor ], though the 1929 crisis was called "The Crash", and the term "panic" has since fallen out of use. At the time of the Great Depression, the term "The Great Depression" was already used to refer to the period 1873–96 (in the United Kingdom), or more narrowly 1873–79 (in the United States), which has retroactively been renamed the ].<ref>{{Cite journal|first=T.W.|last=Fletcher|title=The Great Depression of English Agriculture 1873–1896|journal=The Economic History Review|volume=13|issue=3|year=1961|pages= 417–32|doi=10.2307/2599512|publisher=Blackwell Publishing|jstor=2599512}}</ref>

===Other "great depressions"===
The ], and the breakdown of economic ties which followed, led to a severe economic crisis and catastrophic fall in the ] in the 1990s in ] and the former ],<ref>, BBC News, 11 October 2000.</ref><ref>{{Cite news |date=2 July 2020 |title=The wild decade: how the 1990s laid the foundations for Vladimir Putin's Russia |url=https://theconversation.com/the-wild-decade-how-the-1990s-laid-the-foundations-for-vladimir-putins-russia-141098 |access-date=2024-09-16 |work=The Conversation}}</ref> which was even worse than the Great Depression.<ref>See "What Can Transition Economies Learn from the First Ten Years? A New World Bank Report," in ''Transition Newsletter'' {{Webarchive|url=https://archive.today/20120530044004/http://worldbank.org/transitionnewsletter/janfeb2002 |date=30 May 2012 }}, </ref><ref name=Russia>, New York Times, 8 October 2000.</ref> Even before Russia's ] of 1998, Russia's GDP was half of what it had been in the early 1990s.<ref name=Russia/>

==Comparison with the Great Recession==
{{Main|Comparisons between the Great Recession and the Great Depression}}
The ] has been compared to the 1930s.<ref>Adam Tooze, ''Crashed: How a Decade of Financial Crises Changed the World'' (2018), p. 41.</ref><ref>{{Cite news|url=https://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/03/11/great-recession-a-brief-etymology/|title='Great Recession': A Brief Etymology|work=]|date=11 March 2009|first=Catherine|last=Rampell|access-date=9 March 2017|archive-date=19 October 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211019025802/https://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/03/11/great-recession-a-brief-etymology/|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite magazine |url=https://www.time.com/time/nation/article/0,8599,1891527,00.html |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090417050440/https://www.time.com/time/nation/article/0,8599,1891527,00.html |url-status=dead |archive-date=17 April 2009 |magazine=] |date=15 April 2009|title=The Great Recession: America Becomes Thrift Nation|first= Nancy |last=Gibbs }}</ref><ref>{{Cite news|url= https://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/03/20/the-great-recession-versus-the-great-depression/|title= The Great Recession versus the Great Depression|work= ]|first= Paul|last= Krugman|author-link= Paul Krugman|date= 20 March 2009|access-date= 7 February 2017|archive-date= 25 February 2021|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20210225054220/https://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/03/20/the-great-recession-versus-the-great-depression/|url-status= live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite news|url=https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB124874235091485463|work=]|date=28 July 2009|first=Justin|last=Lahart|title=The Great Recession: A Downturn Sized Up|access-date=3 August 2017|archive-date=15 April 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210415102158/https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB124874235091485463|url-status=live}}</ref>

The ] seem similar to the Great Depression, but significant differences exist. The then-chairman of the ], ], had extensively studied the Great Depression as part of his doctoral work at MIT, and implemented policies to manipulate the money supply and interest rates in ways that were not done in the 1930s. Bernanke's policies will undoubtedly be analyzed and scrutinized in the years to come, as economists debate the wisdom of his choices. In 2011, one journalist contrasted the Great Depression of the 1930s as opposed to the ].<ref>Rabinowitz, Marco (6 October 2011). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20111017025810/https://money.msn.com/top-stocks/post.aspx?post=c72333da-0a10-4f49-8007-3c32f545fea5 |date=17 October 2011 }}: A look at the value of the U.S. dollar in 1929 and 2008; what has changed and where that leaves us today". ]. Benzinga.</ref>

{{blockquote|<poem>If we contrast the 1930s with the Crash of 2008 where gold went through the roof, it is clear that the U.S. dollar on the gold standard was a completely different animal in comparison to the fiat free-floating U.S. dollar currency we have today. Both currencies in 1929 and 2008 were the U.S. dollar, but analogously it is as if one was a ] and the other is a ]; they are two completely different animals. Where we have experienced inflation since the Crash of 2008, the situation was much different in the 1930s when deflation set in. Unlike the deflation of the early 1930s, the U.S. economy currently appears to be in a "]", or a situation where monetary policy is unable to stimulate an economy back to health.

In terms of the stock market, nearly three years after the 1929 crash, the ] dropped 8.4% on 12 August 1932. Where we have experienced great volatility with large intraday swings in the past two months, in 2011, we have not experienced any record-shattering daily percentage drops to the tune of the 1930s. Where many of us may have that '30s feeling, in light of the DJIA, the CPI, and the national unemployment rate, we are simply not living in the '30s. Some individuals may feel as if we are living in a depression, but for many others the current ] simply does not feel like a depression akin to the 1930s.</poem>}}

1928 and 1929 were the times in the 20th century that the ] reached such skewed extremes;<ref>Evans-Pritchard, Ambrose (14 September 2010). . '']'' (London). "America and Europe face the worst jobs crisis since the 1930s and risk 'an explosion of social unrest' unless they tread carefully, the International Monetary Fund has warned."</ref> half the unemployed had been out of work for over six months, something that was not repeated until the late-2000s recession. 2007 and 2008 eventually saw the world reach new levels of wealth gap inequality that rivalled the years of 1928 and 1929.


==See also== ==See also==
{{portal|Economy|1920s|1930s}}
{{multicol}}
{{div col}}
*]
*'']'' written by ]. * ]
* ]
*]
* ]
*]
*] * ]
* ]
*]
{{div col end}}
*]
{{multicol-break}}
*]
*]
*]
* ]
*]
*]
*]
*]
*]
*]
{{multicol-end}}


==Notes== ===General===
{{reflist|2}} {{div col}}
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
{{div col end}}

==References==
{{Reflist}}


==Further reading== ==Further reading==
===Global===
{{refbegin}}
* Brendon, Piers. ''The Dark Valley: A Panorama of the 1930s'' (2000) comprehensive global economic and political history; 816pp
* Ambrosius, G. and W. Hibbard, ''A Social and Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe'' (1989)
* Davis, Joseph S. ''The World Between the Wars, 1919–39: An Economist's View'' (1974)
* Bernanke, Ben S. "The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach" ''Journal of Money, Credit & Banking'', Vol. 27, 1995
* ] ''The Great Depression: An Inquiry into the causes, course, and Consequences of the Worldwide Depression of the Nineteen-Thirties, as Seen by Contemporaries and in Light of History'' (1986)
* Brown, Ian. ''The Economies of Africa and Asia in the inter-war depression'' (1989)
* Garside, W.R. ed. ''Capitalism in crisis: International responses to the Great Depression'' (1993), essays by experts
* Davis, Joseph S., ''The World Between the Wars, 1919-39: An Economist's View'' (1974)
* Grossman, Mark. ''Encyclopedia of the Interwar Years: From 1919 to 1939'' (2000). 400 pp. worldwide coverage
* Eichengreen, Barry. ''Golden fetters: The gold standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939.'' 1992.
* Barry Eichengreen and Marc Flandreau; ''The Gold Standard in Theory and History'' 1997
* Feinstein. Charles H. ''The European economy between the wars'' (1997)
* Friedman, Milton and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. ''A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960'' (1963), monetarist interpretation (heavily statistical)
* Galbraith, John Kenneth, ''The Great Crash, 1929'' (1954)
* Garraty, John A., ''The Great Depression: An Inquiry into the causes, course, and Consequences of the Worldwide Depression of the Nineteen-Thirties, as Seen by Contemporaries and in Light of History'' (1986)
* Garraty John A. ''Unemployment in History'' (1978)
* Garside, William R. ''Capitalism in crisis: international responses to the Great Depression'' (1993)
* Haberler, Gottfried. ''The world economy, money, and the great depression 1919-1939'' (1976)
* Hall Thomas E. and J. David Ferguson. ''The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies'' (1998) * Hall Thomas E. and J. David Ferguson. ''The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies'' (1998)
* Hodson, H.V. ''Slump and Recovery, 1929–37: A Survey of World Economic Affairs'' (Oxford UP, 1938).
* Kaiser, David E. ''Economic diplomacy and the origins of the Second World War: Germany, Britain, France and Eastern Europe, 1930-1939'' (1980)
* Kehoe, Timothy J. and Edward C. Prescott. ''Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century'' (2007)
* Keynes, John Maynard. "The World's Economic Outlook," ''Atlantic'' (May 1932),
* League Of Nations. ''World Economic Survey 1935–1936'' (1936)
* Kindleberger, Charles P. ''The World in Depression, 1929-1939'' (1983)
* ] ''The great slump: capitalism in crisis, 1929–33'' (1970) , Marxist.
* Gernot Kohler and Emilio José Chaves (Editors) “Globalization: Critical Perspectives” Haupauge, New York: Nova Science Publishers (http://www.novapublishers.com/) ISBN 1-59033-346-2. With contributions by ], ], ], ]
* League of Nations, ''World Economic Survey 1932-33'' (1934)
* Madsen, Jakob B. "Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression", ''Southern Economic Journal'', Southern Economic Journal 2001, 67(4), 848-868
* ], ''John] and International Relations: Economic Paths to War and Peace'', Oxford University Press (2006).
* Mundell, R. A. "A Reconsideration of the Twentieth Century," ''The American Economic Review'' Vol. 90, No. 3 (Jun., 2000), pp. 327–340
* Rothermund, Dietmar. ''The Global Impact of the Great Depression'' (1996) * Rothermund, Dietmar. ''The Global Impact of the Great Depression'' (1996)
* Woytinsky, Wladimir. ''The Social Consequences Of The Economic Depression'' (International Labour Office, 1936). Statistics of major economies; not online.
* Tausch, Arno, with Christian Ghymers. "From the “Washington” towards a “Vienna Consensus”? A quantitative analysis on globalization, development and global governance". Hauppauge, N.Y.: Nova Science Publishers, 2007 (for info: https://www.novapublishers.com/catalog/).
* Tausch, Arno and Almas Heshmati (Eds.) "Roadmap to Bangalore? Globalization, the EU’s Lisbon Process and the Structures of Global Inequality" Hauppauge, N.Y.: Nova Science Publishers, 2008, with contributions by Franco Modigliani et al. (for info: https://www.novapublishers.com/catalog/).
* Tipton, F. and R. Aldrich, ''An Economic and Social History of Europe, 1890–1939'' (1987)
{{refend}}
:''For '''US specific references''', please see complete listing in the ] article.''


==External links== ===Europe===
* Aldcroft, Derek H. "Economic Growth in Britain in the Inter-War Years: A Reassessment." Economic History Review, 20#2, 1967, pp.&nbsp;311–26.
{{Commonscat}}
* Ambrosius, G. and W. Hibbard, ''A Social and Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe'' (1989)
*
* Broadberry, S. N. ''The British Economy between the Wars'' (Basil Blackwell 1986)
*
* Feinstein. Charles H. ''The European Economy between the Wars'' (1997)
*
* James, Harold. ''The German slump : politics and economics, 1924–1936'' (1986)
*
* Kaiser, David E. ''Economic diplomacy and the origins of the Second World War: Germany, Britain, France and Eastern Europe, 1930–1939'' (1980)
* from EH.NET by Randall Parker.
* Konrad, Helmut and Wolfgang Maderthaner, eds. '' {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200124020610/https://books.google.com/books?id=cTPUAAAAQBAJ |date=24 January 2020 }}'' (Berghahn Books, 2013), 224 pp.&nbsp;Compares political crises in Germany, Italy, Austria, and Spain with those in Sweden, Japan, China, India, Turkey, Brazil, and the United States.
* by ]
* Psalidopoulos, Michael, ed. ''The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context'' (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012). {{ISBN|978-960-99793-6-8}}. Chapters by economic historians cover Finland, Sweden, Belgium, Austria, Italy, Greece, Turkey, Bulgaria, Yugoslavia, Romania, Spain, Portugal, and Ireland. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170313092132/http://www.ics.ul.pt/rdonweb-docs/ICS_JLCardoso_Great_AI.pdf |date=13 March 2017 }}
* for copyright-free photos of the period
* Tipton, F. and R. Aldrich, '']'' (1987)
* by ] (1969)
*
*
* How to to avoid a 2008 Remake of the Keynesian Debacle


===United States and Canada===
{{GreatDepr nav}}
* Dickstein, Morris. ''Dancing in the dark : a cultural history of the Great Depression'' (2009)
{{US recessions}}
* . ca. 1933–1934. 18 photographic prints (1 box). At the .
{{New Deal}}
* ], ''The Great Crash, 1929'' (1954), popular ]
* Goldston, Robert, ''The Great Depression: The United States in the Thirties'' (1968)
* McNeese, Tim, and Richard Jensen. ''The Great Depression 1929–1938'' (Discovering U.S. History) (2010) , for middle schools.
* Mitchell, Broadus. ''Depression Decade: From New Era through New Deal, 1929–1941'' (1947), 462 pp., thorough coverage of the U.S. economy ]
* Reis, Ronald A. ''The Great Depression and the New Deal : America's economy in crisis'' (2011) for secondary schools. ]
* Safarian, A. E. ''The Canadian economy in the Great Depression'' (2009) ]
* . 1985. 4 sound cassettes; papers. Storey discusses the Great Depression and hardships of early life, abortion, childbearing and motherhood. At the .
* Young, William H. ''The Great Depression in America : a cultural encyclopedia'' (2007) ]


===Other areas===
]
* Brown, Ian. ''The Economies of Africa and Asia in the Inter-war Depression'' (1989)
]
* Drinot, Paulo, and Alan Knight, eds. ''The Great Depression in Latin America'' (2014)
]
* Latham, Anthony, and John Heaton, ''The Depression and the Developing World, 1914–1939'' (1981).
]
* Shiroyama, Tomoko. ''China during the Great Depression : market, state, and the world economy, 1929–1937'' (2008)


===Focus on economic theory or econometrics===
]
* Bernanke, Ben. "The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach" ''Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking'' (1995) 27#1 pp 1–28
]
* Eichengreen, Barry J. ''Hall of mirrors : the Great Depression, the great recession, and the uses-and misuses-of history'' (2015), leading economist compares economic decline after 1929 and after 2008.
]
* Eichengreen, Barry. ''Golden Fetters: The gold standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939.'' 1992.
]
* Eichengreen, Barry, and Marc Flandreau. ''The Gold Standard in Theory and History'' (1997)
]
* Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. ''A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960'' (1963), monetarist interpretation (heavily statistical)
]
* Glasner, David, ed. ''Business Cycles and Depressions'' (Routledge, 1997), 800 pp.
]
* Grinin, L., ] and Tausch A. eds. '''' (2016).
]
* ] ''The World Economy, money, and the great depression 1919–1939'' (1976)
]
* Kehoe, Timothy J. and Edward C. Prescott, eds. ''Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century'' (2007), essays by economists on the U.S., Britain, France, Germany, Italy and on tariffs; statistical
]
* Kindleberger, Charles P. ''The World in Depression, 1929–1939'' (3rd ed. 2013)
]
* Madsen, Jakob B. "Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression", ''Southern Economic Journal'', (2001) 67#4 pp.&nbsp;848–68
]
* ]. ''John Maynard Keynes and International Relations: Economic Paths to War and Peace'' (Oxford University Press, 2006).
]
* Mundell, R.A. "A Reconsideration of the Twentieth Century", ''American Economic Review'' 90#3 (2000), pp.&nbsp;327–40
]
* Richardson, H. W. "The Basis of Economic Recovery in the Nineteen-Thirties: A Review and a New Interpretation." ''Economic History Review,'' 15#2 (1962), pp.&nbsp;344–63. ; focus on United Kingdom.
]
* Romer, Christina D. "The Nation in Depression", ''Journal of Economic Perspectives'' (1993) 7#2 pp.&nbsp;19–39 {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160703181514/http://www.jstor.org/stable/2138198 |date=3 July 2016 }}, statistical comparison of U.S. and other countries
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]


{{Commons category|Great Depression}}
{{Wikiquote}}


{{Portal bar|United States|Economics|1920s|World}}
{{Great Depression}}
{{New Deal}}
{{United States–Commonwealth of Nations recessions}}
{{United States topics}}
{{economics}}
{{Employment}}
{{Authority control}}


]

]

]

]
vanessa loves him very much he dosent understand she would give up the world to him lo amo mucho el sieempre me ase reir hes so fukin sexy he always knows how to make me laugh he is the greatest kisser so efin sexy dammm .... i love you anthony santos=D
]

Latest revision as of 02:10, 28 December 2024

Worldwide economic depression (1929–1939) This article is about the severe worldwide economic downturn in the 1930s. For other uses, see The Great Depression (disambiguation).

Unemployed people lined up outside a soup kitchen opened in Chicago by Al Capone during the Great Depression in February 1931

The Great Depression was a severe global economic downturn from 1929 to 1939. The period was characterized by high rates of unemployment and poverty; drastic reductions in liquidity, industrial production, and trade; and widespread bank and business failures around the world. The economic contagion began in 1929 in the United States, the largest economy in the world, with the devastating Wall Street stock market crash of October 1929 often considered the beginning of the Depression. Among the countries with the most unemployed were the U.S., the United Kingdom, and Germany.

