This article includes a list of references, related reading, or external links, but its sources remain unclear because it lacks inline citations. Please help improve this article by introducing more precise citations. (March 2024) (Learn how and when to remove this message) |
A joint Politics and Economics series |
Social choice and electoral systems |
---|
Single-winner methodsSingle vote - plurality methods
|
Proportional representationParty-list
|
Mixed systemsBy results of combination
By mechanism of combination By ballot type |
Paradoxes and pathologiesSpoiler effects
Pathological response Paradoxes of majority rule |
Social and collective choiceImpossibility theorems
Positive results |
Mathematics portal |
The sequential elimination methods are a class of voting systems that repeatedly eliminate the last-place finisher of another voting method until a single candidate remains. The method used to determine the loser is called the base method. Common are the two-round system, instant-runoff voting, and some primary systems.
Instant-runoff voting is a sequential loser method based on plurality voting, while Baldwin's method is a sequential loser method based on the Borda count.
Properties
Proofs of criterion compliance for loser-elimination methods often use mathematical induction, and so can be easier than proving such compliance for other method types. For instance, if the base method passes the majority criterion, a sequential loser-elimination method based on it will pass mutual majority. Loser-elimination methods are also not much harder to explain than their base methods.
However, loser-elimination methods often fail monotonicity due to chaotic effects (sensitivity to initial conditions): the order in which candidates are eliminated can create erratic behavior.
If the base method passes independence from the weakest alternative, the loser-elimination method is equivalent to the base method. In other words, methods that are immune to weak spoilers are already "their own" elimination methods, because eliminating the weakest candidate does not affect the winner.
If the base method satisfies a criterion for a single candidate (e.g. the majority criterion or the Condorcet criterion), then a sequential loser method satisfies the corresponding set criterion (e.g. the mutual majority criterion or the Smith criterion), so long as eliminating a candidate can't remove another candidate from the set in question. This is because when all but one of the candidates of the set have been eliminated, the single-candidate criterion applies to the remaining candidate.
References
- ^ Xia, Lirong; Lang, Jérôme; Ying, Mingsheng (2007-06-25). "Sequential voting rules and multiple elections paradoxes". Proceedings of the 11th conference on Theoretical aspects of rationality and knowledge - TARK '07. New York, NY, USA: Association for Computing Machinery. pp. 279–288. doi:10.1145/1324249.1324286. ISBN 978-1-4503-7841-3.
- ^ Bag, PK; Sabourian, H; Winter, E. "Sequential Elimination vs. Instantaneous Voting" (PDF). Mimeo.
Further reading
- Chowdhury, Subhasish M.; Kim, Sang-Hyun (July 2017). "'Small, yet Beautiful': Reconsidering the optimal design of multi-winner contests" (PDF). Games and Economic Behavior. 104: 486–493. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2017.05.012. S2CID 43411835.
- Klunover, Doron (December 2023). "Bureaucracy and labor market inefficiency: A contest model". European Journal of Political Economy. 80: 102472. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2023.102472. S2CID 262024392.