The Depression was preceded by a period of industrial growth and social development known as the "Roaring Twenties". Much of the profit generated by the boom was invested in speculation, such as on the stock market, which resulted in growing wealth inequality. Banks were subject to minimal regulation under laissez-faire economic policies, resulting in loose lending and widespread debt. By 1929, declining spending had led to reductions in manufacturing output and rising unemployment. Share values continued to rise until the Wall Street crash, after which the slide continued for three years, accompanied by a loss of confidence in the financial system. By 1933, the unemployment rate in the U.S. had risen to 25 percent, about one-third of farmers had lost their land, and about half of its 25,000 banks had gone out of business. The U.S. federal government under President Herbert Hoover was unwilling to intervene heavily in the economy. In the 1932 presidential election, Hoover was defeated by Franklin D. Roosevelt, who from 1933 pursued a set of expansive New Deal programs in order to provide relief and create jobs. In Germany, which depended heavily on U.S. loans, the crisis caused unemployment to rise to nearly 30% and fueled political extremism, paving the way for Adolf Hitler's Nazi Party to rise to power in 1933.

Between 1929 and 1932, worldwide gross domestic product (GDP) fell by an estimated 15%; in the U.S., the Depression resulted in a 30% contraction in GDP. Recovery varied greatly around the world. Some economies, such as the U.S., Germany and Japan started to recover by the mid-1930s; others, like France, did not return to pre-shock growth rates until later in the decade. The Depression had devastating economic effects on both wealthy and poor countries: all experienced drops in personal income, prices (deflation), tax revenues, and profits. International trade fell by more than 50%, and unemployment in some countries rose as high as 33%. Cities around the world, especially those dependent on heavy industry, were heavily affected. Construction virtually halted in many countries, and farming communities and rural areas suffered as crop prices fell by up to 60%. Faced with plummeting demand and few job alternatives, areas dependent on primary sector industries suffered the most. The outbreak of World War II in 1939 ended the Depression, as it stimulated factory production, providing jobs for women as militaries absorbed large numbers of young, unemployed men.

The precise causes for the Great Depression are disputed. One set of historians, for example, focuses on non-monetary economic causes. Among these, some regard the Wall Street crash itself as the main cause; others consider that the crash was a mere symptom of more general economic trends of the time, which had already been underway in the late 1920s. A contrasting set of views, which rose to prominence in the later part of the 20th century, ascribes a more prominent role to failures of monetary policy. According to those authors, while general economic trends can explain the emergence of the downturn, they fail to account for its severity and longevity; they argue that these were caused by the lack of an adequate response to the crises of liquidity that followed the initial economic shock of 1929 and the subsequent bank failures accompanied by a general collapse of the financial markets.

Overview

The unemployment rate in the U.S. during 1910–60, with the years of the Great Depression (1929–39) highlightedThe Dow Jones Industrial Average, 1928–1930

The economic picture at the beginning of the crisis

After the Wall Street Crash of 1929, when the Dow Jones Industrial Average dropped from 381 to 198 over the course of two months, optimism persisted for some time. The stock market rose in early 1930, with the Dow returning to 294 (pre-depression levels) in April 1930, before steadily declining for years, to a low of 41 in 1932.

At the beginning, governments and businesses spent more in the first half of 1930 than in the corresponding period of the previous year. On the other hand, consumers, many of whom suffered severe losses in the stock market the previous year, cut expenditures by 10%. In addition, beginning in the mid-1930s, a severe drought ravaged the agricultural heartland of the U.S.

Interest rates dropped to low levels by mid-1930, but expected deflation and the continuing reluctance of people to borrow meant that consumer spending and investment remained low. By May 1930, automobile sales declined to below the levels of 1928. Prices, in general, began to decline, although wages held steady in 1930. Then a deflationary spiral started in 1931. Farmers faced a worse outlook; declining crop prices and a Great Plains drought crippled their economic outlook. At its peak, the Great Depression saw nearly 10% of all Great Plains farms change hands despite federal assistance.

Beyond the U.S.

At first, the decline in the U.S. economy was the factor that triggered economic downturns in most other countries due to a decline in trade, capital movement, and global business confidence. Then, internal weaknesses or strengths in each country made conditions worse or better. For example, the U.K. economy, which experienced an economic downturn throughout most of the late 1920s, was less severely impacted by the shock of the depression than the U.S. By contrast, the German economy saw a similar decline in industrial output as that observed in the U.S. Some economic historians attribute the differences in the rates of recovery and relative severity of the economic decline to whether particular countries had been able to effectively devaluate their currencies or not. This is supported by the contrast in how the crisis progressed in, e.g., Britain, Argentina and Brazil, all of which devalued their currencies early and returned to normal patterns of growth relatively rapidly and countries which stuck to the gold standard, such as France or Belgium.

Frantic attempts by individual countries to shore up their economies through protectionist policies – such as the 1930 U.S. Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act and retaliatory tariffs in other countries – exacerbated the collapse in global trade, contributing to the depression. By 1933, the economic decline pushed world trade to one third of its level compared to four years earlier.

Change in economic indicators 1929–1932
United States United Kingdom France Germany
Industrial production −46% −23% −24% −41%
Wholesale prices −32% −33% −34% −29%
Foreign trade −70% −60% −54% −61%
Unemployment +607% +129% +214% +232%

Course

Crowd gathering at the intersection of Wall Street and Broad Street after the 1929 crash

Origins

While the precise causes for the occurrence of the Great depression are disputed and can be traced to both global and national phenomena, its immediate origins are most conveniently examined in the context of the U.S. economy, from which the initial crisis spread to the rest of the world.

In the aftermath of World War I, the Roaring Twenties brought considerable wealth to the United States and Western Europe. Initially, the year 1929 dawned with good economic prospects: despite a minor crash on 25 March 1929, the market seemed to gradually improve through September. Stock prices began to slump in September, and were volatile at the end of the month. A large sell-off of stocks began in mid-October. Finally, on 24 October, Black Thursday, the American stock market crashed 11% at the opening bell. Actions to stabilize the market failed, and on 28 October, Black Monday, the market crashed another 12%. The panic peaked the next day on Black Tuesday, when the market saw another 11% drop. Thousands of investors were ruined, and billions of dollars had been lost; many stocks could not be sold at any price. The market recovered 12% on Wednesday but by then significant damage had been done. Though the market entered a period of recovery from 14 November until 17 April 1930, the general situation had been a prolonged slump. From 17 April 1930 until 8 July 1932, the market continued to lose 89% of its value.

Crowds outside the Bank of United States in New York after its failure in 1931

Despite the crash, the worst of the crisis did not reverberate around the world until after 1929. The crisis hit panic levels again in December 1930, with a bank run on the Bank of United States, a former privately run bank, bearing no relation to the U.S. government (not to be confused with the Federal Reserve). Unable to pay out to all of its creditors, the bank failed. Among the 608 American banks that closed in November and December 1930, the Bank of United States accounted for a third of the total $550 million deposits lost and, with its closure, bank failures reached a critical mass.

The Smoot–Hawley Act and the Breakdown of International Trade

Main article: Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act
Willis C. Hawley (left) and Reed Smoot in April 1929, shortly before the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act passed the House of Representatives

In an initial response to the crisis, the U.S. Congress passed the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act on 17 June 1930. The Act was ostensibly aimed at protecting the American economy from foreign competition by imposing high tariffs on foreign imports. The consensus view among economists and economic historians (including Keynesians, Monetarists and Austrian economists) is that the passage of the Smoot–Hawley Tariff had, in fact, achieved an opposite effect to what was intended. It exacerbated the Great Depression by preventing economic recovery after domestic production recovered, hampering the volume of trade; still there is disagreement as to the precise extent of the Act's influence.

In the popular view, the Smoot–Hawley Tariff was one of the leading causes of the depression. In a 1995 survey of American economic historians, two-thirds agreed that the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act at least worsened the Great Depression. According to the U.S. Senate website, the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act is among the most catastrophic acts in congressional history.

Many economists have argued that the sharp decline in international trade after 1930 helped to worsen the depression, especially for countries significantly dependent on foreign trade. Most historians and economists blame the Act for worsening the depression by seriously reducing international trade and causing retaliatory tariffs in other countries. While foreign trade was a small part of overall economic activity in the U.S. and was concentrated in a few businesses like farming, it was a much larger factor in many other countries. The average ad valorem (value based) rate of duties on dutiable imports for 1921–1925 was 25.9% but under the new tariff it jumped to 50% during 1931–1935. In dollar terms, American exports declined over the next four years from about $5.2 billion in 1929 to $1.7 billion in 1933; so, not only did the physical volume of exports fall, but also the prices fell by about 1⁄3 as written. Hardest hit were farm commodities such as wheat, cotton, tobacco, and lumber.

Governments around the world took various steps into spending less money on foreign goods such as: "imposing tariffs, import quotas, and exchange controls". These restrictions triggered much tension among countries that had large amounts of bilateral trade, causing major export-import reductions during the depression. Not all governments enforced the same measures of protectionism. Some countries raised tariffs drastically and enforced severe restrictions on foreign exchange transactions, while other countries reduced "trade and exchange restrictions only marginally":

  • "Countries that remained on the gold standard, keeping currencies fixed, were more likely to restrict foreign trade." These countries "resorted to protectionist policies to strengthen the balance of payments and limit gold losses." They hoped that these restrictions and depletions would hold the economic decline.
  • Countries that abandoned the gold standard allowed their currencies to depreciate which caused their balance of payments to strengthen. It also freed up monetary policy so that central banks could lower interest rates and act as lenders of last resort. They possessed the best policy instruments to fight the Depression and did not need protectionism.
  • "The length and depth of a country's economic downturn and the timing and vigor of its recovery are related to how long it remained on the gold standard. Countries abandoning the gold standard relatively early experienced relatively mild recessions and early recoveries. In contrast, countries remaining on the gold standard experienced prolonged slumps."

The Gold Standard and the Spreading of Global Depression

The gold standard was the primary transmission mechanism of the Great Depression. Even countries that did not face bank failures and a monetary contraction first-hand were forced to join the deflationary policy since higher interest rates in countries that performed a deflationary policy led to a gold outflow in countries with lower interest rates. Under the gold standard's price–specie flow mechanism, countries that lost gold but nevertheless wanted to maintain the gold standard had to permit their money supply to decrease and the domestic price level to decline (deflation).

There is also consensus that protectionist policies, and primarily the passage of the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act, helped to exacerbate, or even cause the Great Depression.

Gold standard

The Depression in international perspective

Some economic studies have indicated that the rigidities of the gold standard not only spread the downturn worldwide, but also suspended gold convertibility (devaluing the currency in gold terms) that did the most to make recovery possible.

Every major currency left the gold standard during the Great Depression. The UK was the first to do so. Facing speculative attacks on the pound and depleting gold reserves, in September 1931 the Bank of England ceased exchanging pound notes for gold and the pound was floated on foreign exchange markets. Japan and the Scandinavian countries followed in 1931. Other countries, such as Italy and the United States, remained on the gold standard into 1932 or 1933, while a few countries in the so-called "gold bloc", led by France and including Poland, Belgium and Switzerland, stayed on the standard until 1935–36.

According to later analysis, the earliness with which a country left the gold standard reliably predicted its economic recovery. For example, The UK and Scandinavia, which left the gold standard in 1931, recovered much earlier than France and Belgium, which remained on gold much longer. Countries such as China, which had a silver standard, almost avoided the depression entirely. The connection between leaving the gold standard as a strong predictor of that country's severity of its depression and the length of time of its recovery has been shown to be consistent for dozens of countries, including developing countries. This partly explains why the experience and length of the depression differed between regions and states around the world.

German banking crisis of 1931 and British crisis

The financial crisis escalated out of control in mid-1931, starting with the collapse of the Credit Anstalt in Vienna in May. This put heavy pressure on Germany, which was already in political turmoil. With the rise in violence of National Socialist ('Nazi') and Communist movements, as well as investor nervousness at harsh government financial policies, investors withdrew their short-term money from Germany as confidence spiraled downward. The Reichsbank lost 150 million marks in the first week of June, 540 million in the second, and 150 million in two days, 19–20 June. Collapse was at hand. U.S. President Herbert Hoover called for a moratorium on payment of war reparations. This angered Paris, which depended on a steady flow of German payments, but it slowed the crisis down, and the moratorium was agreed to in July 1931. An International conference in London later in July produced no agreements but on 19 August a standstill agreement froze Germany's foreign liabilities for six months. Germany received emergency funding from private banks in New York as well as the Bank of International Settlements and the Bank of England. The funding only slowed the process. Industrial failures began in Germany, a major bank closed in July and a two-day holiday for all German banks was declared. Business failures were more frequent in July, and spread to Romania and Hungary. The crisis continued to get worse in Germany, bringing political upheaval that finally led to the coming to power of Hitler's Nazi regime in January 1933.

The world financial crisis now began to overwhelm Britain; investors around the world started withdrawing their gold from London at the rate of £2.5 million per day. Credits of £25 million each from the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and an issue of £15 million fiduciary note slowed, but did not reverse, the British crisis. The financial crisis now caused a major political crisis in Britain in August 1931. With deficits mounting, the bankers demanded a balanced budget; the divided cabinet of Prime Minister Ramsay MacDonald's Labour government agreed; it proposed to raise taxes, cut spending, and most controversially, to cut unemployment benefits 20%. The attack on welfare was unacceptable to the Labour movement. MacDonald wanted to resign, but King George V insisted he remain and form an all-party coalition "National Government". The Conservative and Liberals parties signed on, along with a small cadre of Labour, but the vast majority of Labour leaders denounced MacDonald as a traitor for leading the new government. Britain went off the gold standard, and suffered relatively less than other major countries in the Great Depression. In the 1931 British election, the Labour Party was virtually destroyed, leaving MacDonald as prime minister for a largely Conservative coalition.

Turning point and recovery

The overall course of the Depression in the United States, as reflected in per-capita GDP (average income per person) shown in constant year 2000 dollars, plus some of the key events of the period. Dotted red line = long-term trend 1920–1970.

In most countries of the world, recovery from the Great Depression began in 1933. In the U.S., recovery began in early 1933, but the U.S. did not return to 1929 GNP for over a decade and still had an unemployment rate of about 15% in 1940, albeit down from the high of 25% in 1933.

There is no consensus among economists regarding the motive force for the U.S. economic expansion that continued through most of the Roosevelt years (and the 1937 recession that interrupted it). The common view among most economists is that Roosevelt's New Deal policies either caused or accelerated the recovery, although his policies were never aggressive enough to bring the economy completely out of recession. Some economists have also called attention to the positive effects from expectations of reflation and rising nominal interest rates that Roosevelt's words and actions portended. It was the rollback of those same reflationary policies that led to the interruption of a recession beginning in late 1937. One contributing policy that reversed reflation was the Banking Act of 1935, which effectively raised reserve requirements, causing a monetary contraction that helped to thwart the recovery. GDP returned to its upward trend in 1938. A revisionist view among some economists holds that the New Deal prolonged the Great Depression, as they argue that National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933 and National Labor Relations Act of 1935 restricted competition and established price fixing. John Maynard Keynes did not think that the New Deal under Roosevelt single-handedly ended the Great Depression: "It is, it seems, politically impossible for a capitalistic democracy to organize expenditure on the scale necessary to make the grand experiments which would prove my case—except in war conditions."

According to Christina Romer, the money supply growth caused by huge international gold inflows was a crucial source of the recovery of the United States economy, and that the economy showed little sign of self-correction. The gold inflows were partly due to devaluation of the U.S. dollar and partly due to deterioration of the political situation in Europe. In their book, A Monetary History of the United States, Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz also attributed the recovery to monetary factors, and contended that it was much slowed by poor management of money by the Federal Reserve System. Chairman of the Federal Reserve (2006–2014) Ben Bernanke agreed that monetary factors played important roles both in the worldwide economic decline and eventual recovery. Bernanke also saw a strong role for institutional factors, particularly the rebuilding and restructuring of the financial system, and pointed out that the Depression should be examined in an international perspective.

Role of women and household economics

Women's primary role was as housewives; without a steady flow of family income, their work became much harder in dealing with food and clothing and medical care. Birthrates fell everywhere, as children were postponed until families could financially support them. The average birthrate for 14 major countries fell 12% from 19.3 births per thousand population in 1930, to 17.0 in 1935. In Canada, half of Roman Catholic women defied Church teachings and used contraception to postpone births.

Among the few women in the labor force, layoffs were less common in the white-collar jobs and they were typically found in light manufacturing work. However, there was a widespread demand to limit families to one paid job, so that wives might lose employment if their husband was employed. Across Britain, there was a tendency for married women to join the labor force, competing for part-time jobs especially.

In France, very slow population growth, especially in comparison to Germany continued to be a serious issue in the 1930s. Support for increasing welfare programs during the depression included a focus on women in the family. The Conseil Supérieur de la Natalité campaigned for provisions enacted in the Code de la Famille (1939) that increased state assistance to families with children and required employers to protect the jobs of fathers, even if they were immigrants.

In rural and small-town areas, women expanded their operation of vegetable gardens to include as much food production as possible. In the United States, agricultural organizations sponsored programs to teach housewives how to optimize their gardens and to raise poultry for meat and eggs. Rural women made feed sack dresses and other items for themselves and their families and homes from feed sacks. In American cities, African American women quiltmakers enlarged their activities, promoted collaboration, and trained neophytes. Quilts were created for practical use from various inexpensive materials and increased social interaction for women and promoted camaraderie and personal fulfillment.

Oral history provides evidence for how housewives in a modern industrial city handled shortages of money and resources. Often they updated strategies their mothers used when they were growing up in poor families. Cheap foods were used, such as soups, beans and noodles. They purchased the cheapest cuts of meat—sometimes even horse meat—and recycled the Sunday roast into sandwiches and soups. They sewed and patched clothing, traded with their neighbors for outgrown items, and made do with colder homes. New furniture and appliances were postponed until better days. Many women also worked outside the home, or took boarders, did laundry for trade or cash, and did sewing for neighbors in exchange for something they could offer. Extended families used mutual aid—extra food, spare rooms, repair-work, cash loans—to help cousins and in-laws.

In Japan, official government policy was deflationary and the opposite of Keynesian spending. Consequently, the government launched a campaign across the country to induce households to reduce their consumption, focusing attention on spending by housewives.

In Germany, the government tried to reshape private household consumption under the Four-Year Plan of 1936 to achieve German economic self-sufficiency. The Nazi women's organizations, other propaganda agencies and the authorities all attempted to shape such consumption as economic self-sufficiency was needed to prepare for and to sustain the coming war. The organizations, propaganda agencies and authorities employed slogans that called up traditional values of thrift and healthy living. However, these efforts were only partly successful in changing the behavior of housewives.

World War II and recovery

A female factory worker in 1942, Fort Worth, Texas. Women entered the workforce as men were drafted into the armed forces.

The common view among economic historians is that the Great Depression ended with the advent of World War II. Many economists believe that government spending on the war caused or at least accelerated recovery from the Great Depression, though some consider that it did not play a very large role in the recovery, though it did help in reducing unemployment.

The rearmament policies leading up to World War II helped stimulate the economies of Europe in 1937–1939. By 1937, unemployment in Britain had fallen to 1.5 million. The mobilization of manpower following the outbreak of war in 1939 ended unemployment.

The American mobilization for World War II at the end of 1941 moved approximately ten million people out of the civilian labor force and into the war. This finally eliminated the last effects from the Great Depression and brought the U.S. unemployment rate down below 10%.

World War II had a dramatic effect on many parts of the American economy. Government-financed capital spending accounted for only 5% of the annual U.S. investment in industrial capital in 1940; by 1943, the government accounted for 67% of U.S. capital investment. The massive war spending doubled economic growth rates, either masking the effects of the Depression or essentially ending the Depression. Businessmen ignored the mounting national debt and heavy new taxes, redoubling their efforts for greater output to take advantage of generous government contracts.

Causes

Main article: Causes of the Great Depression

Attempts to return to the Gold Standard

See also: Financial crisis of 1914

During World War I many countries suspended their gold standard in varying ways. There was high inflation from WWI, and in the 1920s in the Weimar Republic, Austria, and throughout Europe. In the late 1920s there was a scramble to deflate prices to get the gold standard's conversation rates back on track to pre-WWI levels, by causing deflation and high unemployment through monetary policy. In 1933 FDR signed Executive Order 6102 and in 1934 signed the Gold Reserve Act.

Gold Standard Policies by Country
Country Return to Gold Suspension of Gold Standard Foreign Exchange Control Devaluation
Australia April 1925 December 1929 March 1930
Austria April 1925 April 1933 October 1931 September 1931
Belgium October 1926 March 1935
Canada July 1926 October 1931 September 1931
Czechoslovakia April 1926 September 1931 February 1934
Denmark January 1927 September 1931 November 1931 September 1931
Estonia January 1928 June 1933 November 1931 June 1933
Finland January 1926 October 1931 October 1931
France August 1926-June 1928 October 1936
Germany September 1924 July 1931
Greece May 1928 April 1932 September 1931 April 1932
Hungary April 1925 July 1931
Italy December 1927 May 1934 October 1936
Japan December 1930 December 1931 July 1932 December 1931
Latvia August 1922 October 1931
Netherlands April 1925 October 1936
Norway May 1928 September 1931 September 1931
New Zealand April 1925 September 1931 April 1930
Poland October 1927 April 1936 October 1936
Romania March 1927-February 1929 May 1932
Sweden April 1924 September 1931 September 1931
Spain May 1931
United Kingdom May 1925 September 1931 September 1931
United States June 1919 March 1933 March 1933 April 1933

Keynesian vs Monetarist view

Money supply decreased considerably between Black Tuesday and the Bank Holiday in March 1933, when there were massive bank runs across the United States.
CPI 1914–2022
  Inflation   Deflation   M2 money supply increases Year/Year

The two classic competing economic theories of the Great Depression are the Keynesian (demand-driven) and the Monetarist explanation. There are also various heterodox theories that downplay or reject the explanations of the Keynesians and monetarists. The consensus among demand-driven theories is that a large-scale loss of confidence led to a sudden reduction in consumption and investment spending. Once panic and deflation set in, many people believed they could avoid further losses by keeping clear of the markets. Holding money became profitable as prices dropped lower and a given amount of money bought ever more goods, exacerbating the drop in demand. Monetarists believe that the Great Depression started as an ordinary recession, but the shrinking of the money supply greatly exacerbated the economic situation, causing a recession to descend into the Great Depression.

Economists and economic historians are almost evenly split as to whether the traditional monetary explanation that monetary forces were the primary cause of the Great Depression is right, or the traditional Keynesian explanation that a fall in autonomous spending, particularly investment, is the primary explanation for the onset of the Great Depression. Today there is also significant academic support for the debt deflation theory and the expectations hypothesis that – building on the monetary explanation of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz – add non-monetary explanations.

There is a consensus that the Federal Reserve System should have cut short the process of monetary deflation and banking collapse, by expanding the money supply and acting as lender of last resort. If they had done this, the economic downturn would have been far less severe and much shorter.

Mainstream explanations

U.S. industrial production, 1928–1939

Modern mainstream economists see the reasons in

Insufficient spending, the money supply reduction, and debt on margin led to falling prices and further bankruptcies (Irving Fisher's debt deflation).

Monetarist view

The Great Depression in the U.S. from a monetary view. Real gross domestic product in 1996-Dollar (blue), price index (red), money supply M2 (green) and number of banks (grey). All data adjusted to 1929 = 100%.
Crowd at New York's American Union Bank during a bank run early in the Great Depression

The monetarist explanation was given by American economists Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz. They argued that the Great Depression was caused by the banking crisis that caused one-third of all banks to vanish, a reduction of bank shareholder wealth and more importantly monetary contraction of 35%, which they called "The Great Contraction". This caused a price drop of 33% (deflation). By not lowering interest rates, by not increasing the monetary base and by not injecting liquidity into the banking system to prevent it from crumbling, the Federal Reserve passively watched the transformation of a normal recession into the Great Depression. Friedman and Schwartz argued that the downward turn in the economy, starting with the stock market crash, would merely have been an ordinary recession if the Federal Reserve had taken aggressive action. This view was endorsed in 2002 by Federal Reserve Governor Ben Bernanke in a speech honoring Friedman and Schwartz with this statement:

Let me end my talk by abusing slightly my status as an official representative of the Federal Reserve. I would like to say to Milton and Anna: Regarding the Great Depression, you're right. We did it. We're very sorry. But thanks to you, we won't do it again.

— Ben S. Bernanke

The Federal Reserve allowed some large public bank failures – particularly that of the New York Bank of United States – which produced panic and widespread runs on local banks, and the Federal Reserve sat idly by while banks collapsed. Friedman and Schwartz argued that, if the Fed had provided emergency lending to these key banks, or simply bought government bonds on the open market to provide liquidity and increase the quantity of money after the key banks fell, all the rest of the banks would not have fallen after the large ones did, and the money supply would not have fallen as far and as fast as it did.

With significantly less money to go around, businesses could not get new loans and could not even get their old loans renewed, forcing many to stop investing. This interpretation blames the Federal Reserve for inaction, especially the New York branch.

One reason why the Federal Reserve did not act to limit the decline of the money supply was the gold standard. At that time, the amount of credit the Federal Reserve could issue was limited by the Federal Reserve Act, which required 40% gold backing of Federal Reserve Notes issued. By the late 1920s, the Federal Reserve had almost hit the limit of allowable credit that could be backed by the gold in its possession. This credit was in the form of Federal Reserve demand notes. A "promise of gold" is not as good as "gold in the hand", particularly when they only had enough gold to cover 40% of the Federal Reserve Notes outstanding. During the bank panics, a portion of those demand notes was redeemed for Federal Reserve gold. Since the Federal Reserve had hit its limit on allowable credit, any reduction in gold in its vaults had to be accompanied by a greater reduction in credit. On 5 April 1933, President Roosevelt signed Executive Order 6102 making the private ownership of gold certificates, coins and bullion illegal, reducing the pressure on Federal Reserve gold.

Keynesian view

British economist John Maynard Keynes argued in The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money that lower aggregate expenditures in the economy contributed to a massive decline in income and to employment that was well below the average. In such a situation, the economy reached equilibrium at low levels of economic activity and high unemployment.

Keynes's basic idea was simple: to keep people fully employed, governments have to run deficits when the economy is slowing, as the private sector would not invest enough to keep production at the normal level and bring the economy out of recession. Keynesian economists called on governments during times of economic crisis to pick up the slack by increasing government spending or cutting taxes.

As the Depression wore on, Franklin D. Roosevelt tried public works, farm subsidies, and other devices to restart the U.S. economy, but never completely gave up trying to balance the budget. According to the Keynesians, this improved the economy, but Roosevelt never spent enough to bring the economy out of recession until the start of World War II.

Debt deflation

Irving Fisher argued that the predominant factor leading to the Great Depression was a vicious circle of deflation and growing over-indebtedness. He outlined nine factors interacting with one another under conditions of debt and deflation to create the mechanics of boom to bust. The chain of events proceeded as follows:

  1. Debt liquidation and distress selling
  2. Contraction of the money supply as bank loans are paid off
  3. A fall in the level of asset prices
  4. A still greater fall in the net worth of businesses, precipitating bankruptcies
  5. A fall in profits
  6. A reduction in output, in trade and in employment
  7. Pessimism and loss of confidence
  8. Hoarding of money
  9. A fall in nominal interest rates and a rise in deflation adjusted interest rates

During the Crash of 1929 preceding the Great Depression, margin requirements were only 10%. Brokerage firms, in other words, would lend $9 for every $1 an investor had deposited. When the market fell, brokers called in these loans, which could not be paid back. Banks began to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors attempted to withdraw their deposits en masse, triggering multiple bank runs. Government guarantees and Federal Reserve banking regulations to prevent such panics were ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to the loss of billions of dollars in assets.

Outstanding debts became heavier, because prices and incomes fell by 20–50% but the debts remained at the same dollar amount. After the panic of 1929 and during the first 10 months of 1930, 744 U.S. banks failed. (In all, 9,000 banks failed during the 1930s.) By April 1933, around $7 billion in deposits had been frozen in failed banks or those left unlicensed after the March Bank Holiday. Bank failures snowballed as desperate bankers called in loans that borrowers did not have time or money to repay. With future profits looking poor, capital investment and construction slowed or completely ceased. In the face of bad loans and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks became even more conservative in their lending. Banks built up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A vicious cycle developed and the downward spiral accelerated.

The liquidation of debt could not keep up with the fall of prices that it caused. The mass effect of the stampede to liquidate increased the value of each dollar owed, relative to the value of declining asset holdings. The very effort of individuals to lessen their burden of debt effectively increased it. Paradoxically, the more the debtors paid, the more they owed. This self-aggravating process turned a 1930 recession into a 1933 great depression.

Fisher's debt-deflation theory initially lacked mainstream influence because of the counter-argument that debt-deflation represented no more than a redistribution from one group (debtors) to another (creditors). Pure re-distributions should have no significant macroeconomic effects.

Building on both the monetary hypothesis of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz and the debt deflation hypothesis of Irving Fisher, Ben Bernanke developed an alternative way in which the financial crisis affected output. He builds on Fisher's argument that dramatic declines in the price level and nominal incomes lead to increasing real debt burdens, which in turn leads to debtor insolvency and consequently lowers aggregate demand; a further price level decline would then result in a debt deflationary spiral. According to Bernanke, a small decline in the price level simply reallocates wealth from debtors to creditors without doing damage to the economy. But when the deflation is severe, falling asset prices along with debtor bankruptcies lead to a decline in the nominal value of assets on bank balance sheets. Banks will react by tightening their credit conditions, which in turn leads to a credit crunch that seriously harms the economy. A credit crunch lowers investment and consumption, which results in declining aggregate demand and additionally contributes to the deflationary spiral.

Expectations hypothesis

Since economic mainstream turned to the new neoclassical synthesis, expectations are a central element of macroeconomic models. According to Peter Temin, Barry Wigmore, Gauti B. Eggertsson and Christina Romer, the key to recovery and to ending the Great Depression was brought about by a successful management of public expectations. The thesis is based on the observation that after years of deflation and a very severe recession important economic indicators turned positive in March 1933 when Franklin D. Roosevelt took office. Consumer prices turned from deflation to a mild inflation, industrial production bottomed out in March 1933, and investment doubled in 1933 with a turnaround in March 1933. There were no monetary forces to explain that turnaround. Money supply was still falling and short-term interest rates remained close to zero. Before March 1933, people expected further deflation and a recession so that even interest rates at zero did not stimulate investment. But when Roosevelt announced major regime changes, people began to expect inflation and an economic expansion. With these positive expectations, interest rates at zero began to stimulate investment just as they were expected to do. Roosevelt's fiscal and monetary policy regime change helped make his policy objectives credible. The expectation of higher future income and higher future inflation stimulated demand and investment. The analysis suggests that the elimination of the policy dogmas of the gold standard, a balanced budget in times of crisis and small government led endogenously to a large shift in expectation that accounts for about 70–80% of the recovery of output and prices from 1933 to 1937. If the regime change had not happened and the Hoover policy had continued, the economy would have continued its free fall in 1933, and output would have been 30% lower in 1937 than in 1933.

The recession of 1937–1938, which slowed down economic recovery from the Great Depression, is explained by fears of the population that the moderate tightening of the monetary and fiscal policy in 1937 were first steps to a restoration of the pre-1933 policy regime.

Common position

There is common consensus among economists today that the government and the central bank should work to keep the interconnected macroeconomic aggregates of gross domestic product and money supply on a stable growth path. When threatened by expectations of a depression, central banks should expand liquidity in the banking system and the government should cut taxes and accelerate spending in order to prevent a collapse in money supply and aggregate demand.

At the beginning of the Great Depression, most economists believed in Say's law and the equilibrating powers of the market, and failed to understand the severity of the Depression. Outright leave-it-alone liquidationism was a common position, and was universally held by Austrian School economists. The liquidationist position held that a depression worked to liquidate failed businesses and investments that had been made obsolete by technological development – releasing factors of production (capital and labor) to be redeployed in other more productive sectors of the dynamic economy. They argued that even if self-adjustment of the economy caused mass bankruptcies, it was still the best course.

Economists like Barry Eichengreen and J. Bradford DeLong note that President Herbert Hoover tried to keep the federal budget balanced until 1932, when he lost confidence in his Secretary of the Treasury Andrew Mellon and replaced him. An increasingly common view among economic historians is that the adherence of many Federal Reserve policymakers to the liquidationist position led to disastrous consequences. Unlike what liquidationists expected, a large proportion of the capital stock was not redeployed but vanished during the first years of the Great Depression. According to a study by Olivier Blanchard and Lawrence Summers, the recession caused a drop of net capital accumulation to pre-1924 levels by 1933. Milton Friedman called leave-it-alone liquidationism "dangerous nonsense". He wrote:

I think the Austrian business-cycle theory has done the world a great deal of harm. If you go back to the 1930s, which is a key point, here you had the Austrians sitting in London, Hayek and Lionel Robbins, and saying you just have to let the bottom drop out of the world. You've just got to let it cure itself. You can't do anything about it. You will only make it worse. ... I think by encouraging that kind of do-nothing policy both in Britain and in the United States, they did harm.

Heterodox theories

Austrian School

Two prominent theorists in the Austrian School on the Great Depression include Austrian economist Friedrich Hayek and American economist Murray Rothbard, who wrote America's Great Depression (1963). In their view, much like the monetarists, the Federal Reserve (created in 1913) shoulders much of the blame; however, unlike the Monetarists, they argue that the key cause of the Depression was the expansion of the money supply in the 1920s which led to an unsustainable credit-driven boom.

In the Austrian view, it was this inflation of the money supply that led to an unsustainable boom in both asset prices (stocks and bonds) and capital goods. Therefore, by the time the Federal Reserve tightened in 1928 it was far too late to prevent an economic contraction. In February 1929 Hayek published a paper predicting the Federal Reserve's actions would lead to a crisis starting in the stock and credit markets.

According to Rothbard, the government support for failed enterprises and efforts to keep wages above their market values actually prolonged the Depression. Unlike Rothbard, after 1970 Hayek believed that the Federal Reserve had further contributed to the problems of the Depression by permitting the money supply to shrink during the earliest years of the Depression. However, during the Depression (in 1932 and in 1934) Hayek had criticized both the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England for not taking a more contractionary stance.

Hans Sennholz argued that most boom and busts that plagued the American economy, such as those in 1819–20, 1839–1843, 1857–1860, 1873–1878, 1893–1897, and 1920–21, were generated by government creating a boom through easy money and credit, which was soon followed by the inevitable bust.

Ludwig von Mises wrote in the 1930s: "Credit expansion cannot increase the supply of real goods. It merely brings about a rearrangement. It diverts capital investment away from the course prescribed by the state of economic wealth and market conditions. It causes production to pursue paths which it would not follow unless the economy were to acquire an increase in material goods. As a result, the upswing lacks a solid base. It is not real prosperity. It is illusory prosperity. It did not develop from an increase in economic wealth, i.e. the accumulation of savings made available for productive investment. Rather, it arose because the credit expansion created the illusion of such an increase. Sooner or later, it must become apparent that this economic situation is built on sand."

Marxist

Marxists generally argue that the Great Depression was the result of the inherent instability of the capitalist mode of production. According to Forbes, "The idea that capitalism caused the Great Depression was widely held among intellectuals and the general public for many decades."

Inequality

Power farming displaces tenants from the land in the western dry cotton area. Childress County, Texas, 1938.

Two economists of the 1920s, Waddill Catchings and William Trufant Foster, popularized a theory that influenced many policy makers, including Herbert Hoover, Henry A. Wallace, Paul Douglas, and Marriner Eccles. It held the economy produced more than it consumed, because the consumers did not have enough income. Thus the unequal distribution of wealth throughout the 1920s caused the Great Depression.

According to this view, the root cause of the Great Depression was a global over-investment in heavy industry capacity compared to wages and earnings from independent businesses, such as farms. The proposed solution was for the government to pump money into the consumers' pockets. That is, it must redistribute purchasing power, maintaining the industrial base, and re-inflating prices and wages to force as much of the inflationary increase in purchasing power into consumer spending. The economy was overbuilt, and new factories were not needed. Foster and Catchings recommended federal and state governments to start large construction projects, a program followed by Hoover and Roosevelt.

Productivity shock

It cannot be emphasized too strongly that the trends we are describing are long-time trends and were thoroughly evident before 1929. These trends are in nowise the result of the present depression, nor are they the result of the World War. On the contrary, the present depression is a collapse resulting from these long-term trends.

— M. King Hubbert

The first three decades of the 20th century saw economic output surge with electrification, mass production, and motorized farm machinery, and because of the rapid growth in productivity there was a lot of excess production capacity and the work week was being reduced. The dramatic rise in productivity of major industries in the U.S. and the effects of productivity on output, wages and the workweek are discussed by Spurgeon Bell in his book Productivity, Wages, and National Income (1940).

Effects by country

This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (May 2016) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
An impoverished American family living in a shanty, 1936

The majority of countries set up relief programs and most underwent some sort of political upheaval, pushing them to the right. Many of the countries in Europe and Latin America, that were democracies, saw their democratic governments overthrown by some form of dictatorship or authoritarian rule, most famously in Germany in 1933. The Dominion of Newfoundland abandoned its autonomy within the British Empire, becoming the only region ever to voluntarily relinquish democracy. There, too, were severe impacts across the Middle East and North Africa, including economic decline which led to social unrest.

Argentina

This section needs expansion. You can help by making an edit requestadding to it . (April 2024)

Decline in foreign trade hit Argentina hard. The British decision to stop importing Argentine beef led to the signing of the Roca–Runciman Treaty, which preserved a quota in exchange for significant concessions to British exports. By 1935, the economy had recovered to 1929 levels, and the same year, the Central Bank of Argentina was formed. However, the Great Depression was the last time when Argentina was one of the richer countries of the world, as it stopped growing in the decades thereafter, and became underdeveloped.

Australia

Main article: Great Depression in Australia

Australia's dependence on agricultural and industrial exports meant it was one of the hardest-hit developed countries. Falling export demand and commodity prices placed massive downward pressures on wages. Unemployment reached a record high of 29% in 1932, with incidents of civil unrest becoming common. After 1932, an increase in wool and meat prices led to a gradual recovery.

Canada

Main article: Great Depression in Canada
Unemployed men march in Toronto, Ontario, Canada.

Harshly affected by both the global economic downturn and the Dust Bowl, Canadian industrial production had by 1932 fallen to only 58% of its 1929 figure, the second-lowest level in the world after the United States, and well behind countries such as Britain, which fell to only 83% of the 1929 level. Total national income fell to 56% of the 1929 level, again worse than any country apart from the United States. Unemployment reached 27% at the depth of the Depression in 1933.

Chile

Main article: Great Depression in Chile

The League of Nations labeled Chile the country hardest-hit by the Great Depression, because 80% of government revenue came from exports of copper and nitrates, which were in low demand. Chile initially felt the impact of the Great Depression in 1930, when GDP dropped 14%, mining income declined 27%, and export earnings fell 28%. By 1932, GDP had shrunk to less than half of what it had been in 1929, exacting a terrible toll in unemployment and business failures.

Influenced profoundly by the Great Depression, many government leaders promoted the development of local industry in an effort to insulate the economy from future external shocks. After six years of government austerity measures, which succeeded in reestablishing Chile's creditworthiness, Chileans elected to office during the 1938–58 period a succession of center and left-of-center governments interested in promoting economic growth through government intervention.

Prompted in part by the devastating 1939 Chillán earthquake, the Popular Front government of Pedro Aguirre Cerda created the Production Development Corporation (Corporación de Fomento de la Producción, CORFO) to encourage with subsidies and direct investments — an ambitious program of import substitution industrialization. Consequently, as in other Latin American countries, protectionism became an entrenched aspect of the Chilean economy.

China

Main article: Nanjing Decade

China was largely unaffected by the Depression, mainly by having stuck to the Silver standard. However, the U.S. silver purchase act of 1934 created an intolerable demand on China's silver coins, and so, in the end, the silver standard was officially abandoned in 1935 in favor of the four Chinese national banks' "legal note" issues. China and the British colony of Hong Kong, which followed suit in this regard in September 1935, would be the last to abandon the silver standard. In addition, the Nationalist Government also acted energetically to modernize the legal and penal systems, stabilize prices, amortize debts, reform the banking and currency systems, build railroads and highways, improve public health facilities, legislate against traffic in narcotics, and augment industrial and agricultural production. On 3 November 1935, the government instituted the fiat currency (fapi) reform, immediately stabilizing prices and also raising revenues for the government.

European African colonies

The sharp fall in commodity prices and the steep decline in exports hurt the economies of the European colonies in Africa and Asia. The agricultural sector was especially hard-hit. For example, sisal had recently become a major export crop in Kenya and Tanganyika. During the depression, it suffered severely from low prices and marketing problems that affected all colonial commodities in Africa. Sisal producers established centralized controls for the export of their fibre. There was widespread unemployment and hardship among peasants, labourers, colonial auxiliaries, and artisans. The budgets of colonial governments were cut, which forced the reduction in ongoing infrastructure projects, such as the building and upgrading of roads, ports, and communications. The budget cuts delayed the schedule for creating systems of higher education.

The depression severely hurt the export-based Belgian Congo economy because of the drop in international demand for raw materials and for agricultural products. For example, the price of peanuts fell from 125 to 25 centimes. In some areas, as in the Katanga mining region, employment declined by 70%. In the country as a whole, the wage labour force decreased by 72,000 people, and many men returned to their villages. In Leopoldville, the population decreased by 33% because of this labour migration.

Political protests were not common. However, there was a growing demand, that the paternalistic claims be honored by colonial governments to respond vigorously. The theme was, that economic reforms were more urgently needed than political reforms. French West Africa launched an extensive program of educational reform, in which "rural schools", designed to modernize agriculture, would stem the flow of under-employed farm workers to cities where unemployment was high. Students were trained in traditional arts, crafts, and farming techniques and were then expected to return to their own villages and towns.

France

Main article: Great Depression in France
Soup kitchen for the unemployed in Paris, 1932

The crisis affected France a bit later than other countries, hitting hard around 1931. While the 1920s grew at the very strong rate of 4.43% per year, the 1930s rate fell to only 0.63%.

The depression was relatively mild: unemployment peaked under 5%, the fall in production was at most 20% below the 1929 output; there was no banking crisis.

However, the depression had drastic effects on the local economy, and partly explains the February 6, 1934 riots and even more the formation of the Popular Front, led by SFIO socialist leader Léon Blum, which won the elections in 1936. Ultra-nationalist groups also saw increased popularity, though democracy prevailed into World War II.

France's relatively high degree of self-sufficiency meant the damage was considerably less than in neighbouring states like Germany.

Germany

Main article: Weimar Republic
Unemployed men in Hamburg, 1931

The Great Depression hit Germany hard. The impact of the Wall Street Crash forced American banks to end the new loans that had been funding the repayments under the Dawes Plan and the Young Plan. The financial crisis escalated out of control in mid-1931, starting with the collapse of the Credit Anstalt in Vienna in May. This put heavy pressure on Germany, which was already in political turmoil with the rise in violence of national socialist and communist movements, as well as with investor nervousness at harsh government financial policies, investors withdrew their short-term money from Germany as confidence spiraled downward. The Reichsbank lost 150 million marks in the first week of June, 540 million in the second, and 150 million in two days, 19–20 June. Collapse was at hand. U.S. President Herbert Hoover called for a moratorium on payment of war reparations. This angered Paris, which depended on a steady flow of German payments, but it slowed the crisis down, and the moratorium was agreed to in July 1931. An international conference in London later in July produced no agreements, but on 19 August, a standstill agreement froze Germany's foreign liabilities for six months. Germany received emergency funding from private banks in New York as well as the Bank of International Settlements and the Bank of England. The funding only slowed the process. Industrial failures began in Germany, a major bank closed in July, and a two-day holiday for all German banks was declared. Business failures became more frequent in July, and spread to Romania and Hungary.

In 1932, 90% of German reparation payments were cancelled (in the 1950s, Germany repaid all its missed reparations debts). Widespread unemployment reached 25%, as every sector was hurt. The government did not increase government spending to deal with Germany's growing crisis, as they were afraid, that a high-spending policy could lead to a return of the hyperinflation that had affected Germany in 1923. Germany's Weimar Republic was hit hard by the depression, as American loans to help rebuild the German economy now stopped. The unemployment rate reached nearly 30% in 1932.

The devil operating a screw press against a workman, Nazi propaganda medal, obverse
The reverse of this medal supporting the German election Nazi campaigns of 1932

The German political landscape was dramatically altered, leading to Adolf Hitler's rise to power. The Nazi Party rose from being peripheral to winning 18.3% of the vote in the September 1930 election, and the Communist Party also made gains, while moderate forces, like the Social Democratic Party, the Democratic Party, and the People's Party lost seats. The next two years were marked by increased street violence between Nazis and Communists, while governments under President Paul von Hindenburg increasingly relied on rule by decree, bypassing the Reichstag. Hitler ran for the Presidency in 1932, and while he lost to the incumbent Hindenburg in the election, it marked a point during which both Nazi Party and the Communist parties rose in the years following the crash to altogether possess a Reichstag majority following the general election in July 1932. Although the Nazis lost seats in November 1932 election, they remained the largest party, and Hitler was appointed as Chancellor the following January. The government formation deal was designed to give Hitler's conservative coalition partners many checks on his power, but over the next few months, the Nazis manoeuvred to consolidate a single-party dictatorship.

Adolf Hitler speaking in 1935

Hitler followed an economic policy of autarky, creating a network of client states and economic allies in central Europe and Latin America. By cutting wages and taking control of labor unions, plus public works spending, unemployment fell significantly by 1935. Large-scale military spending played a major role in the recovery. The policies had the effect of driving up the cost of food imports and depleting foreign currency reserves, leading to economic impasse by 1936. Nazi Germany faced a choice of either reversing course or pressing ahead with rearmament and autarky. Hitler chose the latter route, which, according to Ian Kershaw, "could only be partially accomplished without territorial expansion" and therefore war.

Greece

Main article: Economic history of Greece and the Greek world

The reverberations of the Great Depression hit Greece in 1932. The Bank of Greece tried to adopt deflationary policies to stave off the crises that were going on in other countries, but these largely failed. For a brief period, the drachma was pegged to the U.S. dollar, but this was unsustainable given the country's large trade deficit and the only long-term effects of this were Greece's foreign exchange reserves being almost totally wiped out in 1932. Remittances from abroad declined sharply, and the value of the drachma began to plummet from 77 drachmas to the dollar in March 1931 to 111 drachmas to the dollar in April 1931. This was especially harmful to Greece, as the country relied on imports from the UK, France, and the Middle East for many necessities. Greece went off the gold standard in April 1932, and declared a moratorium on all interest payments. The country also adopted protectionist policies, such as import quotas, which several European countries also did during the period.

Protectionist policies coupled with a weak drachma and the stifling of imports allowed the Greek industry to expand during the Great Depression. In 1939, the Greek industrial output was 179% that of 1928. These industries were for the most part "built on sand", as one report of the Bank of Greece put it, as without massive protection, they would not have been able to survive. Despite the global depression, Greece managed to suffer comparatively little, averaging an average growth rate of 3.5% from 1932 to 1939. The dictatorial regime of Ioannis Metaxas took over the Greek government in 1936, and economic growth was strong in the years leading up to the Second World War.

Iceland

Main article: Economic history of Iceland

Icelandic post-World War I prosperity came to an end with the outbreak of the Great Depression. The Depression hit Iceland hard, as the value of exports plummeted. The total value of Icelandic exports fell from 74 million kronur in 1929 to 48 million in 1932, and was not to rise again to the pre-1930 level until after 1939. Government interference in the economy increased: "Imports were regulated, trade with foreign currency was monopolized by state-owned banks, and loan capital was largely distributed by state-regulated funds". Due to the outbreak of the Spanish Civil War, which cut Iceland's exports of saltfish by half, the Depression lasted in Iceland until the outbreak of World War II (when prices for fish exports soared).

India

Main article: Great Depression in India

How much India was affected, has been hotly debated. Historians have argued, that the Great Depression slowed long-term industrial development. Apart from two sectors — jute and coal — the economy was little-affected. However, there were major negative impacts on the jute industry, as world demand fell and prices plunged. Otherwise, conditions were fairly stable. Local markets in agriculture and small-scale industry showed modest gains.

Ireland

Main article: Economic history of the Republic of Ireland

Frank Barry and Mary E. Daly have argued that:

Ireland was a largely agrarian economy, trading almost exclusively with the UK at the time of the Great Depression. Beef and dairy products comprised the bulk of exports, and Ireland fared well relative to many other commodity producers, particularly in the early years of the depression.

Italy

Main article: Economic history of Italy
Unemployed outside a factory in Italy, October 1931
Benito Mussolini giving a speech at the Fiat Lingotto factory in Turin, 1932

The Great Depression hit Italy very hard. As industries came close to failure they were bought out by the banks in a largely illusionary bail-out—the assets used to fund the purchases were largely worthless. This led to a financial crisis peaking in 1932 and major government intervention. The Industrial Reconstruction Institute (IRI) was formed in January 1933 and took control of the bank-owned companies, suddenly giving Italy the largest state-owned industrial sector in Europe (excluding the USSR). IRI did rather well with its new responsibilities—restructuring, modernising and rationalising as much as it could. It was a significant factor in post-1945 development. But it took the Italian economy until 1935 to recover the manufacturing levels of 1930—a position that was only 60% better than that of 1913.

Japan

The Great Depression did not strongly affect Japan. The Japanese economy shrank by 8% during 1929–31. Japan's Finance Minister Takahashi Korekiyo was the first to implement what have come to be identified as Keynesian economic policies: first, by large fiscal stimulus involving deficit spending; and second, by devaluing the currency. Takahashi used the Bank of Japan to sterilize the deficit spending and minimize resulting inflationary pressures. Econometric studies have identified the fiscal stimulus as especially effective.

The devaluation of the currency had an immediate effect. Japanese textiles began to displace British textiles in export markets. The deficit spending proved to be most profound and went into the purchase of munitions for the armed forces. By 1933, Japan was already out of the depression. By 1934, Takahashi realized that the economy was in danger of overheating, and to avoid inflation, moved to reduce the deficit spending that went towards armaments and munitions.

This resulted in a strong and swift negative reaction from nationalists, especially those in the army, culminating in his assassination in the course of the February 26 Incident. This had a chilling effect on all civilian bureaucrats in the Japanese government. From 1934, the military's dominance of the government continued to grow. Instead of reducing deficit spending, the government introduced price controls and rationing schemes that reduced, but did not eliminate inflation, which remained a problem until the end of World War II.

The deficit spending had a transformative effect on Japan. Japan's industrial production doubled during the 1930s. Further, in 1929 the list of the largest firms in Japan was dominated by light industries, especially textile companies (many of Japan's automakers, such as Toyota, have their roots in the textile industry). By 1940 light industry had been displaced by heavy industry as the largest firms inside the Japanese economy.

Latin America

Main article: Great Depression in Latin America

Because of high levels of U.S. investment in Latin American economies, they were severely damaged by the Depression. Within the region, Chile, Bolivia and Peru were particularly badly affected.

Before the 1929 crisis, links between the world economy and Latin American economies had been established through American and British investment in Latin American exports to the world. As a result, Latin Americans export industries felt the depression quickly. World prices for commodities such as wheat, coffee and copper plunged. Exports from all of Latin America to the U.S. fell in value from $1.2 billion in 1929 to $335 million in 1933, rising to $660 million in 1940.

But on the other hand, the depression led the area governments to develop new local industries and expand consumption and production. Following the example of the New Deal, governments in the area approved regulations and created or improved welfare institutions that helped millions of new industrial workers to achieve a better standard of living.

Netherlands

Main article: Great Depression in the Netherlands
A line of unemployed people in Amsterdam, 1933

From roughly 1931 to 1937, the Netherlands suffered a deep and exceptionally long depression. This depression was partly caused by the after-effects of the American stock-market crash of 1929, and partly by internal factors in the Netherlands. Government policy, especially the very late dropping of the Gold Standard, played a role in prolonging the depression. The Great Depression in the Netherlands led to some political instability and riots, and can be linked to the rise of the Dutch fascist political party NSB. The depression in the Netherlands eased off somewhat at the end of 1936, when the government finally dropped the Gold Standard, but real economic stability did not return until after World War II.

New Zealand

Main article: History of New Zealand § Great Depression

New Zealand was especially vulnerable to worldwide depression, as it relied almost entirely on agricultural exports to the United Kingdom for its economy. The drop in exports led to a lack of disposable income from the farmers, who were the mainstay of the local economy. Jobs disappeared and wages plummeted, leaving people desperate and charities unable to cope. Work relief schemes were the only government support available to the unemployed, the rate of which by the early 1930s was officially around 15%, but unofficially nearly twice that level (official figures excluded Māori and women). In 1932, riots occurred among the unemployed in three of the country's main cities (Auckland, Dunedin, and Wellington). Many were arrested or injured through the tough official handling of these riots by police and volunteer "special constables".

Persia

This section needs expansion. You can help by making an edit requestadding to it . (April 2024)

In Iran, then known as the Imperial State of Persia, the Great Depression had negative impacts on its exports. In 1933 a new concession was signed with the Anglo-Persian Oil Company.

Poland

Main article: Second Polish Republic § Economy

Poland was affected by the Great Depression longer and stronger than other countries due to inadequate economic response of the government and the pre-existing economic circumstances of the country. At that time, Poland was under the authoritarian rule of Sanacja, whose leader, Józef Piłsudski, was opposed to leaving the gold standard until his death in 1935. As a result, Poland was unable to perform a more active monetary and budget policy. Additionally, Poland was a relatively young country that emerged merely 10 years earlier after being partitioned between German, Russian and the Austro-Hungarian Empires for over a century. Prior to independence, the Russian part exported 91% of its exports to Russia proper, while the German part exported 68% to Germany proper. After independence, these markets were largely lost, as Russia transformed into USSR that was mostly a closed economy, and Germany was in a tariff war with Poland throughout the 1920s.

Industrial production fell significantly: in 1932 hard coal production was down 27% compared to 1928, steel production was down 61%, and iron ore production noted an 89% decrease. On the other hand, electrotechnical, leather, and paper industries noted marginal increases in production output. Overall, industrial production decreased by 41%. A distinct feature of the Great Depression in Poland was the de-concentration of industry, as larger conglomerates were less flexible and paid their workers more than smaller ones.

Unemployment rate rose significantly (up to 43%) while nominal wages fell by 51% in 1933 and 56% in 1934, relative to 1928. However, real wages fell less due to the government's policy of decreasing cost of living, particularly food expenditures (food prices were down by 65% in 1935 compared to 1928 price levels). Material conditions deprivation led to strikes, some of them violent or violently pacified – like in Sanok (March of the Hungry in Sanok [pl] 6 March 1930), Lesko county (Lesko uprising 21 June – 9 July 1932) and Zawiercie (Bloody Friday (1930) [pl] 18 April 1930).

To adapt to the crisis, Polish government employed deflation methods such as high interest rates, credit limits and budget austerity to keep a fixed exchange rate with currencies tied to the gold standard. Only in late 1932 did the government effect a plan to fight the economic crisis. Part of the plan was mass public works scheme, employing up to 100,000 people in 1935. After Piłsudski's death, in 1936 the gold standard regime was relaxed, and launching the development of the Central Industrial Region kicked off the economy, to over 10% annual growth rate in the 1936–1938 period.

Portugal

Main article: Economic history of Portugal

Already under the rule of a dictatorial junta, the Ditadura Nacional, Portugal suffered no turbulent political effects of the Depression, although António de Oliveira Salazar, already appointed Minister of Finance in 1928 greatly expanded his powers and in 1932 rose to Prime Minister of Portugal to found the Estado Novo, an authoritarian corporatist dictatorship. With the budget balanced in 1929, the effects of the depression were relaxed through harsh measures towards budget balance and autarky, causing social discontent but stability and, eventually, an impressive economic growth.

Puerto Rico

In the years immediately preceding the depression, negative developments in the island and world economies perpetuated an unsustainable cycle of subsistence for many Puerto Rican workers. The 1920s brought a dramatic drop in Puerto Rico's two primary exports, raw sugar and coffee, due to a devastating hurricane in 1928 and the plummeting demand from global markets in the latter half of the decade. 1930 unemployment on the island was roughly 36% and by 1933 Puerto Rico's per capita income dropped 30% (by comparison, unemployment in the United States in 1930 was approximately 8% reaching a height of 25% in 1933). To provide relief and economic reform, the United States government and Puerto Rican politicians such as Carlos Chardon and Luis Muñoz Marín created and administered first the Puerto Rico Emergency Relief Administration (PRERA) 1933 and then in 1935, the Puerto Rico Reconstruction Administration (PRRA).

Romania

Main article: Great Depression in Romania

Romania was also affected by the Great Depression.

South Africa

Main article: Great Depression in South Africa

As world trade slumped, demand for South African agricultural and mineral exports fell drastically. The Carnegie Commission on Poor Whites had concluded in 1931 that nearly one-third of Afrikaners lived as paupers. The social discomfort caused by the depression was a contributing factor in the 1933 split between the "gesuiwerde" (purified) and "smelter" (fusionist) factions within the National Party and the National Party's subsequent fusion with the South African Party. Unemployment programs were begun that focused primarily on the white population.

Soviet Union

The Soviet Union was the only major socialist state in the world and had very little international trade. Its economy was not tied to the rest of the world and was mostly unaffected by the Great Depression.

At the time of the Depression, the Soviet economy was growing steadily, fuelled by intensive investment in heavy industry. The apparent economic success of the Soviet Union at a time when the capitalist world was in crisis led many Western intellectuals to view the Soviet system favorably. Jennifer Burns wrote:

As the Great Depression ground on and unemployment soared, intellectuals began unfavorably comparing their faltering capitalist economy to Russian Communism. Karl Marx had predicted that capitalism would fall under the weight of its own contradictions, and now with the economic crisis gripping the West, his predictions seem to be coming true. By contrast Russia seemed an emblematic modern nation, making the staggering leap from a feudal past to an industrial future with ease.

The early years of the Great Depression caused mass immigration to the Soviet Union, including 10,000 to 15,000 from Finland and thousands more from Poland, Sweden, Germany, and other nearby countries. The Kremlin was at first happy to help these immigrants settle, believing that they were victims of capitalism who had come to help the Soviet cause. However, by 1933, the worst of the Depression had come to an end in many countries, and word had been received that illegal migrants to the Soviet Union were being sent to Siberia. These factors caused immigration to the Soviet Union to slow significantly, and roughly a tenth of Finnish migrants returned to Finland, either legally or illegally.

Spain

Main article: Economic history of Spain

Spain had a relatively isolated economy, with high protective tariffs and was not one of the main countries affected by the Depression. The banking system held up well, as did agriculture.

By far the most serious negative impact came after 1936 from the heavy destruction of infrastructure and manpower by the civil war, 1936–39. Many talented workers were forced into permanent exile. By staying neutral in the Second World War, and selling to both sides, the economy avoided further disasters.

Sweden

Main article: Economy of Sweden

By the 1930s, Sweden had what America's Life magazine called in 1938 the "world's highest standard of living". Sweden was also the first country worldwide to recover completely from the Great Depression. Taking place amid a short-lived government and a less-than-a-decade old Swedish democracy, events such as those surrounding Ivar Kreuger (who eventually committed suicide) remain infamous in Swedish history. The Social Democrats under Per Albin Hansson formed their first long-lived government in 1932 based on strong interventionist and welfare state policies, monopolizing the office of Prime Minister until 1976 with the sole and short-lived exception of Axel Pehrsson-Bramstorp's "summer cabinet" in 1936. During forty years of hegemony, it was the most successful political party in the history of Western liberal democracy.

Thailand

In Thailand, then known as the Kingdom of Siam, the Great Depression contributed to the end of the absolute monarchy of King Rama VII in the Siamese revolution of 1932.

Turkey

This section needs expansion. You can help by making an edit requestadding to it . (April 2024)

Turkey was badly affected by the Great Depression and it came at a time when the state was still reforming its economic policy following the end of the Ottoman era. Exports of grapes, which held an important share, were down considerably which had already started beforehand due to drought.

United Kingdom

Main articles: Great Depression in the United Kingdom and Interwar Britain
Unemployed people in front of a workhouse in London, 1930

The world depression broke at a time when the United Kingdom had still not fully recovered from the effects of the First World War more than a decade earlier. The country was driven off the gold standard in 1931.

The world financial crisis began to overwhelm Britain in 1931; investors around the world started withdrawing their gold from London at the rate of £2.5 million per day. Credits of £25 million each from the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and an issue of £15 million fiduciary note slowed, but did not reverse the British crisis. The financial crisis now caused a major political crisis in Britain in August 1931. With deficits mounting, the bankers demanded a balanced budget; the divided cabinet of Prime Minister Ramsay MacDonald's Labour government agreed; it proposed to raise taxes, cut spending and most controversially, to cut unemployment benefits by 20%. The attack on welfare was totally unacceptable to the Labour movement. MacDonald wanted to resign, but King George V insisted he remain and form an all-party coalition "National Government". The Conservative and Liberals parties signed on, along with a small cadre of Labour, but the vast majority of Labour leaders denounced MacDonald as a traitor for leading the new government. Britain went off the gold standard, and suffered relatively less than other major countries in the Great Depression. In the 1931 British election, the Labour Party was virtually destroyed, leaving MacDonald as prime minister for a largely Conservative coalition.

The effects on the northern industrial areas of Britain were immediate and devastating, as demand for traditional industrial products collapsed. By the end of 1930 unemployment had more than doubled from 1 million to 2.5 million (20% of the insured workforce), and exports had fallen in value by 50%. In 1933, 30% of Glaswegians were unemployed due to the severe decline in heavy industry. In some towns and cities in the north east, unemployment reached as high as 70% as shipbuilding fell by 90%. The National Hunger March of September–October 1932 was the largest of a series of hunger marches in Britain in the 1920s and 1930s. About 200,000 unemployed men were sent to the work camps, which continued in operation until 1939.

In the less industrial Midlands and Southern England, the effects were short-lived and the later 1930s were a prosperous time. Growth in modern manufacture of electrical goods and a boom in the motor car industry was helped by a growing southern population and an expanding middle class. Agriculture also saw a boom during this period.

United States

Main articles: Great Depression in the United States and The New Deal
Unemployed men standing in line outside a depression soup kitchen in Chicago, 1931

Hoover's first measures to combat the depression were based on encouraging businesses not to reduce their workforce or cut wages but businesses had little choice: wages were reduced, workers were laid off, and investments postponed.

In June 1930, Congress approved the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act which raised tariffs on thousands of imported items. The intent of the Act was to encourage the purchase of American-made products by increasing the cost of imported goods, while raising revenue for the federal government and protecting farmers. Most countries that traded with the U.S. increased tariffs on American-made goods in retaliation, reducing international trade, and worsening the Depression.

In 1931, Hoover urged bankers to set up the National Credit Corporation so that big banks could help failing banks survive. But bankers were reluctant to invest in failing banks, and the National Credit Corporation did almost nothing to address the problem.

Burning shacks on the Anacostia flats, Washington, D.C., put up by the Bonus Army (World War I veterans) after the marchers with their wives and children were driven out by the regular Army by order of President Hoover, 1932

By 1932, unemployment had reached 23.6%, peaking in early 1933 at 25%. Those released from prison during this period had an especially difficult time finding employment given the stigma of their criminal records, which often led to recidivism out of economic desperation. Drought persisted in the agricultural heartland, businesses and families defaulted on record numbers of loans, and more than 5,000 banks had failed. Hundreds of thousands of Americans found themselves homeless, and began congregating in shanty towns – dubbed "Hoovervilles" – that began to appear across the country. In response, President Hoover and Congress approved the Federal Home Loan Bank Act, to spur new home construction, and reduce foreclosures. The final attempt of the Hoover Administration to stimulate the economy was the passage of the Emergency Relief and Construction Act (ERA) which included funds for public works programs such as dams and the creation of the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC) in 1932. The Reconstruction Finance Corporation was a Federal agency with the authority to lend up to $2 billion to rescue banks and restore confidence in financial institutions. But $2 billion was not enough to save all the banks, and bank runs and bank failures continued. Quarter by quarter the economy went downhill, as prices, profits and employment fell, leading to the political realignment in 1932 that brought to power Franklin Delano Roosevelt.

Buried machinery in a barn lot; South Dakota, May 1936. The Dust Bowl on the Great Plains coincided with the Great Depression.

Shortly after President Franklin Delano Roosevelt was inaugurated in 1933, drought and erosion combined to cause the Dust Bowl, shifting hundreds of thousands of displaced persons off their farms in the Midwest. From his inauguration onward, Roosevelt argued that restructuring of the economy would be needed to prevent another depression or avoid prolonging the current one. New Deal programs sought to stimulate demand and provide work and relief for the impoverished through increased government spending and the institution of financial reforms.

During a "bank holiday" that lasted five days, the Emergency Banking Act was signed into law. It provided for a system of reopening sound banks under Treasury supervision, with federal loans available if needed. The Securities Act of 1933 comprehensively regulated the securities industry. This was followed by the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 which created the Securities and Exchange Commission. Although amended, key provisions of both Acts are still in force. Federal insurance of bank deposits was provided by the FDIC, and the Glass–Steagall Act.

The Agricultural Adjustment Act provided incentives to cut farm production in order to raise farming prices. The National Recovery Administration (NRA) made a number of sweeping changes to the American economy. It forced businesses to work with government to set price codes through the NRA to fight deflationary "cut-throat competition" by the setting of minimum prices and wages, labor standards, and competitive conditions in all industries. It encouraged unions that would raise wages, to increase the purchasing power of the working class. The NRA was deemed unconstitutional by the Supreme Court of the United States in 1935.

CCC workers constructing drainage culvert, 1933. Over 3 million unemployed young men were taken out of the cities and placed into 2,600+ work camps managed by the CCC.

These reforms, together with several other relief and recovery measures, are called the First New Deal. Economic stimulus was attempted through a new alphabet soup of agencies set up in 1933 and 1934 and previously extant agencies such as the Reconstruction Finance Corporation. By 1935, the "Second New Deal" added Social Security (which was later considerably extended through the Fair Deal), a jobs program for the unemployed (the Works Progress Administration, WPA) and, through the National Labor Relations Board, a strong stimulus to the growth of labor unions. In 1929, federal expenditures constituted only 3% of the GDP. The national debt as a proportion of GNP rose under Hoover from 20% to 40%. Roosevelt kept it at 40% until the war began, when it soared to 128%.

By 1936, the main economic indicators had regained the levels of the late 1920s, except for unemployment, which remained high at 11%, although this was considerably lower than the 25% unemployment rate seen in 1933. In the spring of 1937, American industrial production exceeded that of 1929 and remained level until June 1937. In June 1937, the Roosevelt administration cut spending and increased taxation in an attempt to balance the federal budget. The American economy then took a sharp downturn, lasting for 13 months through most of 1938. Industrial production fell almost 30 per cent within a few months and production of durable goods fell even faster. Unemployment jumped from 14.3% in 1937 to 19.0% in 1938, rising from 5 million to more than 12 million in early 1938. Manufacturing output fell by 37% from the 1937 peak and was back to 1934 levels.

The WPA employed 2–3 million at unskilled labor.

Producers reduced their expenditures on durable goods, and inventories declined, but personal income was only 15% lower than it had been at the peak in 1937. As unemployment rose, consumers' expenditures declined, leading to further cutbacks in production. By May 1938 retail sales began to increase, employment improved, and industrial production turned up after June 1938. After the recovery from the Recession of 1937–38, conservatives were able to form a bipartisan conservative coalition to stop further expansion of the New Deal and, when unemployment dropped to 2% in the early 1940s, they abolished WPA, CCC and the PWA relief programs. Social Security remained in place.

Between 1933 and 1939, federal expenditure tripled, and Roosevelt's critics charged that he was turning America into a socialist state. The Great Depression was a main factor in the implementation of social democracy and planned economies in European countries after World War II (see Marshall Plan). Keynesianism generally remained the most influential economic school in the United States and in parts of Europe until the periods between the 1970s and the 1980s, when Milton Friedman and other neoliberal economists formulated and propagated the newly created theories of neoliberalism and incorporated them into the Chicago School of Economics as an alternative approach to the study of economics. Neoliberalism went on to challenge the dominance of the Keynesian school of Economics in the mainstream academia and policy-making in the United States, having reached its peak in popularity in the election of the presidency of Ronald Reagan in the United States, and Margaret Thatcher in the United Kingdom.

Literature

And the great owners, who must lose their land in an upheaval, the great owners with access to history, with eyes to read history and to know the great fact: when property accumulates in too few hands it is taken away. And that companion fact: when a majority of the people are hungry and cold they will take by force what they need. And the little screaming fact that sounds through all history: repression works only to strengthen and knit the repressed.

–John Steinbeck, The Grapes of Wrath

The Great Depression has been the subject of much writing, as authors have sought to evaluate an era that caused both financial and emotional trauma. Perhaps the most noteworthy and famous novel written on the subject is The Grapes of Wrath, published in 1939 and written by John Steinbeck, who was awarded the Pulitzer Prize for the work, and in 1962 was awarded the Nobel Prize for literature. The novel focuses on a poor family of sharecroppers who are forced from their home as drought, economic hardship, and changes in the agricultural industry occur during the Great Depression. Steinbeck's Of Mice and Men is another important novella about a journey during the Great Depression. Additionally, Harper Lee's To Kill a Mockingbird is set during the Great Depression. Margaret Atwood's Booker prize-winning The Blind Assassin is likewise set in the Great Depression, centering on a privileged socialite's love affair with a Marxist revolutionary. The era spurred the resurgence of social realism, practiced by many who started their writing careers on relief programs, especially the Federal Writers' Project in the U.S. Nonfiction works from this time also capture important themes. The 1933 memoir Prison Days and Nights by Victor Folke Nelson provides insight into criminal justice ramifications of the Great Depression, especially in regard to patterns of recidivism due to lack of economic opportunity.

A number of works for younger audiences are also set during the Great Depression, among them the Kit Kittredge series of American Girl books written by Valerie Tripp and illustrated by Walter Rane, released to tie in with the dolls and playsets sold by the company. The stories, which take place during the early to mid 1930s in Cincinnati, focuses on the changes brought by the Depression to the titular character's family and how the Kittredges dealt with it. A theatrical adaptation of the series entitled Kit Kittredge: An American Girl was later released in 2008 to positive reviews. Similarly, Christmas After All, part of the Dear America series of books for older girls, take place in 1930s Indianapolis; while Kit Kittredge is told in a third-person viewpoint, Christmas After All is in the form of a fictional journal as told by the protagonist Minnie Swift as she recounts her experiences during the era, especially when her family takes in an orphan cousin from Texas.

Naming

Further information: Economic depression

The term "The Great Depression" is most frequently attributed to British economist Lionel Robbins, whose 1934 book The Great Depression is credited with formalizing the phrase, though Hoover is widely credited with popularizing the term, informally referring to the downturn as a depression, with such uses as "Economic depression cannot be cured by legislative action or executive pronouncement" (December 1930, Message to Congress), and "I need not recount to you that the world is passing through a great depression" (1931).

Black Friday, 9 May 1873, Vienna Stock Exchange. The Panic of 1873 and Long Depression followed.

The term "depression" to refer to an economic downturn dates to the 19th century, when it was used by varied Americans and British politicians and economists. The first major American economic crisis, the Panic of 1819, was described by then-president James Monroe as "a depression", and the most recent economic crisis, the Depression of 1920–21, had been referred to as a "depression" by then-president Calvin Coolidge.

Financial crises were traditionally referred to as "panics", most recently the major Panic of 1907, and the minor Panic of 1910–11, though the 1929 crisis was called "The Crash", and the term "panic" has since fallen out of use. At the time of the Great Depression, the term "The Great Depression" was already used to refer to the period 1873–96 (in the United Kingdom), or more narrowly 1873–79 (in the United States), which has retroactively been renamed the Long Depression.

Other "great depressions"

The collapse of the Soviet Union, and the breakdown of economic ties which followed, led to a severe economic crisis and catastrophic fall in the standards of living in the 1990s in post-Soviet states and the former Eastern Bloc, which was even worse than the Great Depression. Even before Russia's financial crisis of 1998, Russia's GDP was half of what it had been in the early 1990s.

Comparison with the Great Recession

Main article: Comparisons between the Great Recession and the Great Depression

The worldwide economic decline after 2008 has been compared to the 1930s.

The causes of the Great Recession seem similar to the Great Depression, but significant differences exist. The then-chairman of the Federal Reserve, Ben Bernanke, had extensively studied the Great Depression as part of his doctoral work at MIT, and implemented policies to manipulate the money supply and interest rates in ways that were not done in the 1930s. Bernanke's policies will undoubtedly be analyzed and scrutinized in the years to come, as economists debate the wisdom of his choices. In 2011, one journalist contrasted the Great Depression of the 1930s as opposed to the late-2000s recession.

If we contrast the 1930s with the Crash of 2008 where gold went through the roof, it is clear that the U.S. dollar on the gold standard was a completely different animal in comparison to the fiat free-floating U.S. dollar currency we have today. Both currencies in 1929 and 2008 were the U.S. dollar, but analogously it is as if one was a Saber-toothed tiger and the other is a Bengal tiger; they are two completely different animals. Where we have experienced inflation since the Crash of 2008, the situation was much different in the 1930s when deflation set in. Unlike the deflation of the early 1930s, the U.S. economy currently appears to be in a "liquidity trap", or a situation where monetary policy is unable to stimulate an economy back to health.

In terms of the stock market, nearly three years after the 1929 crash, the DJIA dropped 8.4% on 12 August 1932. Where we have experienced great volatility with large intraday swings in the past two months, in 2011, we have not experienced any record-shattering daily percentage drops to the tune of the 1930s. Where many of us may have that '30s feeling, in light of the DJIA, the CPI, and the national unemployment rate, we are simply not living in the '30s. Some individuals may feel as if we are living in a depression, but for many others the current global financial crisis simply does not feel like a depression akin to the 1930s.

1928 and 1929 were the times in the 20th century that the wealth gap reached such skewed extremes; half the unemployed had been out of work for over six months, something that was not repeated until the late-2000s recession. 2007 and 2008 eventually saw the world reach new levels of wealth gap inequality that rivalled the years of 1928 and 1929.

See also

General

References

  1. ^ Friedman, Milton; Schwartz, Anna Jacobson (2008). A monetary history of the United States 1867-1960. Princeton paperbacks (9th pbk. printing, 22nd printing ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-00354-2.
  2. Lewis, William Arthur (2003). Economic survey: 1919 - 1939. International economics (Reprint 1949 ed.). London : Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-31359-9.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  3. ^ Frank, Robert H.; Bernanke, Ben S. (2007). Principles of Macroeconomics (3rd ed.). Boston: McGraw-Hill/Irwin. p. 98. ISBN 978-0-07-319397-7.
  4. "Commodity Data". U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Archived from the original on 3 June 2019. Retrieved 30 November 2008.
  5. Cochrane, Willard W. (1958). Farm Prices, Myth and Reality. p. 15.
  6. "World Economic Survey 1932–33". League of Nations: 43.
  7. Mitchell, Depression Decade
  8. ^ "Great Depression" Archived 9 May 2015 at the Wayback Machine, Encyclopædia Britannica
  9. Thomas S. Coleman (2019). Milton Friedman, Anna Schwartz, and A Monetary History of the US. Draft Lecture, Harris School of Public Policy, University of Chicago.
  10. "1998/99 Prognosis Based Upon 1929 Market Autopsy". Gold Eagle. Archived from the original on 17 May 2008. Retrieved 22 May 2008.
  11. "Drought: A Paleo Perspective – 20th Century Drought". National Climatic Data Center. Archived from the original on 30 March 2009. Retrieved 5 April 2009.
  12. Hamilton, James (1987). "Monetary Factors in the Great Depression". Journal of Monetary Economics. 19 (2): 145–69. doi:10.1016/0304-3932(87)90045-6. ISSN 0304-3932.
  13. "The Great Depression". drought.unl.edu. Archived from the original on 29 March 2018. Retrieved 29 March 2018.
  14. Kindleberger, Charles P. (1986). The world in depression, 1929–1939. History of the world economy in the twentieth century (Rev. and enl. ed.). Berkeley: University of California Press. ISBN 978-0-520-05591-9.
  15. Kindleberger, Charles Poor (1973). The world in depression, 1929–1939. History of the world economy in the twentieth century (Rev. and enl. ed., 11.  ed.). Berkeley, Calif.: University of California Press. ISBN 978-0-520-05592-6.
  16. Richard, Clay Hanes, ed. (July 2002). Historic Events for Students: The Great Depression (Volume I ed.). Gale. ISBN 978-0-7876-5701-7.
  17. Tignor, Robert L. (28 October 2013). Worlds together, worlds apart: a history of the world from the beginnings of humankind to the present (Fourth ed.). New York: W. W. Norton. ISBN 978-0-393-92207-3. OCLC 854609153.
  18. Jerome Blum, Rondo Cameron, Thomas G. Barnes, The European world: a history, (2nd ed 1970), 885 pp.
  19. George H. Soule, Prosperity Decade: From War to Depression: 1917–1929, (1947).
  20. "Timeline: A selected Wall Street chronology". PBS. Archived from the original on 23 September 2008. Retrieved 30 September 2008.
  21. Post, Special to Financial (24 October 2011). "The Great Crash of 1929, some key dates". Financial Post. Retrieved 22 July 2020.
  22. ^ "Market crash of 1929: Some facts of the economic downturn". Economic Times. Times Inernet. 22 October 2017. Retrieved 16 February 2019.
  23. According to the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data website, based on a monthly timeseries 1929 September – 1932 June, the Dow Jones Industrial Average lost 87.1% while the Cowles Commission and S&P's all stock index lost 85.0%: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=qj2m , https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=qj2l.
  24. Gordon, John Steele (November–December 2018). "The Bank of United States". ABA Banking Journal. 110 (6): 58. ProQuest 2160290916.
  25. Calomiris, Charles W. (November 2007). "Bank Failures in Theory and History: The Great Depression and Other "Contagious" Events". National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper Series. Cambridge, MA. doi:10.3386/w13597. S2CID 154123748.
  26. Ferguson, Niall (October 2009), The Ascent of Money, Penguin, p. 163, ISBN 978-986-173-584-9
  27. Whaples, Robert (March 1995). "Where Is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions". The Journal of Economic History. 55 (1). Cambridge University Press: 144. doi:10.1017/S0022050700040602. JSTOR 2123771. S2CID 145691938.
  28. "Protectionism and the Great Depression" Archived 25 February 2021 at the Wayback Machine, Paul Krugman, New York Times, 30 November 2009
  29. Barry Eichengreen, Douglas Irwin (17 March 2009). "The protectionist temptation: Lessons from the Great Depression for today". Archived 24 May 2012 at the Wayback Machine. VOX.
  30. ^ Whaples, Robert (1995). "Where is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions". The Journal of Economic History. 55 (1): 139–154. doi:10.1017/S0022050700040602. JSTOR 2123771. S2CID 145691938.
  31. "The Senate Passes the Smoot-Hawley Tariff". United States Senate. Archived from the original on 20 October 2021. Retrieved 3 May 2020.
  32. "The World in Depression". Mount Holyoke College. Archived from the original on 10 March 2008. Retrieved 22 May 2008.
  33. Parker, Selwyn (2 September 2010). The Great Crash: How the Stock Market Crash of 1929 Plunged the World into Depression. Little, Brown Book Group. ISBN 978-0-7481-2231-8.
  34. ^ Eichengreen, B.; Irwin, D. A. (2010). "The Slide to Protectionism in the Great Depression: Who Succumbed and Why?" (PDF). Journal of Economic History. 70 (4): 871–897. doi:10.1017/s0022050710000756. S2CID 18906612. Archived (PDF) from the original on 14 May 2019. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  35. Peter Temin, Gianni Toniolo, The World Economy between the Wars, Oxford University Press, 2008, ISBN 978-0-19-804201-3, p. 106
  36. Randall E. Parker, Reflections on the Great Depression, Elgar publishing, 2003, ISBN 978-1-84376-335-2, p. 22.
  37. International data from Maddison, Angus. "Historical Statistics for the World Economy: 1–2003 AD".. Gold dates culled from historical sources, principally Eichengreen, Barry (1992). Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-506431-3.
  38. Eichengreen, Barry (1992). Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-506431-3.
  39. Bernanke, Ben (2 March 2004). "Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke: Money, Gold and the Great Depression". At the H. Parker Willis Lecture in Economic Policy, Washington and Lee University, Lexington, Virginia. Archived from the original on 15 February 2022. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  40. Charles Loch Mowat, Britain between the wars, 1918–1940 (1955) pp. 379–385.
  41. ^ William Ashworth, A short history of the international economy since 1850, (2nd ed. 1962), pp. 237–244.
  42. ^ Isabel Schnabel, "The German twin crisis of 1931". Journal of Economic History 64#3 (2004): 822–871.
  43. ^ H. V. Hodson (1938), Slump and Recovery, 1929–1937 (London), pp. 64–76.
  44. ^ Williams, David (1963). "London and the 1931 financial crisis". Economic History Review. 15 (3): 513–528. doi:10.2307/2592922. JSTOR 2592922.
  45. Mowat (1955), Britain between the wars, 1918–1940, pp. 386–412.
  46. ^ Sean Glynn and John Oxborrow (1976), Interwar Britain : a social and economic history, pp. 67–73.
  47. ^ Per-capita GDP data from MeasuringWorth: What Was the U.S. GDP Then? Archived 4 September 2010 at the Wayback Machine
  48. Gauti B. Eggertsson, "Great Expectations and the End of the Depression", American Economic Review 98, No. 4 (September 2008): 1476–1516
  49. "Was the New Deal Contractionary?" Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 264, October 2006, Gauti B. Eggertsson Archived 12 February 2022 at the Wayback Machine
  50. "The Mistake of 1937: A General Equilibrium Analysis", Monetary and Economic Studies 24, No. S-1 (December 2006), Boj.or.jp Archived 11 August 2015 at the Wayback Machine
  51. Eggertsson, Gauti B. "A Reply to Steven Horwitz's Commentary on 'Great Expectations and the End of the Great Depression'". Econ Journal Watch. 7 (3): 197–204. Archived from the original on 15 February 2022. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  52. Steven Horwitz, "Unfortunately Unfamiliar with Robert Higgs and Others: A Rejoinder to Gauti Eggertsson on the 1930s", Econ Journal Watch 8(1), 2, January 2011. Archived 15 February 2022 at the Wayback Machine.
  53. Hannsgen, Greg; Papadimitriou, Dimitri (2010). "Did the New Deal Prolong or Worsen the Great Depression?". Challenge. 53 (1): 63–86. doi:10.2753/0577-5132530103. ISSN 0577-5132. JSTOR 40722622. S2CID 153490746.
  54. Quoted by P. Renshaw. Journal of Contemporary History. 1999 vol. 34 (3). pp. 377–364
  55. Romer, Christina D. (December 1992). "What Ended the Great Depression" (PDF). Journal of Economic History. 52 (4): 757–84. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.207.844. doi:10.1017/S002205070001189X. Archived from the original (PDF) on 17 January 2013. monetary development were crucial to the recovery implies that self-correction played little role in the growth of real output
  56. Ben Bernanke. Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-01698-6. p. 7
  57. Ben S. Bernanke, "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propaga-tion of the Great Depression", The American Economic Review 73, No. 3 (June 1983): 257–276, available from the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank collection at Stlouisfed.org Archived 5 March 2016 at the Wayback Machine
  58. Bernanke, Ben S. (February 1995). "The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach" (PDF). Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 27 (1). Fraser.stlouisfed.org: 1–28. doi:10.2307/2077848. JSTOR 2077848. Archived (PDF) from the original on 4 March 2016. Retrieved 16 October 2014.
  59. W. S. Woytinsky and E. S. Woytinsky, World population and production: trends and outlook (1953) p. 148
  60. Denyse Baillargeon, Making Do: Women, Family and Home in Montreal during the Great Depression (Wilfrid Laurier University Press, 1999), p. 159.
  61. Stephenson, Jill (2014). Women in Nazi Germany. Taylor & Francis. pp. 3–5. ISBN 978-1-317-87607-6. Archived from the original on 16 August 2021. Retrieved 27 June 2015.
  62. Susan K. Foley (2004). Women in France Since 1789: The Meanings of Difference. Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 186–90. ISBN 978-0-230-80214-8.
  63. Srigley, Katrina (2010). Breadwinning Daughters: Young Working Women in a Depression-era City, 1929–1939. University of Toronto Press. p. 135. ISBN 978-1-4426-1003-3.
  64. Jessica S. Bean, "'To help keep the home going': female labour supply in interwar London". Economic History Review (2015) 68#2 pp. 441–470.
  65. Deirdre Beddoe, Back to Home and Duty: Women Between the Wars, 1918–1939 (1989).
  66. Camiscioli, Elisa (2001). "Producing Citizens, Reproducing the 'French Race': Immigration, Demography, and Pronatalism in Early Twentieth-Century France". Gender & History. 13 (3): 593–621. doi:10.1111/1468-0424.00245. PMID 18198513. S2CID 20333294.
  67. Ann E. McCleary, "'I Was Really Proud of Them': Canned Raspberries and Home Production During the Farm Depression". Augusta Historical Bulletin (2010), Issue 46, pp. 14–44.
  68. Vogelsang, Willem. "3. Feedsacks and the Great Depression". trc-leiden.nl. Archived from the original on 15 April 2021. Retrieved 21 March 2020.
  69. Klassen, Tari (2008). "How Depression-Era Quiltmakers Constructed Domestic Space: An Interracial Processual Study". Midwestern Folklore. 34 (2): 17–47.
  70. Baillargeon, Making Do: Women, Family and Home in Montreal during the Great Depression (1999), pp. 70, 108, 136–138, 159.
  71. Metzler, Mark (2004). "Woman's Place in Japan's Great Depression: Reflections on the Moral Economy of Deflation". Journal of Japanese Studies. 30 (2): 315–352. doi:10.1353/jjs.2004.0045. S2CID 146273711.
  72. Reagin, N. R. (2001). "Marktordnung and Autarkic Housekeeping: Housewives and Private Consumption under the Four-Year Plan, 1936–1939". German History. 19 (2): 162–184. doi:10.1191/026635501678771619. PMID 19610237.
  73. Referring to the effect of World War II spending on the economy, economist John Kenneth Galbraith said, "One could not have had a better demonstration of the Keynesian ideas." Daniel Yergin, William Cran (writers / producer) (2002). Commanding Heights, see chapter 6 video or transcript (TV documentary). U.S.: PBS.
  74. Romer, Christina D. (1992). "What Ended the Great Depression?". Journal of Economic History. 52 (4): 757–784. doi:10.1017/S002205070001189X. fiscal policy was of little consequence even as late as 1942, suggests an interesting twist on the usual view that World War II caused, or at least accelerated, the recovery from the Great Depression.
  75. Higgs, Robert (1 March 1992). "Wartime Prosperity? A Reassessment of the U.S. Economy in the 1940s". The Journal of Economic History. 52 (1): 41–60. doi:10.1017/S0022050700010251. ISSN 1471-6372. S2CID 154484756.
  76. "Great Depression and World War II" Archived 24 January 2022 at the Wayback Machine. Library of Congress.
  77. Selective Service System. (27 May 2003). Induction Statistics. In Inductions (by year) from World War I Through the End of the Draft (1973) Archived 7 May 2009 at the Wayback Machine. Retrieved 8 September 2013.
  78. "Depression & WWII" Archived 25 June 2009 at the Wayback Machine. Americaslibrary.gov.
  79. ^ Hyman, Louis (16 December 2011). "How Did World War II End the Great Depression?: Echoes". Bloomberg. Archived from the original on 3 May 2016. Retrieved 25 August 2015.
  80. Richard J. Jensen, "The causes and cures of unemployment in the Great Depression" Archived 2 November 2021 at the Wayback Machine. Journal of Interdisciplinary History 19.4 (1989): 553–583.
  81. McCulloch, Hu (23 August 2018). "World War I, Gold, and the Great Depression". Cato Institute. Retrieved 12 November 2024.
  82. https://www.nber.org/system/files/chapters/c11482/c11482.pdf
  83. Lioudis, Nick. "What is the difference between Keynesian and monetarist economics?". Investopedia. Archived from the original on 20 December 2021. Retrieved 12 July 2021.
  84. "Great Depression – Causes of the decline". Encyclopedia Britannica. Archived from the original on 9 May 2015. Retrieved 12 July 2021.
  85. Hayes, Adam. "What is a Monetarist?". Investopedia. Archived from the original on 5 November 2021. Retrieved 12 July 2021.
  86. Whaples, Robert (1995). "Where is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions" (PDF). The Journal of Economic History. 55 (1). p. 150. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.482.4975. doi:10.1017/S0022050700040602. JSTOR 2123771. S2CID 145691938. Archived (PDF) from the original on 4 November 2021. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  87. Mendoza, Enrique G.; Smith, Katherine A. (1 September 2006). "Quantitative implications of a debt-deflation theory of Sudden Stops and asset prices". Journal of International Economics. 70 (1): 82–114. doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.06.016. ISSN 0022-1996. Archived from the original on 18 February 2022. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  88. Buraschi, Andrea; Jiltsov, Alexei (1 February 2005). "Inflation risk premia and the expectations hypothesis". Journal of Financial Economics. 75 (2): 429–490. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.07.003. ISSN 0304-405X. Archived from the original on 18 February 2022. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  89. Whaples, Robert (1995). "Where is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions" (PDF). The Journal of Economic History. 55 (1). p. 143. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.482.4975. doi:10.1017/S0022050700040602. JSTOR 2123771. S2CID 145691938. Archived (PDF) from the original on 4 November 2021. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  90. A Monetary History of the United States, 1857–1960. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, 1963.
  91. Randall E. Parker (2003), Reflections on the Great Depression Archived 18 August 2021 at the Wayback Machine, Edward Elgar Publishing, ISBN 978-1-84376-550-9, pp. 11–12
  92. Friedman, Milton; Anna Jacobson Schwartz (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New ed.). Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0691137940. Archived from the original on 16 January 2020. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  93. Bernanke, Ben (2000). Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton University Press. p. 7. ISBN 0-691-01698-4. Archived from the original on 24 December 2021. Retrieved 24 May 2021.
  94. Ben S. Bernanke (8 November 2002), "FederalReserve.gov: Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke" Archived March 24, 2020, at the Wayback Machine Conference to Honor Milton Friedman, University of Chicago
  95. Friedman, Milton; Schwartz, Anna (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New ed.). Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0691137940. Archived from the original on 16 January 2020. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  96. Krugman, Paul (15 February 2007). "Who Was Milton Friedman?". The New York Review of Books. 54 (2). Archived from the original on 10 April 2008. Retrieved 22 May 2008.
  97. G. Edward Griffin (1998). The Creature from Jekyll Island: A Second Look at the Federal Reserve (3d ed.). American Media. p. 503. ISBN 978-0-912986-39-5.
  98. ^ Frank Freidel (1973), Franklin D. Roosevelt: Launching the New Deal, ch. 19, Little, Brown & Co.
  99. Klein, Lawrence R. (1947). "The Keynesian Revolution". New York: Macmillan: 56–58, 169, 177–179. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help); Rosenof, Theodore (1997). Economics in the Long Run: New Deal Theorists and Their Legacies, 1933–1993. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. ISBN 0-8078-2315-5.
  100. ^ Fisher, Irving (October 1933). "The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions". Econometrica. 1 (4). The Econometric Society: 337–57. doi:10.2307/1907327. JSTOR 1907327. S2CID 35564016.
  101. Fortune, Peter (September–October 2000). "Margin Requirements, Margin Loans, and Margin Rates: Practice and Principles – analysis of history of margin credit regulations – Statistical Data Included". New England Economic Review. Archived from the original on 11 August 2015. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  102. ^ "Bank Failures". Living History Farm. Archived from the original on 19 February 2009. Retrieved 22 May 2008.
  103. "Friedman and Schwartz, Monetary History of the United States", 352
  104. Randall E. Parker, Reflections on the Great Depression, Edward Elgar Publishing, 2003, ISBN 978-1-84376-550-9, pp. 14–15
  105. Bernanke, Ben S. (June 1983). "Non-Monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression" (PDF). The American Economic Review. 73 (3). The American Economic Association: 257–276. JSTOR 1808111. Archived from the original (PDF) on 18 November 2017. Retrieved 22 February 2021.
  106. Mishkin, Fredric (December 1978). "The Household Balance and the Great Depression". Journal of Economic History. 38 (4): 918–937. doi:10.1017/S0022050700087167. S2CID 155049545.
  107. Gauti B. Eggertsson, Great Expectations and the End of the Depression, Archived 25 January 2016 at the Wayback Machine, American Economic Review 2008, 98: 4, pp. 1476–1516.
  108. Christina Romer, "The Fiscal Stimulus, Flawed but Valuable" Archived 29 November 2021 at the Wayback Machine, The New York Times, 20 October 2012.
  109. Peter Temin, Lessons from the Great Depression, MIT Press, 1992, ISBN 978-0-262-26119-7, pp. 87–101.
  110. Eggertsson, Gauti B. (2008). "Great Expectations and the End of the Depression". The American Economic Review. 98 (4). p. 1480. doi:10.1257/aer.98.4.1476. hdl:10419/60661. JSTOR 29730131.
  111. ^ De Long, J. Bradford (December 1990). "'Liquidation' Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression". NBER Working Paper No. 3546. Cambridge, MA: 1. doi:10.3386/w3546.
  112. ^ Randall E. Parker, Reflections on the Great Depression, Elgar Publishing, 2003, ISBN 978-1-84376-335-2, p. 9
  113. ^ White, Lawrence (2008). "Did Hayek and Robbins Deepen the Great Depression?". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 40 (4): 751–768. doi:10.1111/j.1538-4616.2008.00134.x. Archived from the original on 15 April 2021. Retrieved 7 November 2019.
  114. De Long, J. Bradford (December 1990). "'Liquidation' Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression". NBER Working Paper No. 3546. Cambridge, MA: 5. doi:10.3386/w3546.
  115. De Long, J. Bradford (December 1990). "'Liquidation' Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression". NBER Working Paper No. 3546. Cambridge, MA: 33. doi:10.3386/w3546.
  116. ^ Murray Rothbard, America's Great Depression (Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2000), pp. 159–163.
  117. Steele, G. R. (2001). Keynes and Hayek. Routledge. p. 9. ISBN 978-0-415-25138-9.
  118. Rothbard, America's Great Depression, pp. 19–21.
  119. For Hayek's view, see:
    • Diego Pizano, Conversations with Great Economists: Friedrich A. Hayek, John Hicks, Nicholas Kaldor, Leonid V. Kantorovich, Joan Robinson, Paul A.Samuelson, Jan Tinbergen (Jorge Pinto Books, 2009).
    For Rothbard's view, see:
    • Murray Rothbard, A History of Money and Banking in the United States (Ludwig von Mises Institute), pp. 293–294.
  120. ^ John Cunningham Wood, Robert D. Wood, Friedrich A. Hayek, Taylor & Francis, 2004, ISBN 978-0-415-31057-4, p. 115.
  121. Sennholz, Hans (1 October 1969). "The Great Depression". Foundation for Economic Education. Archived from the original on 24 December 2021. Retrieved 23 October 2016.
  122. Mises, Ludwig (18 August 2014). "The Causes of the Economic Crisis, and Other Essays Before and After the Great Depression". Ludwig von Mises Institute. Archived from the original on 5 December 2021. Retrieved 24 October 2016.
  123. Bonner, Bill (25 February 2011). "Buying Bad Debt to Return Bank Solvency". Business Insider. Archived from the original on 24 October 2016. Retrieved 24 October 2016.
  124. Corey, Lewis (1934). The Decline of American Capitalism. Covici Friede Publishers. ISBN 978-0-405-04116-7.
  125. Fleisher, Larry (30 October 2009). "The Great Depression And The Great Recession". Forbes.
  126. Dorfman, Joseph (1959). The economic mind in American civilization. The Viking Press. OCLC 71400420. Archived from the original on 18 February 2022. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  127. Allgoewer, Elisabeth (May 2002). "Underconsumption theories and Keynesian economics. Interpretations of the Great Depression" (PDF). Discussion Paper No. 2002–14. Archived (PDF) from the original on 4 March 2016. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  128. Foster, William Trufant; Catchings, Waddill (1928). The Road to Plenty. Houghton Mifflin. Archived from the original on 18 February 2022. Retrieved 28 December 2021.
  129. Hubbert, M. King (1940). "Man Hours and Distribution, Derived from Man Hours: A Declining Quantity, Technocracy, Series A, No. 8, August 1936". Archived from the original on 7 April 2020. Retrieved 9 September 2017. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  130. Bell, Spurgeon (1940). Productivity, Wages and National Income, The Institute of Economics of the Brookings Institution.
  131. Anderson, Betty S. (2016). A history of the modern Middle East : rulers, rebels, and rogues. Stanford, California. ISBN 978-0-8047-9875-4. OCLC 945376555. Archived from the original on 18 February 2022. Retrieved 13 February 2022.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  132. James Overton, "Economic Crisis and the End of Democracy: Politics in Newfoundland During the Great Depression." Labour 1990 (26): 85–124. ISSN 0700-3862
  133. della Paolera, Gerardo; Taylor, Alan M. (2001). "Steering through the Great Depression: Institutions, Expectations, and the Change of Macroeconomic Regime". Straining at the Anchor: The Argentine Currency Board and the Search for Macroeconomic Stability, 1880-1935. University of Chicago Press. pp. 188–189.
  134. Spruk, Rok (15 November 2019). "The rise and fall of Argentina". Latin American Economic Review. 28 (1): 16. doi:10.1186/s40503-019-0076-2. ISSN 2196-436X.
  135. Geoffrey Lawrence, Capitalism and the Countryside: The rural crisis in Australia (Pluto Press, 1987).
  136. A Century of Change in the Australian Labour Market Archived 31 December 2021 at the Wayback Machine, Australian Bureau of Statistics
  137. John Birmingham (2000). Leviathan: The unauthorised biography of Sydney. Random House. ISBN 978-0-09-184203-1.
  138. Judy Mackinolty, ed. The Wasted Years?: Australia's Great Depression (Allen & Unwin, 1981).
  139. 1929–1939 – The Great Depression Archived 27 January 2009 at the Wayback Machine, Source: Bank of Canada
  140. Anthony Latham and John Heaton, The Depression and the Developing World, 1914–1939 (1981).
  141. Coquery-Vidrovitch, C. (1977). "Mutation de l'Impérialisme Colonial Français dans les Années 30". African Economic History (in French) (4): 103–152. doi:10.2307/3601244. JSTOR 3601244.
  142. Westcott, Nicholas (1984). "The East African sisal industry, 1929–1949: the marketing of a colonial commodity during depression and war". Journal of African History. 25 (4): 445–461. doi:10.1017/s0021853700028486. S2CID 161203218.
  143. R. Olufeni Ekundare, An Economic History of Nigeria 1860–1960 (1973) online. Archived 31 December 2021 at the Wayback Machine, pp. 104–226.
  144. Olubomehin, O.O. (2002). "Road Transportation and the Economy of South-Western Nigeria, 1920–1939". Lagos Historical Review. 2: 106–121.
  145. Lungu, Gatian F. (1993). "Educational Policy-Making in Colonial Zambia: The Case of Higher Education for Africans from 1924 to 1964". The Journal of Negro History. 78 (4): 207–232. doi:10.2307/2717416. JSTOR 2717416. S2CID 149538992.
  146. R. Anstey, King Leopold's Legacy: The Congo under Belgian Rule 1908–1960 (1966), p. 109.
  147. Ochonu, Moses (2009). "Critical convergence: the Great Depression and the meshing of Nigerian and British anti-colonial polemic". Canadian Journal of African Studies. 43 (2): 245–281. doi:10.1080/00083968.2010.9707572. S2CID 142695035.
  148. Gamble, Harry (2009). "Les paysans de l'empire: écoles rurales et imaginaire colonial en Afrique occidentale française dans les années 1930". Cahiers d'Études Africaines (in French). 49 (3): 775–803. doi:10.4000/etudesafricaines.15630.
  149. Laufenburger, Henry (1936). "France and the Depression". International Affairs. 15 (2): 202–224. doi:10.2307/2601740. JSTOR 2601740.
  150. Jean-Pierre Dormois, The French Economy in the Twentieth Century (2004) p. 31
  151. Beaudry, Paul; Portier, Franck (2002). "The French Depression in the 1930s". Review of Economic Dynamics. 5 (1): 73–99. doi:10.1006/redy.2001.0143.
  152. About the Great Depression Archived 20 December 2008 at the Wayback Machine, University of Illinois
  153. ^ Germany – Economic Archived 31 December 2021 at the Wayback Machine, Public Broadcasting Service (PBS).
  154. Bullock, Alan (1991) . Hitler: A Study in Tyranny. New York; London: Harper Perennial. ISBN 978-1-56852-036-0.
  155. "The History Place – Rise of Hitler: Hitler Runs for President". History Place. Archived from the original on 3 November 2016. Retrieved 23 October 2016.
  156. Kershaw, Ian (1998). Hitler, 1889–1936: Hubris. W.W. Norton. p. 411. ISBN 978-0-393-32035-0.
  157. Adam Tooze, The Wages of Destruction: The Making and Breaking of the Nazi Economy (2007)
  158. R. J. Overy, "Misjudging Hitler", pp. 93–115 from The Origins of the Second World War Reconsidered edited by Gordon Martel, Routledge: London, England, 1999, pp. 98–99.
  159. Kershaw, Ian To Hell and Back: Europe 1914–1949, Ch. 5
  160. ^ Karlsson, Gunnar (2000). History of Iceland. pp. 308–12.
  161. Manikumar, K. A. (2003). A Colonial Economy in the Great Depression, Madras (1929–1937).
  162. Samita Sen, "Labour, Organization and Gender: The Jute Industry in India in the 1930s", in Helmut Konrad and Wolfgang Maderthaner, eds. Routes Into the Abyss: Coping with Crises in the 1930s (2013) pp. 152–66.
  163. Simmons, Colin (1987). "The Great Depression and Indian Industry: Changing Interpretations and Changing Perceptions". Modern Asian Studies. 21 (3): 585–623. doi:10.1017/S0026749X00009215. JSTOR 312643. S2CID 145538790.
  164. Frank Barry and Mary F. Daly, "Concurrent Irish Perspectives on the Great Depression" (2010)
  165. Frank Barry and Mary E. Daly, "Irish Perceptions of the Great Depression" in Michael Psalidopoulos, The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012), pp. 395–424.
  166. See also B. Girvin, Between Two Worlds: Politics and Economy in Independent Ireland (Dublin: Gill and Macmillan, 1989).
  167. Barry, Frank, and Mary E. Daly. "Irish Perceptions of the Great Depression" (No. iiisdp349. IIIS, 2011.) Online Archived 11 August 2015 at the Wayback Machine
  168. Vera Zamagni, The economic history of Italy 1860–1990 (Oxford University Press, 1993)
  169. Fabrizio Mattesini, and Beniamino Quintieri. "Italy and the Great Depression: An analysis of the Italian economy, 1929–1936." Explorations in Economic History (1997) 34#3 pp: 265–294.
  170. Fabrizio Mattesini and Beniamino Quintieri. "Does a reduction in the length of the working week reduce unemployment? Some evidence from the Italian economy during the Great Depression." Explorations in Economic History (2006), 43#3, pp. 413–37.
  171. Myung Soo Cha, "Did Takahashi Korekiyo Rescue Japan from the Great Depression?", The Journal of Economic History 63, No. 1 (March 2003): 127–144.
  172. (For more on the Japanese economy in the 1930s see "MITI and the Japanese Miracle" by Chalmers Johnson.)
  173. Rosemary Thorp, Latin America in the 1930s: the role of the periphery in world crisis (Palgrave Macmillan, 2000).
  174. E. H. Kossmann, The Low Countries: 1780–1940 (1978).
  175. "Social Welfare and The State: Great Depression Archived March 7, 2016, at the Wayback Machine", Museum of New Zealand Te Papa Tongarewa.
  176. Foundation, Encyclopaedia Iranica. "Welcome to Encyclopaedia Iranica". iranicaonline.org. Retrieved 17 April 2024.
  177. "II RP była gospodarczą porażką. Mity na jej temat są bardzo szkodliwe [TOP 2018]". forsal.pl (in Polish). 3 November 2018. Archived from the original on 19 October 2021. Retrieved 29 July 2021.
  178. ^ "Wielki kryzys gospodarczy w Polsce". histmag.org. Archived from the original on 29 July 2021. Retrieved 29 July 2021.
  179. "Wielki kryzys w Polsce. Zbankrutowało niemal 25% firm, a produkt krajowy spadł o ponad połowę". WielkaHistoria (in Polish). 9 November 2020. Archived from the original on 29 July 2021. Retrieved 29 July 2021.
  180. "140 lat temu urodził się Bolesław Wieniawa-Długoszowski". dzieje.pl (in Polish). Archived from the original on 12 August 2021. Retrieved 29 July 2021.
  181. José Cardozo, "The great depression and Portugal" in Michael Psalidopoulos, ed. (2012). The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context Athens: Alpha Bank, ISBN 978-960-99793-6-8. pp. 361–394 Online. Archived 13 March 2017 at the Wayback Machine.
  182. Rodriguez, Manuel (2011). A New Deal for the Tropics. Princeton: Markus Wiener. p. 23.
  183. "Graph of U.S. Unemployment Rate: 1930–1945". American Social History Project. Archived from the original on 23 January 2021. Retrieved 19 April 2017.
  184. Dietz, James (1986). Economic History of Puerto Rico. Princeton: Princeton University Press. pp. 154–55. ISBN 0-691-02248-8. Archived from the original on 18 August 2021. Retrieved 4 February 2018.
  185. Blejan, Elisabeta; Costache, Brîndușa; Aloman, Adriana (2009). "The National Bank of Romania during the Great Depression – 1929–1933" (PDF). Fourth Conference of Southeast Europe Monetary History Network (SEEMHN) (8). National Bank of Serbia: 1–34. Archived (PDF) from the original on 19 November 2021. Retrieved 21 March 2021.
  186. Chiappini, Raphaël; Torre, Dominique; Tosi, Elise (2009). "Romania's unsustainable stabilization: 1929–1933" (PDF). GREDEG Working Papers (2019–43). Groupe de Recherche en Droit, Economie, Gestion: 1–32. Archived (PDF) from the original on 8 July 2021. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  187. Dan O'Meara, Volkskapitalisme: class, capital, and ideology in the development of Afrikaner nationalism, 1934–1948 (Cambridge University Press, 1983).
  188. The Great Depression and the 1930S Archived 2 January 2022 at the Wayback Machine, Federal Research Division of the Library of Congress.
  189. Minnaar, Anthony (1994). "Unemployment and relief measures during the Great Depression (1929–1934)". Kleio. 26 (1): 45–85. doi:10.1080/00232084.1994.10823193.
  190. Robert William Davies, Mark Harrison, and Stephen G. Wheatcroft, eds. The economic transformation of the Soviet Union, 1913–1945 (Cambridge University Press, 1994)
  191. Jennifer Burns (2009).Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right Archived April 15, 2021, at the Wayback Machine, p. 34. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-532487-0
  192. "Illegal Emigration to the U.S.S.R. During the Great Depression". www.genealogia.fi. Archived from the original on 24 February 2021. Retrieved 19 September 2016.
  193. Gabriel Tortella and Jordi Palafox, "Banking and Industry in Spain 1918–1936", Journal of European Economic History (1984), 13#2 Special Issue, pp. 81–110.
  194. R. J. Harrison, Economic History of Modern Spain (1978), pp. 129–149.
  195. Göran Therborn, "A Unique Chapter in the History of Democracy: The Swedish Social Democrats", in K. Misgeld et al. (eds), Creating Social Democracy, University Park, Penn State University Press, 1996.
  196. Handley, Paul M. (2006). The King Never Smiles: A Biography of Thailand's Bhumibol Adulyadej. New Haven and London: Yale University Press. p. 37.
  197. Yankın, Yeşim Ertem (2018). "THE EFFECT OF THE GREAT DEPRESSION OVER AEGEAN GRAPES (REPERCUSSIONS)". Journal of Atatürk and the History of Turkish Republic. 1 (3): 147–160.
  198. Charles Loch Mowat, Britain between the wars, 1918–1940 (1955) pp. 386–412.
  199. Unemployment During The Great Depression Archived 24 January 2009 at the Wayback Machine, thegreatdepression.co.uk
  200. Cook, Chris and Bewes, Diccon; What Happened Where: A Guide To Places And Events In Twentieth-Century History p. 115; Routledge, 1997 ISBN 1-85728-533-6
  201. "Work camps that tackled Depression" Archived 6 January 2022 at the Wayback Machine, BBC News.
  202. Constantine, Stephen (1983), Social Conditions in Britain 1918–1939, ISBN 0-416-36010-6
  203. ^ Peter Clemens, Prosperity, Depression and the New Deal: The USA 1890–1954, Hodder Education, 4. Auflage, 2008, ISBN 978-0-340-96588-7, p. 114.
  204. Charles R. Morris, A Rabble of Dead Money: The Great Crash and the Global Depression: 1929–1939 (PublicAffairs, 2017), 389 pp. online review Archived 24 April 2017 at the Wayback Machine
  205. "Smoot-Hawley Tariff" Archived 12 March 2009 at the Wayback Machine, U.S. Department of State.
  206. "Reconstruction Finance Corporation". EH.net Encyclopedia. Archived from the original on 29 October 2013.
  207. Clemens, Prosperity, Depression and the New Deal, 2008, p. 113.
  208. The Great Depression (1929–1939), The Eleanor Roosevelt Papers. Archived 23 December 2008 at the Wayback Machine
  209. Swanson, Joseph; Williamson, Samuel (1972). "Estimates of national product and income for the United States economy, 1919–1941". Explorations in Economic History. 10 (1): 53–73. doi:10.1016/0014-4983(72)90003-4.
  210. ^ Prison Days and Nights, by Victor F. Nelson (New York: Garden City Publishing Co., Inc., 1936)
  211. "Great Depression in the United States" Archived 28 October 2009 at the Wayback Machine, Microsoft Encarta. Archived 31 October 2009.
  212. Joyce Bryant, "The Great Depression and New Deal" Archived 21 July 2016 at the Wayback Machine, Yale-New Haven Teachers Institute.
  213. The Dust Bowl, Geoff Cunfer, Southwest Minnesota State University. Archived 28 December 2008 at the Wayback Machine
  214. "National Park History: "The Spirit of the Civilian Conservation Corps"". Nationalparkstraveler.com. Archived from the original on 5 September 2010. Retrieved 4 September 2010.
  215. Robert Goldston, The Great Depression, Fawcett Publications, 1968, p. 228.
  216. Economic Fluctuations, Maurice W. Lee, Chairman of Economics Dept., Washington State College, published by R.D. Irwin Inc, Homewood, Illinois, 1955, p. 236.
  217. Business Cycles, James Arthur Estey, Purdue University, Prentice-Hall, 1950, pp. 22–23 chart.
  218. Maurice W. Lee, 1955.
  219. Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. The Coming of the New Deal: 1933–1935. Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003 . ISBN 0-618-34086-6; Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. The Politics of Upheaval: 1935–1936. Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003 . ISBN 0-618-34087-4
  220. Lanny Ebenstein, Milton Friedman: A Biography (2007).
  221. The Grapes of Wrath, by John Steinbeck, Penguin, 2006, 0143039431, p. 238
  222. David Taylor, Soul of a People: The WPA Writers' Project Uncovers Depression America (2009).
  223. Jerre Mangione, The Dream and the Deal: The Federal Writers' Project, 1935–1943 (1996)
  224. Jerrold Hirsch, Portrait of America: A Cultural History of the Federal Writers' Project (2006)
  225. Stacy I. Morgan, Rethinking Social Realism: African American art and literature, 1930–1953 (2004), p. 244.
  226. Harry, Lou (1 October 2010). Cincinnati Magazine. Emmis Communications. pp. 59–63. Archived from the original on 15 April 2021. Retrieved 10 July 2017.
  227. Morency, Philip. On the Aisle, Volume 2: Film Reviews by Philip Morency. Dorrance Publishing. pp. 133–. ISBN 978-1-4349-7709-0. Archived from the original on 17 August 2021. Retrieved 22 August 2017.
  228. Pimpare, Stephen (2017). Ghettos, Tramps, and Welfare Queens: Down and Out on the Silver Screen. Oxford University Press. pp. 216–. ISBN 978-0-19-066072-7. Archived from the original on 15 April 2021. Retrieved 10 July 2017.
  229. Smith, Robert W. (26 January 2006). Spotlight on America: The Great Depression. Teacher Created Resources. ISBN 978-1-4206-3218-7. Archived from the original on 15 April 2021. Retrieved 10 July 2017.
  230. ^ "When Did the Great Depression Receive Its Name? (And Who Named It?) – History News Network". hnn.us. Archived from the original on 9 January 2022. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
  231. William Manchester, The Glory and the Dream: A Narrative History of America, 1932–1972.
  232. Fletcher, T.W. (1961). "The Great Depression of English Agriculture 1873–1896". The Economic History Review. 13 (3). Blackwell Publishing: 417–32. doi:10.2307/2599512. JSTOR 2599512.
  233. "Child poverty soars in eastern Europe", BBC News, 11 October 2000.
  234. "The wild decade: how the 1990s laid the foundations for Vladimir Putin's Russia". The Conversation. 2 July 2020. Retrieved 16 September 2024.
  235. See "What Can Transition Economies Learn from the First Ten Years? A New World Bank Report," in Transition Newsletter Worldbank.org Archived 30 May 2012 at archive.today, K-A.kg
  236. ^ Who Lost Russia?, New York Times, 8 October 2000.
  237. Adam Tooze, Crashed: How a Decade of Financial Crises Changed the World (2018), p. 41.
  238. Rampell, Catherine (11 March 2009). "'Great Recession': A Brief Etymology". The New York Times. Archived from the original on 19 October 2021. Retrieved 9 March 2017.
  239. Gibbs, Nancy (15 April 2009). "The Great Recession: America Becomes Thrift Nation". Time. Archived from the original on 17 April 2009.
  240. Krugman, Paul (20 March 2009). "The Great Recession versus the Great Depression". The New York Times. Archived from the original on 25 February 2021. Retrieved 7 February 2017.
  241. Lahart, Justin (28 July 2009). "The Great Recession: A Downturn Sized Up". The Wall Street Journal. Archived from the original on 15 April 2021. Retrieved 3 August 2017.
  242. Rabinowitz, Marco (6 October 2011). "The Great Depression vs. the Great Recession Archived 17 October 2011 at the Wayback Machine: A look at the value of the U.S. dollar in 1929 and 2008; what has changed and where that leaves us today". MSN Money. Benzinga.
  243. Evans-Pritchard, Ambrose (14 September 2010). "IMF Fears 'Social Explosion' From World Jobs Crisis". The Daily Telegraph (London). "America and Europe face the worst jobs crisis since the 1930s and risk 'an explosion of social unrest' unless they tread carefully, the International Monetary Fund has warned."

Further reading

Global

  • Brendon, Piers. The Dark Valley: A Panorama of the 1930s (2000) comprehensive global economic and political history; 816pp
  • Davis, Joseph S. The World Between the Wars, 1919–39: An Economist's View (1974)
  • Garraty, John A. The Great Depression: An Inquiry into the causes, course, and Consequences of the Worldwide Depression of the Nineteen-Thirties, as Seen by Contemporaries and in Light of History (1986) online
  • Garside, W.R. ed. Capitalism in crisis: International responses to the Great Depression (1993), essays by experts
  • Grossman, Mark. Encyclopedia of the Interwar Years: From 1919 to 1939 (2000). 400 pp. worldwide coverage
  • Hall Thomas E. and J. David Ferguson. The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies (1998)
  • Hodson, H.V. Slump and Recovery, 1929–37: A Survey of World Economic Affairs (Oxford UP, 1938). online
  • Kehoe, Timothy J. and Edward C. Prescott. Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century (2007)
  • League Of Nations. World Economic Survey 1935–1936 (1936) online
  • Rees, Goronwy. The great slump: capitalism in crisis, 1929–33 (1970) online, Marxist.
  • Rothermund, Dietmar. The Global Impact of the Great Depression (1996)
  • Woytinsky, Wladimir. The Social Consequences Of The Economic Depression (International Labour Office, 1936). Statistics of major economies; not online.

Europe

  • Aldcroft, Derek H. "Economic Growth in Britain in the Inter-War Years: A Reassessment." Economic History Review, 20#2, 1967, pp. 311–26. online
  • Ambrosius, G. and W. Hibbard, A Social and Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe (1989)
  • Broadberry, S. N. The British Economy between the Wars (Basil Blackwell 1986)
  • Feinstein. Charles H. The European Economy between the Wars (1997)
  • James, Harold. The German slump : politics and economics, 1924–1936 (1986) online
  • Kaiser, David E. Economic diplomacy and the origins of the Second World War: Germany, Britain, France and Eastern Europe, 1930–1939 (1980)
  • Konrad, Helmut and Wolfgang Maderthaner, eds. Routes Into the Abyss: Coping With Crises in the 1930s Archived 24 January 2020 at the Wayback Machine (Berghahn Books, 2013), 224 pp. Compares political crises in Germany, Italy, Austria, and Spain with those in Sweden, Japan, China, India, Turkey, Brazil, and the United States.
  • Psalidopoulos, Michael, ed. The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012). ISBN 978-960-99793-6-8. Chapters by economic historians cover Finland, Sweden, Belgium, Austria, Italy, Greece, Turkey, Bulgaria, Yugoslavia, Romania, Spain, Portugal, and Ireland. table of contents Archived 13 March 2017 at the Wayback Machine
  • Tipton, F. and R. Aldrich, An Economic and Social History of Europe, 1890–1939 (1987)

United States and Canada

Other areas

  • Brown, Ian. The Economies of Africa and Asia in the Inter-war Depression (1989)
  • Drinot, Paulo, and Alan Knight, eds. The Great Depression in Latin America (2014) excerpt
  • Latham, Anthony, and John Heaton, The Depression and the Developing World, 1914–1939 (1981).
  • Shiroyama, Tomoko. China during the Great Depression : market, state, and the world economy, 1929–1937 (2008) online

Focus on economic theory or econometrics

  • Bernanke, Ben. "The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach" Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking (1995) 27#1 pp 1–28 online
  • Eichengreen, Barry J. Hall of mirrors : the Great Depression, the great recession, and the uses-and misuses-of history (2015), leading economist compares economic decline after 1929 and after 2008. online
  • Eichengreen, Barry. Golden Fetters: The gold standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. 1992.
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Marc Flandreau. The Gold Standard in Theory and History (1997)
  • Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960 (1963), monetarist interpretation (heavily statistical)
  • Glasner, David, ed. Business Cycles and Depressions (Routledge, 1997), 800 pp. Excerpt
  • Grinin, L., Korotayev, A. and Tausch A. eds. Economic Cycles, Crises, and the Global Periphery (2016).
  • Haberler, Gottfried. The World Economy, money, and the great depression 1919–1939 (1976)
  • Kehoe, Timothy J. and Edward C. Prescott, eds. Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century (2007), essays by economists on the U.S., Britain, France, Germany, Italy and on tariffs; statistical
  • Kindleberger, Charles P. The World in Depression, 1929–1939 (3rd ed. 2013) online
  • Madsen, Jakob B. "Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression", Southern Economic Journal, (2001) 67#4 pp. 848–68 online at JSTOR.
  • Markwell, Donald. John Maynard Keynes and International Relations: Economic Paths to War and Peace (Oxford University Press, 2006).
  • Mundell, R.A. "A Reconsideration of the Twentieth Century", American Economic Review 90#3 (2000), pp. 327–40 online version
  • Richardson, H. W. "The Basis of Economic Recovery in the Nineteen-Thirties: A Review and a New Interpretation." Economic History Review, 15#2 (1962), pp. 344–63. online; focus on United Kingdom.
  • Romer, Christina D. "The Nation in Depression", Journal of Economic Perspectives (1993) 7#2 pp. 19–39 in JSTOR Archived 3 July 2016 at the Wayback Machine, statistical comparison of U.S. and other countries
Portals:
Great Depression
Topics
By country
United States
New Deal
Causes and legacy
New Deal
Second New Deal
Individuals
Economic expansions and recessions in the United States and Commonwealth of Nations countries
Commercial revolution
(1000–1760)
1st Industrial Revolution
(1760–1840)
Early Victorian Britain/
Civil War-era United States
(1840–1870)
Gilded Age/
2nd Industrial Revolution
(1870–1914)
Interwar period
(1918–1939)
Post–WWII expansion
(1945–1973)
Great Inflation
(1973–1982)
Great Moderation/
Great Regression
(1982–2007)
Information Age
(2007–present)
United States articles
History
By period
By event
By topic
Geography
Politics
Federal
Executive
Legislative
Judicial
Law
Uniformed
State,
Federal District,
and Territorial
Executive
Legislative
Judicial
Law
Tribal
Local
County
Cities
Minor divisions
Special district
Economy
Transport
Society
Culture
Social class
Health
Issues
Economics
Theoretical
Empirical
Applied
Schools
(history)
Economists
Lists
  • Category
  • Index
  • Lists
  • Outline
  • Publications
  • Business portal
  • Employment
    Classifications
    Hiring
    Roles
    Working class
    Career and training
    Attendance
    Schedules
    Wages and salaries
    Benefits
    Safety and health
    Equal opportunity
    Infractions
    Willingness
    Termination
    Unemployment
    Public programs

    Comprehensive Employment and Training Act

    See also
    See also templates
    Categories: